Preferred Citation: Engelbert, Ernest A., and Ann Foley Scheuring, editors Water Scarcity: Impacts on Western Agricultur...
12 downloads
1065 Views
3MB Size
Report
This content was uploaded by our users and we assume good faith they have the permission to share this book. If you own the copyright to this book and it is wrongfully on our website, we offer a simple DMCA procedure to remove your content from our site. Start by pressing the button below!
Report copyright / DMCA form
Preferred Citation: Engelbert, Ernest A., and Ann Foley Scheuring, editors Water Scarcity: Impacts on Western Agriculture. Berkeley: University of California Press, c1984 1984. http://ark.cdlib.org/ark:/13030/ft0f59n72f/
Water Scarcity Impacts on Western Agriculture Edited by Ernest A. Engelbert with Ann Foley Scheuring UNIVERSITY OF CALIFORNIA PRESS
Berkeley · Los Angeles · Oxford
© 1984 The Regents of the University of California
Preferred Citation: Engelbert, Ernest A., and Ann Foley Scheuring, editors Water Scarcity: Impacts on Western Agriculture. Berkeley: University of California Press, c1984 1984. http://ark.cdlib.org/ark:/13030/ft0f59n72f/
PREFACE This publication is the product of an interdisciplinary conference on water problems in the western United States held in Monterey, California, in September, 1982. The primary purpose of the conference and this volume has been to assess the impacts on local, state, national and international communities of limited water supplies for agriculture in the semiarid West. This vast area of the nation is faced with important decisions in the management of declining water supplies if a prosperous agricultural economy is to be sustained. Planning for the conference began in 1978 under the sponsorship of the Directorate on Arid Zone Ecosystems, a part of the United States Man and the Biosphere Program. The Man and the Biosphere Program is an
international effort under the auspices of UNESCO to study the relationships of man to changing environments in various regions of the world. Because the future of western agriculture in the United States has significance for the economies and semiarid regions of other countries, the Organizing Committee of the conference concluded that a careful analysis of what was happening in the American West would have international interest and relevance. The conference and this volume represent an interdisciplinary effort to deal with the subject from both a natural and social science perspective. The Organizing Committee identified the topics and invited over seventy specialists from diverse disciplines representing the academic community, private industry, and the public sector to prepare papers and discussants' comments for the conference. Over two hundred persons participated in four intensive days of presentations and discussions of the papers. The participants represented a broad spectrum of experience, views and interests, including farmers, businessmen, bankers, planners, analysts, environmentalists, community leaders, elected officials, and representatives of other concerned organizations. They reviewed and critiqued the prepared presentations and made substantial contributions to the analyses. Following the conference the authors were given the opportunity to revise their papers and comments, and, in some cases, to include overlooked but relevant points. This volume is the combined product of the revised papers and conference input. To provide integration of subject matter, the papers have been organized under section and chapter headings and placed in appropriate sequence.
― viii ― No one who participated in this educational undertaking would conclude that all topics involving water and agriculture in the semiarid West have been adequately covered. Indeed, as both the Introduction and the Summary show, many issues remain unresolved. However, the Organizing Committee believes that a searching focus has been given to this subject and public attention called to what is becoming an increasingly critical aspect of the nation's economy. Thus we hope that this volume will be informative and useful for everyone who is concerned with future water supplies for agriculture in the West. ROBERT M. HAGAN CHAIRMAN, ORGANIZING COMMITTEE
― ix ―
ACKNOWLEDGMENTS Many organizations and individuals contributed to the planning and organization of the conference and publication on Limited Water for Agriculture in the West: No Simple Solutions. Grateful appreciation for their assistance is made to the following groups and persons: · Sponsors who provided financial, facilitative and moral support which made this activity possible. · Members of the Organizing Committee who gave very generously of their time and services in defining the scope of the conference, in selecting the topics to be discussed and in designating the authors and conference participants. · The California Advisory Committee which assisted with the planning and implementation of conference logistics and arrangements. · The authors and discussants who accepted defined writing assignments and who cooperated in developing an integrated symposium. · Conference participants for their review of the essays and their useful critiques in the conference deliberations. · Jack D. Johnson, the initial chairman of the Directorate on Arid Zone Ecosystems, who continued to provide enthusiastic support for this venture as a member of the Organizing Committee. · Robert M. Hagan for his outstanding leadership and effort as chairman of the Directorate and of the conference Organizing Committee, and for continuously infusing all of his associates with the significance of this educational undertaking. · Marcia Kreith for exceptional service as administrative coordinator of the conference, a person who deserves high praise for seeing that all activities were implemented on schedule. · Raymond H. Coppock for providing expert informational services throughout the planning and implementation of the conference.
―x― · Noreen Dowling whose administrative talents and communication skills were helpful in many ways. · The staff of the University of California, Davis, who provided invaluable assistance at various stages of this undertaking, notably Betty Esky of the Department of Land, Air and Water Resources for secretarial services, Marian Cain, Kelly Carner and Paula Sullivan of the Public Service Research and Dissemination Program for administrative and secretarial services, together with Patricia Farid of the Water Resources Center, for assistance in the preparation and publication of this volume. THE EDITORS
― xi ―
INTRODUCTION— NO SIMPLE SOLUTIONS by Ann F. Scheuring, Ernest A. Engelbert, and Robert M. Hagan We are approaching the end of an era in the West. As with most such transitions, it is a period of some confusion and conflict. The era in question is that of seemingly unlimited western water development. We have begun to realize that there are indeed limits to the water resource base, that we will have to learn to live within them, and that we must come to agreement on priorities for use of water supplies in the future. The subject of this book is whether and how irrigated agriculture in the West will be affected by these new perceptions and changing conditions in water management. Water is the lifeblood of the West as we know it today. Much of the semiarid western landscape has been altered over the past century by human manipulation of scattered natural water supplies. In many locations irrigated farming has replaced native vegetation and dryland ranching, bringing new productivity to the land and improving local economies. With increasingly uncertain outlook for water supplies in the future, however, new adjustments may have to be made within the agricultural sector. Plans for further expansion of irrigation may have to be cancelled and some land now under irrigation may revert to semiarid conditions, unless accommodations to the increasing constraints on water supply can be made. Both competition
for limited resources and changing viewpoints on social utility challenge former assumptions about the "best use" for water. Depending on which groups of citizens stand to lose or gain from change, the viewpoints they express are varied and sometimes contradictory. Where life is comfortable, people are apt to rationalize and seek technical "fixes" in the attempt to maintain the status quo. Others struggle to achieve a greater share of resources and degree of equity by negotiation or legislation. Change is not easy, but in the period of adjustment in water policy which lies inevitably before us, special-interest clashes and philosophic disagreements must be tempered by hope for reasonable and far-sighted action. Water issues in the West encompass such large areas and affect so many millions of people, that
―2― programs and policies must be truly collaborative to be acceptable. "There are no simple solutions—only intelligent choices."
What Is the West? As defined in this volume, the "West" consists of those 17 states west of the 98th meridian, from the Canadian to the Mexican borders. This is half of the United States in size, an immense and varied region, with its own geographic peculiarities, history, and ambiance. The West is no single place: it means different things to different people, depending on where they live—rolling plains; thundering rivers; rocky canyons; windswept salt flats; barren volcanic plateaus; marshy swamps; arid deserts; verdant valleys; forested mountains; ocean surf; shabby towns; comfortable cities; sophisticated metropolises. To describe the West in its physical entirety is difficult, but let us briefly try. The great green checkerboard of the agricultural Midwest gives way very gradually to the drier Great Plains. The Great Plains states include North Dakota, South Dakota, Nebraska, Kansas, Oklahoma, and Texas. Relatively thinly populated, with much distance between towns, these states are largely agricultural and produce huge grain crops. The Great Plains states slope upward to the Rockies. The regular geometry of cultivated square and rectangular fields gradually becomes browner, larger in scale, and irregularly contoured in the transition into the Rocky Mountain states of Montana, Wyoming, Colorado, and New Mexico. In these
states the mountainous backbone of North America trends south-tonorthwest from Mexico to Canada. Only a handful of cities appears in the immense mountainous landscape, and agriculture is limited to river valleys. Spurs and subranges of the Rockies continue west into the states of Idaho, Utah, and Arizona, merging gradually into the Great Western Desert—the high arid plateaus and salt flats of southwestern Idaho, western Utah, all of Nevada, and much of Arizona. In northwestern Arizona the Grand Canyon slashes through the high desert, cut by the Colorado River over eons of geologic time. Much of this four-state area is still relative wasteland, though scattered green settlements dot the occasional waterways.
―3― On their eastern borders the Pacific Coast states of Washington, Oregon, and California are also part of the semiarid western desert, but these states' climate is transformed by the Sierra Nevada and the Coast Ranges, as well as by the Pacific Ocean. Western Washington and Oregon and northern California are moist, mountainous, and thickly forested; rainfall and snowpack can be heavy. South of the Cascades and west of the Sierra, the 400-mile-long Central Valley of California displays a rich and varied agriculture, while most of the state's famous cities cluster along the coast. Southern California is, again, mostly desert except for coastal basins and valleys. Thus the West consists of several distinct major climatic zones, with varied topography, soils, and precipitation. With the exception of relatively humid western Washington and Oregon and northwestern California, however, most of the West is arid or semiarid, registering on average less than 20 inches of rainfall per year. It is a region which characteristically depends on irrigation for its agricultural productivity or is dry-farmed—and where, to meet agriculture's needs, the most intensive water developments in the world have taken place.
History: An Epoch of Development It was the fact of aridity, coupled with the immense distances and rough terrain, that discouraged early settlement of the region. Though Lewis and Clark explored the upper reaches of the West as early as 1805, only a relatively few hardy pioneers pushed through the trials and terrors of wagon train travel in the first half of the 19th century. The California Gold Rush in 1849, however, set off an explosion in population movement, and the following decades saw settlement throughout much of the West.
The Homestead Act of 1862 was intended to aid settlement of the U.S. by offering chunks of the public domain nearly free to anyone who would make a serious effort to develop a farm or ranch. In the semiarid West, however, it was soon learned that 160 acres—the original amount of land allowed for individual homesteads—was hardly sufficient. Subsequently the law was amended; in certain areas a homestead claim could be up to 640 acres, or a square mile, because of the low grazing capacity and limited agricultural possibilities of water-short country. By 1900, aided by the expansion of railroads, most of the West was at least thinly populated. The image of the "Old West" changed as its economy developed from mining and early livestock-grain agriculture to a more diversified base. As mining
―4― became industrialized, prospectors became figures of the past. In such states as Wyoming, Oklahoma, and California, oil was discovered in huge deposits, bringing a new kind of wealth. Water development brought in irrigation, changing farming patterns. The Depression impelled many dustbowl migrants to seek employment in the West. World War II also brought large numbers of people to the West for military reasons, and many of them remained or returned after the war to take advantage of the climate, the lifestyle, and the opportunities they saw. New industries began to populate the western states, particularly entertainment, communications, and aerospace in Southern California and high technology and electronics in other areas. More than a place, more than a history, the West also represents a mindset. In comparison with the humid eastern seaboard and fertile Midwest, the early West was not an easy place to settle. Perhaps it took special kinds of people to move into a raw, often hostile wilderness. Western pioneers were sometimes dreamers, sometimes renegades from polite society; but they saw opportunities for enterprise in a landscape that offered wealth for those who could take advantage of it. Speculators and ambitious settlers recognized chances for development of natural resources through ingenuity and emerging technology. Gold miners in California extracted billions of dollars in gold using extensive flumes for sluicing and hydraulic hoses for blasting away earth from mineral deposits. The Mormons in Utah were among the first to build networks of canals for irrigating farms wrested from the desert. Public policy also encouraged settlement, development, and even exploitation. Where water was in short supply, private efforts at impoundments and canals were supplemented by public funding after the turn of the century. Local water districts brought water consumers together
for development of resources through taxation. Sometimes decades in advance of their construction, grand plans were suggested for state and federal dams on the Missouri, Arkansas, and Pecos rivers of the Great Plains; for the Colorado of the Southwest; for the Columbia of the Northwest; and for the Sacramento and San Joaquin valley watersheds in California. Boulder Dam, later called Hoover, harnessed the Colorado River in 1936, and Bonneville Dam spanned the Columbia in 1937. In Montana, Fort Peck Dam controlled the upper Missouri River in 1940. California's Central Valley Project completed Shasta Dam in 1944; Garrison Dam in North
―5― Dakota was finished in 1960; and the California State Water Project brought additional irrigation and power to California starting with Oroville Dam on the Feather River in 1968. These gigantic dams and canals, pumps and pipelines to store and transfer water, are a symbol of today's West. They stand as monuments to human ambition, in a remarkable blending of engineering and socio-economic vision. Where cattle and sheep and dryland grain were once the agricultural mode, some western states have diversified into row and vegetable crops, orchards, vineyards, and a host of specialty crops. None of this would have been possible without irrigation. In 1977 the 17 western states had 49 million acres of irrigated land, or 85 percent of all irrigated land in the U.S., and accounted for 91 percent of all water used for irrigation in the nation. Massive interbasin water transfers are a way of life in parts of the West. Irrigated agriculture produces a great deal of income. California alone, for example, has led the nation in cash farm receipts for more than 30 consecutive years. The state earned about $14 billion in revenues from agriculture in 1981, or about 10 percent of national gross cash receipts from farming. California produces more than 200 different agricultural commodities, many of them grown nowhere else in the nation and in few other places in the world (almonds, artichokes, Brussels sprouts, nectarines, olives, prunes, walnuts, to name a few). Approximately 30 percent of California's total agricultural revenue is now earned in export markets, accounting for nearly 10 percent of total U.S. agricultural exports in dollar volume. And it is the 8.5 million acres of irrigated California farmland which produces the bulk of California's farm income.
A New Era Why does it now appear that the West is approaching a new era? Resource development over the last century has resulted in a dynamic economy. What signs suggest that this era of development is ending? Western states are still very young historically—Arizona was the last continental state to be created,
in 1914. With the vast open spaces and resources yet remaining in the West, one might think that there are potentially many years of development still ahead. There are, in fact, planned stages of such massive undertakings as the Missouri River Basin Project and California's State Water Project not yet under construction. The physical facts, however, are plain: almost all the potentially good agricultural land close to water supplies has already
―6― been developed. Moreover, most of the readily available water sources of the West have been accessed; certainly all of the relatively inexpensive sources have already been tapped. Few rivers are without dams, and most of the major rivers have whole series of them. Reservoirs, giant and small, dot the western states. In addition, groundwater supplies in some areas are being measurably depleted as ever deeper wells draw up water from aquifers. In some areas land subsidence signals serious sinking of the water table. In certain locales water quality has also become a problem, with increased salinity of supplies or deterioration through chemical and other pollution. Thus even the same quantity of water supply becomes less usable for former purposes. In some cases stream diversions or impoundments have destroyed or severely damaged formerly abundant natural wildlife habitat and fisheries. In addition, economic balances are changing. We have had clear warnings of coming energy shortages. Given our addiction to massive consumption of fossil fuels, energy equations for pumping water will change radically as such fuels begin to run out. Construction and development costs have soared over the decades, and it is likely that even where new dams and storage projects have been considered technically feasible, they may not be affordable. Social viewpoints are also changing. Agriculture may once have been the hub upon which western economies turned, but as areas diversify, competition between uses for water increases. Industry has need for water in manufacturing, for cleansing, and for power; commercial fisheries and forestry require water to sustain their natural base; cities demand water for residential and municipal purposes; and recreationists value such waterrelated amenities as boating, swimming, and sport fishing. Nor is economic competition the whole story. U.S. society has seen the rise of what is termed the conservation ethic, under which the natural environment is valued as much for itself as for its exploitable potential. Some citizens protest what they perceive as the narrow view that a resource has value only insofar as it can be made productive for human purposes. They argue that biologic diversity and aesthetic values must be safeguarded for future generations; that every stream need not be dammed, every acre
planted, every drop of water "used." Thus we find ourselves at a turning point, and it is not clear how rapidly we will change course. We know, however, that our course will change. The question is, to what extent will we choose the direction?
―7―
Issues and Choices At issue in this book is whether irrigated agriculture in the West as we know it today is truly in jeopardy—and whether, after all, it matters. We know some things, and can guess at others: 1) In some areas of the West it has taken a massive public investment to bring surface water onto arid lands which could otherwise not support modern agriculture—and the subsidy continues in the form of reduced water prices for irrigation. 2) In several areas of the West groundwater supplies are being depleted, endangering the future viability of farming communities. 3) Agricultural irrigation now accounts for about 85 percent of developed water put to use in such states as California, but increasing demands for water for other purposes will in some regions of the West cut into agriculture's current supplies. 4) Water quality is deteriorating in some areas, soil quality in others. Salinization, for example, presently affects large acreages. One answer to salination is to build drains and use more water for flushing salts away, but this requires both sufficient water and adequate engineering, and is costly. Another reaction to the problem is simply to abandon the land because it is too expensive to reclaim. 5) The outlook for developing significant new surface water supplies to meet increasing demands is questionable, given limited sites for development, soaring construction costs, and voter skepticism. 6) Certain peripheral effects related to use of water for irrigation (including loss of fish and wildlife, increased erosion, pollution from agricultural chemicals in runoff, etc.) suggest that long-term adjustments in water use may be necessary.
7) Long-range data on climatic cycles indicate that recent decades may have been unusually moist in the West, and that extended periods of drought may lie ahead. Thus even our present estimate of water supplies may be more sanguine than history warrants. Such facts and reasonable guesses would indicate that western agriculture is, if not in jeopardy, slated for some considerable changes in future. It is clear that local circumstances vary considerably, and that different areas will have different problems
―8― and pressures. But overall it seems fair to say that irrigated agriculture in the West may not be totally sustainable under its present arrangements. We may indeed find that the "blooming of the desert" was, in some cases, an exciting but temporary phenomenon. Already in a few places abandoned cropland gives mute testimony to past doomed efforts at cultivation. Does this matter? Is it important that present-day irrigated agriculture in the West be "saved?" Are there, in fact, ways to moderate trends and stave off local crises? The first and second questions are matters of economic and social judgment. Western agriculture contributes significantly to the nation's food and fiber supply, and to the U.S. balance of payments in world markets. Nevertheless, the West is only part of the larger nation; and if one production region should fail, another may take up the slack. According to some observers, the primary U.S. agricultural problem today is over-supply, not insufficiency. But today's balance of supply and demand is not necessarily that of the 21st century—and national and world populations are growing. Usually discussions of the importance of agriculture are couched in economic terms, but a sociological dimension also needs recognition. Part of the ambiance of the West is its farming and ranching base. Deterioration or destruction of that base might alter the very character of the region. Again, this is a matter of judgment: does it matter? Many civilizations as well as regional cultures have come and gone. Is the West in its present condition uniquely worth supporting? Is the way of life in the West—which many have admired—one which ought to be preserved? The third question asks what options may be available to deal with pressures on agricultural water supplies. These options may be divided generally into four categories: technical and scientific innovations; management strategies; institutional arrangements; and modification of lifestyle. These are not mutually exclusive, and may in fact be used in many combinations, depending on water use situations. We rank them here in order from the
local and specific (on-farm practices) to the very broad and general (societal change). Technical and scientific innovations. These may include improved irrigation technologies, better plant breeding for drought resistance, precise monitoring of water needs, systematic groundwater replenishment, and other kinds of water-using and water-conserving techniques. Advances in science and
―9― technology can be a major factor in ameliorating the consequences of water shortages throughout the West. Management strategies. Recent years have shown that agriculture can pursue a variety of management strategies to achieve more efficient water use. These strategies include appropriate use of crops, careful water scheduling and recycling, effective employment of machinery, good economic and financial determinations, and all other aspects of farm decision making involving land and water practices. Institutional arrangements. Realignment and reorganization of existing institutions dealing with water, both public and private, may be helpful in cutting waste and in encouraging collaborative overall efficiency. Building flexibility into institutional arrangements may also help them respond to local needs more effectively. Modification of lifestyle. Economic sustainability may ultimately have to be based on lower economic expectations, both among individuals and in society at large. If nonrenewable resources are being depleted and even renewable resources seem under great pressure, one logical answer to the problem may be for consumers to be satisfied with less consumption. An exploitative tendency can be replaced with a philosophy of stewardship, though this may take years of experience and education. Social equity also demands commitment to reasonable goals by all citizens, not just by some. Underlying any options for action to address water problems are certain basic philosophic principles, all of them related, which can be mentioned here only as questions for public debate in a democratic society: · What balance between economic laissez-faire and institutional regulation is desirable? · What balance between local control and centralized decision-making is
best? · Is incrementalism or long-range planning preferable? Decisions for action (or nonaction) will inevitably reflect answers to these central questions.
An Overview of this Volume This book has been designed to discuss the western water situation from multiple perspectives. Water policy is by its nature complex and must be approached from several points of view. This book therefore attempts to review economic and social
― 10 ― as well as scientific and technical information relevant to the assessment of desirable policy. Each main chapter is accompanied by commentaries which provide additional information or suggest other facets of the subject under discussion. Part I provides an overview of the facts and conditions of water availability in the semiarid West, first from the hydrological perspective and then from institutional and economic perspectives. Chapter 1 gives information on precipitation, streamflows, and important aquifers in the West, and identifies areas where water supplies appear critical. Chapter 2 describes water law and institutions which govern water allocation. This chapter suggests that many western states will have to make some changes in legal and institutional arrangements to achieve greater efficiency in water use and management. Chapter 3 reviews trends in competition for water among economic sectors. Many areas of the West face shifts in water use from one industrial sector to another; this will have significant impact upon local economies, particularly agricultural communities. Part II consists of six chapters describing possible alternatives for satisfying water demands by western agriculture. Chapter 4 explores the alternatives for developing new water supplies to meet increasing demands. It concludes that the opportunities for large scale augmentation of present supplies are limited and that no significant technological breakthroughs are in sight. Chapter 5 examines the possibilities for increasing the efficiency of nonagricultural water use. While some savings in urban-industrial uses can be made, the gains will not be sufficient to cover the impending shortages in agricultural water needs. Chapter 6 describes research on management strategies to cope with increasing soil salinity in semiarid regions. This increasing salinity, the most extensive irrigation-caused problem faced by
western agriculture, will call for a diversity of techniques and controls to improve the situation. Chapters 7, 8, and 9 review current on-farm methods for improving crop management, land use, and irrigation systems. Chapter 7 discusses crop shifts, use of drought-resistant crops, and improved production techniques. Indications are that in the future farmers will have to modify many present cropping patterns to maintain optimum production with declining water supplies. Chapter 8 reports on proven ways to sustain arid-land agriculture through water "harvesting," minimum tillage, snow management, and other practices. An expansion of dry-land agriculture appears inevitable for many areas of the semiarid West.
― 11 ― Chapter 9 treats engineering improvements that can be made in irrigation systems. It concludes that massive changes in conveyance and application systems will provide only a modest increase in net water supply for agriculture. Part III encompasses six chapters that focus upon the economic, social, and environmental impacts of limited water supplies in the West. Chapter 10 looks at the impacts of less water upon regional and local economies. The evidence suggests that while irrigated agriculture will face some retrenchment, the overall regional economic impacts should be gradual and minor. Chapter 11 analyzes the impending decline of irrigated agriculture in the West from the standpoint of the national and international agricultural commodity systems. Using an econometric model, the chapter concludes that, depending upon economic and institutional variables, reduced water supplies will result in only slight food price increases in both the domestic and international markets. Chapter 12 examines the impact of limited water supplies upon business communities in the West. Increasing water prices will result in a more intensive agriculture, with consequent implications for land values, agribusiness enterprises, banking, and other economic sectors. Chapter 13 discusses what will happen to rural communities if irrigated agriculture declines. It predicts considerable unemployment and social suffering unless remedial actions are taken to diversify local economies. Chapter 14 looks at the impact of the changing agricultural base upon urban communities. Serious unemployment problems for cities arising from a ruralurban migration are not expected since the numbers of people affected by a declining western agriculture would be relatively small. Chapter 15 considers the environmental consequences of agricultural land going out of production. Reversion of land to dryland farming or to nonuse may, unless corrective actions are taken, result in wind erosion and damage to fish and wildlife habitats.
Part IV outlines some strategies for maintaining agricultural viability in the West with limited water. Chapter 16 describes some specific technical and management solutions to water problems from the farmer's viewpoint. The chapter shows that farmers can be innovative in adjusting to declining and higher-priced water supplies. Chapter 17 examines how business and financial interests can respond. Emphasis is placed upon the need for more research and development, upon appropriate systems of financing, and upon better cooperation between the business and agricultural sectors. Chapter 18 discusses changes in the system
― 12 ― for the allocation and transfer of water supplies. It calls for the evolution of an economic market system for water rights so that water may move to the geographical areas and sectors of most valued use. Two chapters, 19 and 20, address state and national water policies and practices. The state of Montana's efforts for water resources management are described in Chapter 19, while Chapter 20 chronicles the shift in federal policy to encourage state initiative and the deregulation of water markets. The complexities of government policies and programs for water resources are reflected in both chapters, and the need for intergovernmental cooperation is emphasized. Part V provides an integrative summary of the major problems and findings of the preceding chapters. Subjects are interrelated and placed in perspective. Issues which need to be resolved are identified. The challenges facing western water planners are highlighted. A number of views emerge from this book, although they are not held equally by all authors: 1) There is no immediate national crisis with respect to water for western agriculture. 2) Some regional impacts due to local decreasing water supplies are inevitable, and some local and individual situations could become traumatic. 3) It is difficult to predict when future adverse impacts will become evident because adjustments may still be made. 4) Impacts of declining water supplies may be partly offset by technical and institutional adjustments, some of which are already taking place.
5) Much uncertainty exists because of economic, political, climatic, demographic, and other variables. 6) Assessments of water supply and demand, to some extent circumstantial, may change in the future. 7) Lack of a present crisis does not preclude a future crisis caused by increasing population, growing world food and energy needs, and possible climatic changes. 8) Since the federal role in water policy appears to be decreasing, local and private sector initiative may have to fill in any gaps. 9) Several chapters suggest that allocation and transfer of water might be in some cases appropriately implemented through the marketplace.
― 13 ― These varied views emerging from the chapters suggest how complex and challenging is the subject of water in the West. Future studies and decisions, as our authors remind us, must truly be both interdisciplinary and collaborative.
The Future of Water in the West Why Planning Is Difficult The summary chapter of this volume suggests several factors which make rational overall water planning difficult: (1) territorialism and ownership disputes; (2) uncertainty about key facts; (3) political evolution; (4) an ongoing shift in ethos; and (5) a certain apathy, or at least a tendency toward inaction, without a crisis for motivation. All of these are significant constraints on our ability to plan for the future. Few of us would disagree, however, that some kind of planning for the future is prudent, if not without risks. It is clear that some areas of the West will inevitably experience problems as water supplies become increasingly strained to their limits. Several areas are already identified as being in "critical overdraft," i.e., the condition in which water supplies are being depleted faster than they can be replaced. There is not much doubt that these areas will likely experience serious economic discomfort as water becomes more scarce and dear. The rumblings of these dislocations are already being felt.
We can make certain predictions on what may happen in farming communities where overdraft trends continue. There will be more financial risk and failure for farmers; there will be changes in crops and in irrigation methods; some acreage may be phased out of production. Land values may decline, the tax base may shrink, farm-related businesses may suffer, communities may decline as the economic base erodes. Water availability will certainly influence the distribution of income and wealth between areas. There will be transfer of wealth out of water-short areas into those with more abundant supplies; the decline of income in one area will be picked up elsewhere. Agriculture is nevertheless an adaptive system. It can adjust in a variety of ways to limited water; or water can be transferred among agricultural regions. Such adjustments need not be disastrous, and some of them are already currently taking place. To encourage rational conservation activities and to alleviate widespread impacts from water shortages, it behooves water planners on various levels of government to take as clear a look at water planning for the future as is possible.
― 14 ― Much of our uncertainty as to prediction stems from the nature of certain variables—climate, energy, population, and political events, to name only a few. In many ways our crystal ball is cloudy, and must remain so. With regard to climate, for example, the commentary to Chapter 1 suggests that the West may be experiencing an unusually moist few decades in the 20th century, compared to other eras recorded in existing western tree ring data. If climate altered substantially over a period of years—which is entirely possible—our current estimates of surface and groundwater supplies would have to be radically revised. Current international markets also figure prominently into the U.S. agricultural picture. Disruption of these markets through political events or economic upheavals could change supply-demand equations drastically, and thus incentives for agricultural production. Energy, as an essential component in the pumping of water, also remains an uncertain variable, with the only sure prediction being that prices for fossil fuels will go up. But how fast? How far? Population trends are another question mark. U.S. and world population is sure to expand in the decades ahead, increasing food needs; but we don't know the magnitude of population expansion to expect, nor do we know how other world regions will deal with the needs of their peoples. Dire warnings have been made about world population trends and future food needs, but
even the experts disagree. It is difficult to make long-range plans when there are so many admitted uncertainties, but we know that we should at least be prepared to cope rationally with emerging possibilities. Western water planners will deal best with an uncertain future if they are able to direct their activities along reasonably logical lines.
Needs for Action Many of the chapters in this volume explicitly or implicitly recommend certain kinds of action to be taken on a number of fronts. Briefly, we condense and list these recommendations here: · Research and information gathering on consumptive and environmental water needs, including more agreement on methodologies of analysis to be employed. · Widespread adoption of efficient and cost-effective water management and conservation techniques, including conjunctive use of ground and surface waters in basins.
― 15 ― · Investigation of feasible new water developments in certain specific locations. · More availability of capital for long-range water management goals, at both local and regional levels. · Appropriate provision for environmental and social needs in water management and use. · More innovation in interorganizational planning, particularly at the local level. · Removal of institutional barriers to economic freedom in decision making. · More collaboration between federal government and states in management of projects and coordination of policies.
· Better cooperation and more compromise among interest groups representing water users. These calls for action seem to fall into two general categories: the gathering of more information and knowledge on such matters as environmental interrelationships, technical and scientific innovations, management possibilities, and economic systems; and the building of more flexibility and cooperation into institutions and organizations concerned with water. Those who live in the western United States have both the opportunity and the challenge to show other water-deficient areas of the world how limited water resources can be managed not only for regional well being, but for the ultimate benefit of mankind.
A New Stage of History Unlike any other era in human history, we of the later 20th century have the capacity to look at our globe as a whole. The astronauts who first looked back on the Earth from space were struck with both the beauty of the planet and its vulnerability. Suddenly we know that the Earth is fragile; we have begun to realize that there are limits to natural resources, and to our human activities. Our era is crucially different from those which have gone before. We have greater scientific and technological power—both constructive and destructive —to change our surroundings. We have more knowledge at our fingertips, more ability to gather new information, more power to integrate and transmit it. We realize, and can learn from, mistakes of the past. Our electorate is less likely to foot costly projects, more likely to question motives and intent, and more likely to recognize their own interests. As we grapple with the problems of the present, we have a sense for the complexities inherent in our choices. Perhaps it is that consciousness of complexity which will allow us to become a more mature society, no longer committed to simple
― 16 ― solutions, but able to take a wise and balanced view of the resources of our planet—of the West—not only as they will serve us in the short run, but as they will sustain us over time.
― 17 ―
PART I— WATER AVAILABILITY FOR AGRICULTURE IN THE SEMIARID WEST Chapter 1— Physical Limitations of Water Resources by John Bredehoeft
Abstract In considering the concept of the hydrologic cycle today one must take into account man's influence as an integral part of the functioning of the cycle. Except for the mining of groundwater, the same quantity of water is, on the average, in transit in the hydrologic cycle. Groundwater mining is extensive, especially in Arizona and the High Plains of Texas and New Mexico. Groundwater, however, is a one-time supply; to the extent that we mine it, we are faced with a shortage in the future. Both urban movement to the Southwest and energy development compete with agriculture for the available supply, especially in the areas of critical water supply, southern California and Arizona. Competition is present throughout the semiarid West; anywhere water is fully appropriated, increased urban and industrial supplies must come from agriculture. There seems little doubt that as we approach the limits of available water supply there will be increasing competition for water. In a classic economic sense increased competition implies a shortage.
The water supply of the West is nearly fully utilized. It is difficult to foresee major construction projects which will add significantly to the currently available supply. Several critical areas are now heavily dependent upon mining groundwater, a supply which will be depleted at some point in the future. Urban and energy developments, especially in the Southwest, are competing with agriculture for the available water. This competition will undoubtedly intensify, which poses two major issues for society: 1) How will society, at local, state, and regional levels, cope with the increased competition for water? 2) To what extent can the nation forego irrigated agriculture in the West
without significantly decreasing its agricultural output?
― 18 ― It is not the intent of this chapter to address these issues; however, we will attempt to provide an overview of the current availability of water.
The Hydrologic Cycle Traditionally, when considering the problems of water resources we hydrologists have been prone to think in terms of virgin or natural streamflow. However, it has become increasingly obvious that natural flow is a relict of the distant past. Man has impacted the water resources so dramatically, especially in the arid and semiarid West, that natural flow does not exist except perhaps in the most remote areas. We must recognize that man's activities are today an integral and inseparable part of the hydrologic cycle. Our current understanding of the hydrologic cycle can be described in a paradigm suggested by Matalas, Landwehr, and Wolman. The three tenets of the active paradigm are: i) human activity is inseparable from the natural system; ii) quality is no less a concern than quantity of the water mass as it is distributed and moves through the cycle; iii) the quantity of the water mass affects and is affected by the quality of the water.[1] If we accept the active paradigm as best characterizing our concept of the hydrologic cycle, then it is impossible to look at the physical and chemical limitations on water resources without looking at man's activities.
Available Water Precipitation ultimately is the source of water resources. The average annual precipitation for the United States is depicted in Figure 1.1. That precipitation translates into runoff. West of the 100th meridian much of the land is characterized by less than one inch of runoff. The areas of abundant runoff in the West are easily identified in Figure 1.2. The relative magnitude of the average streamflow of the large rivers in the U.S. is shown in Figure 1.3. The major rivers of interest in the western states are the Columbia, the
Colorado, the Sacramento, the Missouri, and
― 19 ―
Figure 1.1 Average Annual U.S. Precipitation, 1931-1960 Source: U.S. Council on Environmental Quality, Environmental Trends, Washington, D.C., 1981, p. 346.
― 20 ―
Figure 1.2 Average Annual U.S. Runoff Source: Rickert, D.G., W.J. Ulman, and E.R. Hampton, Synthetic Fuels Development—Earth Sciences Considerations, U.S. Geologic Survey, 1979, p.45.
― 21 ―
Figure 1.3 Average U.S. Streamflow, 1941-1970 Source: U.S. Water Resources Council, Essentials of Ground Water Hydrology Pertinent to Water Resources Planning, Bulletin 16, revised 1979, p.48.
their tributaries. Future large-scale surface water diversions must almost certainly come from these river systems. Runoff comes largely from the mountains in the spring as snowmelt. The typical seasonal variation is illustrated by the long-term average monthly runoff for the Clarks Fork of the Yellowstone River near Belfrey, Montana, Figure 1.4. Storage of water, either in surface reservoirs or in aquifers, improves the timing between supply and demand, especially the seasonal demand for agriculture.
― 22 ―
Figure 1.4 Average Monthly Runoff, Clarks Fork of Yellowstone River Source: Rickert et al. Groundwater forms an additional resource. The important aquifers of the western United States are shown in Figure 1.5.
Depletion of Water Given our picture of surface and groundwater, how much is utilized? Relative water depletion is depicted in Figure 1.6. Depletion is defined as "the total consumptive use plus any water exported from each basin, divided by the total supply". Groundwater mining has been excluded from the long-term supply. This is perhaps the most important single illustration in this paper. Several critical areas show up on the map of depletion: 1) Most of the lower Colorado River basin, southern California, and most of Nevada, where the depletion
― 23 ―
Figure 1.5 Extensive Aquifers of the U.S. Source: U.S. Water Resources Council, 1979.
― 24 ―
Figure 1.6 Relative Water Depletion in the U.S. Source: Rickert et al.
― 25 ― exceeds 100 percent. The differences are made up from mining groundwater. 2) South-central California, including the San Joaquin and Owens Valleys, where the depletion exceeds 75 percent. 3) The High Plains of Colorado and west Texas, where the depletion exceeds 75 percent. 4) Much of New Mexico, where the depletion exceeds 75 percent. The depletion map is somewhat misleading, since instream flow requirements are not accounted for, and they are important constraints on water availability. Groundwater constitutes an important additional source of water. Groundwater withdrawals are shown in Figure 1.7. California and Texas are the two largest users of groundwater, accounting for 37 percent of the total withdrawn nationwide, closely followed by Nebraska, Idaho, Kansas, and
Arizona, which together account for an additional 26 percent of the total. These six states account for almost two-thirds of the groundwater withdrawn in the United States. The relative importance of groundwater as a source of water in the semiarid West is depicted in Figure 1.8. Groundwater constitutes the major source of water, exceeding approximately 50 percent in much of the High Plains, a large portion of Arizona, and parts of California. Much of the groundwater withdrawn is being mined. The Second National Water Assessment of the U.S. Water Resources Council[2] identified areas of groundwater overdraft—"mining" in my terminology—as shown in Figure 1.9. The principal areas of overdraft identified west of the 100th meridian are (1) the high plains of Texas, New Mexico, Colorado, Oklahoma, and Kansas, and (2) large areas of Arizona. Moderate overdrafts occur over much of the area west of the 100th meridian.
Water Use How is the water used? Figure 1.10 is a graph of water withdrawals for the period 1950 through 1975 for the entire U.S. The
― 26 ―
Figure 1.7 U.S. Groundwater Withdrawals, 1975 (million gallons per day) Source: U.S. Water Resources Council, 1979.
― 27 ―
Figure 1.8 U.S. Groundwater Withdrawals, 1975 (percent of fresh water used from groundwater sources) Source: CEQ, 1981.
― 28 ―
Figure 1.9 U.S. Groundwater Overdraft Source: CEQ, 1981.
― 29 ―
Figure 1.10 U.S. Water Withdrawals, by Use, 1950-1975 Source: CEQ, 1981. largest withdrawals are for power plant cooling and irrigation. Consumptive use, on the other hand, presents a very different picture. Figure 1.11 shows nationwide water consumption. Irrigation accounts for by far the largest fraction of consumption. In the western states irrigation accounts for more than 90 percent of the consumptive use. Groundwater use is also interesting; the growth in groundwater withdrawal over the last 25 years has been almost exclusively for irrigation, as is shown in Figure 1.12. In 1977 42 million acres were irrigated, for which the consumption was approximately 82 billion gallons a day (92 million acre-feet per year). Something approaching one third to one half of that water came from groundwater, much of which was mined, as Figure 1.9 indicates.
― 30 ―
Figure 1.11 U.S. Water Consumption by Use, 1950-1975 Source: CEQ, 1981.
Figure 1.12 U.S. Groundwater Use, 1950-1975
― 31 ― Eighty-four percent of the fresh water consumed in the coterminous United States is consumed in the 17 western states; most is utilized for agriculture. The acreages irrigated in the 17 western states are given in Table 1.1. California accounts for 23 percent of the total acreage; together, Texas and California account for 42 percent of the total.
Table 1.1 Irrigated Acreage in the 17 Western States, 1975 State
Acreage (millions)
California
8.7
Texas
6.9
Nebraska
3.3
Colorado
2.9
Idaho
2.9
Montana
1.9
Kansas
1.6
Oregon
1.6
Wyoming
1.5
Arizona
1.2
Washington
1.2
Utah
1.1
New Mexico
0.9
Nevada
0.8
Oklahoma
0.5
South Dakota
0.2
North Dakota
0.1
Total
37.3
Source: U.S. Soil Conservation Service, Crop Consumptive Irrigation
Requirements and Irrigation Efficiency Coefficients for the United States, U.S. Department of Agriculture, 1976, p. 24.
― 32 ― Looking at statistics for the nation as a whole may appear to be somewhat misleading. However, since the 17 western states dominate the consumptive use, consuming 84 percent, the statistics for the nation are strongly influenced by the West, where agriculture is the primary consumer of water.
The Lower Colorado Basin In any overview of the water resources of the semiarid West, the lower Colorado River basin and southern California stand out as the most critical areas for water. Another look at the depletion map, Figure 1.6, indicates that the water supply is more than 100 percent depleted in these areas. This is substantiated by the overdraft of groundwater shown in Figure 1.9. The Colorado River is the principal long-term source of water for much of this area. Stockton and Jacoby,[3] utilizing tree-ring data, reconstructed Colorado River streamflow back to 1512. Using this record they estimated the mean annual flow at 13.5 million acre-feet. This is approximately 2 million acre-feet less than anticipated when the water rights were divided in the 1922 Colorado River Compact. Unfortunately, the 1922 Compact was based on records of flow during a series of unusually wet years from 1906 to 1920. The availability of water from the Colorado is further complicated by a number of Indian claims upon the river which are as yet unresolved. A synthesized record of the flow of the Colorado River below all major diversions, in Figure 1.13, portrays the outflow of the river into the Gulf of California. The downward trend of the residual flow, which is caused by an increasing use of water from the Colorado River, is evident. Usage by Mexico as well as by the United States is reflected in the residuals. (Under the terms of a treaty between the United States and Mexico in 1944, supplemented by various "minutes" and negotiations, Mexico is allotted an annual quantity of 1.5 million acre-feet.) Diversions from the Colorado began considerably before 1900. However, prior to that year, annual net diversions generally were less than 1.0 million acre-feet. The residual flows during 1935-39 were unusually low, largely because of the initial filling of Lake Mead. Low flows from 1960 to 1978 reflect nearly complete use of the river. In 1979 and 1980, major floods in
the Lower Colorado River basin downstream from the principal reservoirs resulted in larger outflows.
― 33 ―
Figure 1.13 Annual Flow of Colorado River Above All Major Diversions, 1910-1980 Clearly all the water in the Colorado is currently utilized. The consumptive use within the basin is compared with entitlements from the river in Figure 1.14. The large consumptive use in Arizona is made up in part by groundwater mining. The water in the Colorado is also plagued by an increasing load of dissolved salts. This load comes from a number of natural sources and from sources which are the result of man's actions. Approximately one third of the total salt load is the result of irrigation. Another 10 percent or so comes from Flaming Gorge Reservoir and from Lake Mead, where salts are being leached from geologic deposits inundated by the reservoirs. Figure 1.15 attempts to summarize both the concentration of dissolved solids as well as the total salt load.
― 34 ―
Figure 1.14 Consumptive Uses and Losses of Water in the Colorado River System, 1971-1975 Averages Water is in short supply in the Lower Colorado River basin. Population statistics indicate a growth in urbanization both in Arizona and southern California. If urban growth is to continue, there will undoubtedly be pressure to shift water away from agricultural use.
― 35 ―
Figure 1.15
Salt Load in the Colorado River, 1941-1978 Averages
Alternatives for Additional Water Supplies A number of alternatives have been discussed for increasing the water supply. These are categorized for the purpose of discussion into: (1) increased surface storage; (2) increased groundwater development; (3) more efficiency of water utilization; and (4) large-scale interbasin transfers of water.
Increased Surface Storage Surface storage is the traditional method of providing additional available water. Additional reservoir sites exist in some parts of the western states. Langbein[4] has reviewed historic trends in reservoir development in the U.S. Table 1.2, taken
― 36 ―
Table 1.2 Reservoir Capacity in Some Major River Basins of the United States Region or Basin
Date
Total Usable Capacity (existing plus potential, million acrefeet)
Drainage Area (1000 sq.mi.)
Unit Capacity (acre-feet per sq.mi.)
North Atlantic Region
1966
47.9
173
280
Potomac River
1963
3.9
14
275
Colorado River
1946
102
250
400
Missouri
1969
137
500
270
River Southeast Region
1963
26
88
300
Columbia River
1946
52
220
235
Source: W.B. Langbein, Dams, Reservoirs and Withdrawals for Water Supply—Historic Trends.
from Langbein, shows the reservoir capacity currently available in a number of the major river basins of the country. Langbein has suggested that a unit capacity of approximately 400 acre-feet of storage per square mile of drainage area represents a potential limit for reservoir development; the Colorado has a potential unit capacity of 400 acre-feet per square mile. Langbein also plotted the historic trend of reservoir capacity; this plot is shown in Figure 1.16. The growth in capacity for all purposes and for withdrawal has flattened out since 1960. The question is whether this reduction in reservoir construction will continue, or if it is simply an aberration in long-term growth curve.
― 37 ―
Figure 1.16
Usable Major Reservoir Capacity in the U.S. since 1920 Source: Langbein, 1982. Our assessment is that surface reservoirs will continue to be increasingly difficult to develop. Recent legislation such as the National Environmental Protection Act (NEPA) makes it easier for environmental groups to voice their interests. Every major new reservoir project seems likely to receive some resistance from opposing groups. Major conflicts will, in many instances, be settled politically. In arid regions such as the lower Colorado River basin, where water is particularly critical, additional reservoirs may evaporate as much or more water as is made available, thereby further concentrating the dissolved salts. Increasing surface storage in the lower Colorado is a losing proposition.
― 38 ―
Increased Groundwater Development Groundwater is already heavily utilized, as has been pointed out, much of its development resulting in mining of water. The increased costs of pumping imposed by increased energy costs have reduced groundwater pumping, especially in areas such as Arizona. The one area with apparent potential for a major increase in groundwater development is Nebraska. Table 1.3 is a compilation of the water in storage in the Ogallala Aquifer, the result of an ongoing U.S. Geological Survey study of the system. Approximately two thirds of the water in storage is in Nebraska, an enormous reserve of groundwater. Only in Texas and New Mexico has more than 10 percent of the water initially in storage been depleted. The depletion statistics may be somewhat misleading, since it is economically impractical to remove all the water initially in storage; perhaps 50 to 70 percent is a reasonable estimate of what might be removed under favorable economic conditions. These data indicate that only a small percentage of the water in the Ogallala has been removed. Obviously an enormous quantity of groundwater is still present for development in Nebraska.
More Effective Water Utilization A number of measures have been suggested to effect better utilization of water available. Among these, increased irrigation efficiency, weather modification, reuse of wastewater, conjunctive use of groundwater, desalination, and increased use of saline water have been considered.
Increased efficiency of irrigation has obvious advantages. But a major nagging question is: what happens to the salts in the system when one increases the efficiency? A study of a reach of the Arkansas[5] suggested that following an initial two-to-three-year period after increasing irrigation efficiency, groundwater in the shallow aquifer along the Arkansas River would become more saline. This increase in salinity of the groundwater would increase the salinity of the flow in the river. Pillsbury,[6] in an article in Scientific American entitled "The Salinity of Rivers", argues that salt buildup is a major problem for all irrigation projects. His thesis is that sufficient water must be applied to continually remove salt from the soils. Salt buildup seems to pose some limit on possibilities for increasing irrigation efficiency.
― 39 ―
Table 1.3 Water Supplies and Depletion in the Ogallala Aquifer Water in Storage Percent (1980) Depletion (acre-feet) (predevelopment to 1980) Colorado
112 (x 106 )
5
Kansas
300
8
Nebraska
2100
less than 1
New Mexico
48
16
Oklahoma
92
7
South Dakota
105
less than 1
Texas
375
23
Wyoming
138
less than 1
3270 (x 106 ) Source: Luckey, R.R., E.D. Gutentag, and J.B. Weeks, Water Level and Saturated-Thickness Changes, Predevelopment to 1980, in the High Plains Aquifer in Part of Colorado, Kansas, Nebraska, New Mexico, Oklahoma, South Dakota, Texas and Wyoming, Hydro. Invest. Atlas, U.S. Geological Survey, 1981.
In such systems as the South Platte, or the Arkansas in Colorado, or the lower Colorado, most of the water goes to support beneficial transpiration. It seems questionable that increased efficiency can materially add to the useful supply. Weather modification has received considerable attention. The data, although not totally conclusive, suggest that cloud seeding could increase precipitation locally, with a 10 percent increase in supply possible. The question remains as to what happens downwind—does cloud seeding reduce rainfall? This issue remains to be settled. However, it appears that some local increase in available supply is possible from weather modification.
― 40 ― Reuse of wastewater is another possible source of water. Reuse is already practiced in a number of places. In irrigation, reuse occurs through return flow, which replenishes the streamflow. Municipal wastes have been purchased in such areas as Phoenix, Arizona, for utilization in irrigation. The city of Irvine, California, reuses all of its wastewater, mostly for municipal irrigation. Major metropolitan areas along the coast continue to discharge some wastes to the sea. Some of this water could be reused beneficially. However, the costs of cleaning it up may be such as to preclude it for use in agricultural irrigation. The shallow aquifers in the earth provide an enormous fresh water reservoir. Many of these are already utilized extensively as active storage reservoirs. The conjunctive water use developments along the Platte, the Arkansas, the Rio Grande, and the Snake rivers are classic examples of utilization of the groundwater system as a storage reservoir. In certain areas such as the southern San Joaquin Valley in California,
groundwater reservoirs can be utilized to store water in periods of abundance. Already a number of such developments are well established elsewhere in California, particularly in Orange County and the Santa Clara Valley. The groundwater aquifer has obvious advantages for storage as only small surface areas are affected, evapotranspiration is greatly reduced, and in many places the aquifer serves as an excellent filter for the water. On the other hand, aquifer storage has the disadvantage that it is sometimes expensive to recharge groundwater, especially if one has to utilize wells. How much impact conjunctive use will have in the overall water management in the West is difficult to forecast at this time. The cost of desalinating water makes it too expensive, in most instances, for agriculture. However, the use of desalination for municipal and industrial use may reduce the competition for water currently utilized in agriculture. Saline water can also be utilized for industrial purposes such as cooling, and for special purposes such as slurrying coal. There is abundant saline groundwater over much of the West, and use of these resources could reduce the competition for water. How effective more efficient water utilization measures will be in making water available is anyone's guess. If collectively they could make available 10 percent of the water currently used in agriculture, this would approximately equal all of the other consumptive uses. Ten percent may be an achievable goal.
― 41 ―
Large-Scale Interbasin Transfers of Water Large-scale interbasin transfers, particularly to the lower Colorado River basin, have been proposed as a source of water for some time. The major interbasin transfers are shown in Figure 1.17. The two really significant transfers occur in the Colorado basin and in California. By far the largest of these transfers occurs in California. Traditionally, the states have primacy with respect to utilization of water. Large-scale interbasin transfers cannot take place without a change in state primacy. As water is perceived to be a critical commodity, state primacy will be harder and harder to change. We are pessimistic that this policy can be changed significantly to allow further large interbasin transfers between states. In fact the magnitude of the transfers in California has only been possible, in our judgment, because they occurred within a single state. Interbasin transfer continues to be a sensitive issue even in California, as witnessed by the 1982 referendum over the Peripheral Canal.
It seems problematical that major quantities of water are available for interbasin transfer. For example, Whittlesey and Gibbs,[7] who reviewed the utilization of water in the Columbia for hydropower, concluded that water for irrigation in central Washington costs the general public $150 per acre per year in increased energy costs. This cost comes from lost hydropower downstream and from large quantities of energy to supply supplemental irrigation water which is provided irrigators at very low rates. Under such circumstances it seems highly unlikely that Washington would allow additional water to be diverted for irrigation within the state, and certainly it would fight a major interbasin transfer to another state. Similar situations exist in other western states which, at first glance, appear to have "surplus" fresh water.
Conclusions It is increasingly difficult to effect major structural changes which would provide large quantities of water to those areas where water is in critical supply—southern California, Arizona, and the High Plains of Texas and New Mexico. Outside California, large interbasin transfers must face the issue of state primacy, a particularly difficult issue to overcome.
― 42 ―
Figure 1.17 Major Interbasin Water Transfers in the Western U.S. Source: Modified from Geraughty, J.J., D.W. Miller, F. Van Der Leeden, and F.L. Troise, Water Atlas of the United States, Water Information Center, Port Washington, N.Y., 1973.
― 43 ― One must turn to other measures to utilize more effectively the water that is currently available. Increased efficiency, weather modification, reuse, and conjunctive use, while perhaps not dramatic, have the potential to make better utilization of the available water supply. If collectively these measures could make available 10 percent of the water currently consumed by agriculture, that quantity would approximately equal the total of all other consumption in the West. On the average, the quantity of water in transport in the hydrologic cycle remains unchanged. Except for the fact that we are mining groundwater, no less water is available than heretofore. The fact that we are approaching the limit of the water which can be developed means that there is, and will continue to be, ever-increasing competition for that water. Increased competition implies a higher value for the commodity. While as a society we rarely make large-scale water decisions purely on economic grounds, higher value also implies a higher price. Thus, in the context of increased competition, we have a shortage, at least of inexpensive water. A number of areas in the West depend heavily upon groundwater for their supply. The areas of largest overdraft of groundwater are Arizona and the High Plains of Texas and New Mexico. Much of this water is a one-time supply, obtained by a "mining" operation. Although that is not necessarily bad, the supply is finite, and at some point, perhaps in the distant future, will be gone. Arizona has recently moved to strengthen its groundwater law to protect the resource. The drought of the mid-70s in California motivated farmers to drill many new wells to tide themselves through a period of shortage. Now that the wells are drilled, they continue to be pumped, demonstrating that additional supplies of surface water do not always ease the overdraft of groundwater. In many instances, new supplies bring more land into production. To the extent that we are mining groundwater, we are running out of water. The one bright spot in the water picture in the West is Nebraska, where a huge supply of groundwater is present in the aquifer. The figures on the Ogallala Aquifer in Nebraska suggest that this is probably the largest virtually untapped supply of water present in the 17 western states. There can be little doubt that we are entering an era of continually increasing competition for water. In the Southwest, where water shortage threatens most critically, increasing urbanization and increasing energy development both compete
― 44 ―
with agriculture, now the largest water consumer. Steve Reynolds, State Engineer of New Mexico, aptly states the current water situation when he says, "Water flows uphill toward money." To what extent agriculture in the West can accommodate the competition is the issue.
Discussion: Harold C. Fritts I see no significant weakness in Bredehoeft's lucid and concise discussion except that his projections are based upon relatively short hydrologic records. More specifically, paleoclimatic data indicate that worldwide climate changes occurred around the turn of the century—measurements such as Bredehoeft has used, which are confined to the 20th century, are likely to be biased by these changes. I have used tree-ring widths as proxy climate records (substitutes for instrumented data) to estimate the magnitude of this bias. The ring widths of approximately 1000 trees from sites throughout the West were calibrated with the 20th-century instrumented climatic record throughout the United States. The
― 45 ― calibration equation was then applied to past ring-width growth to estimate past variations in climate.[1] The estimates of climate were then verified with independent instrumented data[1], [2] available prior to the time period used for calibration. Finally, optimal reconstructions were selected based upon the best calibration and verification statistics.
When these procedures are applied to California precipitation[3] (Figure 1.18), pre-20th century precipitation is reconstructed to be below the 20th century mean; when a line is drawn through the plot, long periods of extended drought are evident. Figure 1.19a shows another analysis[4] in which the means for 1901-1970 temperature and annual precipitation in 11 North American regions were compared to the reconstructed means for 1602-1900. The 20th century was slightly cooler than the 17th-19th centuries for five regions in the West, and warmer for the remaining regions. It was 19 percent wetter in California (Region 2), above average in four additional southwestern regions, and dryer elsewhere. Thus one can see that when expectations for precipitation are based solely on this century they would overestimate the long-term expectations for
moisture because of recent anomalous trends in precipitation, particularly in California. Similarly, temperature projections would underestimate conditions west of the Rockies and overestimate them east of the Rockies. Figure 1.19b shows the standard deviations of the reconstructions in the West for the 20th century, compared to the standard deviations for three prior centuries. They indicate a lower variability in 20th-century climate, especially in the amount of precipitation. In addition, reconstructions of surface pressure[4] suggest that coastal storms became more southerly displaced around the turn of the century, bringing higher moisture into California and the Southwest during winter. These storms appear to have traveled on the average in a northeast direction through the Great Lakes. The resulting southerly air flow brought less moisture and warmer temperatures to the eastern portions of the country. Prior to the 20th century storms apparently entered the country more often over the Pacific Northwest, passed over the Rockies, and traveled eastward or southeastward, bringing colder temperatures and more moisture to the East. However, this pattern was more variable, more severe storms were reported in the East,[5] and plains droughts occurred that were as severe, if not more severe, than those in the 1930s.[6]
― 46 ―
Figure 1.18 Average Annual Precipitation for 18 California Stations Reconstructed from 5 2 Western Tree-ring Chronologies Dots represent eight-year weighted averages used to smooth out the annual values. The horizontal line corresponds to the 1901-1961 me an value.
― 47 ―
Figure 1.19 Differences in Climate between the 20th Century and Three Prior Centuries A veraged within 11 Different Regions in North America Figure 1.19a shows the change in means for 1901-1970 comp ared to 1602-1900. Figure 1.19b shows the percent change in standard deviation for 1901-1961 compared to 1602-1900. The upper value in each case is for the reconstructed annual temperature in degrees Ce ntigrade; the lower value is for the reconstructed annual precipitation, in percent.
― 48 ― Stockton and Boggess[7] point out that the consequences of a dry and warm climatic change would be greatest in many areas of the arid Southwest, especially in the Lower Colorado, Missouri Arkansas-White-Red, and Texas Gulf, where groundwater is already extensively used. Two primary future climatic projections have been made by climatologists today.[8] The most popular is that the climate is likely to warm, due to the burning of fossil fuel and an increase of atmospheric CO/d/s-22/s+2/u. The second is that the climate was anomalous for the first half of the 20th century and that it is now likely to revert to the state of prior centuries. In either projection, climate in the semiarid West is likely to be drier, perhaps warmer, and more variable. This would indicate that the existing projections of water resources for the West based on the 20th-century hydrologic record are in all likelihood overestimates of what the water resources may be in the future.
Acknowledgement The research reported here was supported in part by NSF Grant ATM7522378 Climate Variability, Climate Dynamics Program and by the California Department of Water Resources, Agreement No. B53367.
― 49 ―
Discussion: Parry D. Harrison Mr. Bredehoeft presents a rather gloomy picture of the water supplies in the West. Although much of what he says is correct, some of it tends to be a little misleading. I do not fully agree that the water supply of the West is nearly fully utilized. Some river basins like the Colorado could be said to be fully utilized. However, an example of underdeveloped water supply is the Columbia River at The Dalles, with an average flow of over 140 million acre-feet per year; and the Willamette River at Portland averages over 23 million acre-feet per year. I could name at least ten other rivers that discharge between 3 and 15 million acre-feet per year. While it is true that not all of these vast water supplies can be utilized and storage projects are very difficult to construct, many worthwhile storage projects have yet to be constructed. The problem with most of these rivers is that they are far from the heavy demand areas of California and the Southwest. Runoff Predictions. A most difficult problem, and yet a paramount need, is accurate prediction of streamflows for the next six months, year, two years, and five years. Much has been written about the hydrologic cycle, the correlation of precipitation and runoff with sunspots, wind patterns, volcanic activity, effect of air pollution on weather, and effect on weather of atomic explosions. Nevertheless, the ability to predict precipitation and hence runoff with any degree of accuracy has not been demonstrated. The theory has been that the key lies in history; hence, studies of tree ring data, runoff records, stochastic analysis with the aid of computers—and we are still a long way from an acceptable solution. Irrigation. Somewhere between 30 and 75 percent of water diverted for irrigation is a direct depletion and is consumed by evapotranspiration. The remainder either percolates into the ground and becomes part of the groundwater resource or returns to the stream and becomes available for reuse. Return flow usually is of poorer quality than the source. Many
significant groundwater resources have been the result of or enhanced by irrigation. (Examples: Columbia basin in central Washington, Snake Plain aquifer in south-central Idaho, and the Sacramento and San Joaquin valleys in California). Groundwater. Groundwater pumping from an aquifer that is being mined is a depletion of that resource, whatever its use. There may be some reuse or secondary use of the water pumped;
― 50 ― but unless it is reinjected, groundwater that is being mined is not a renewable resource. When it is used up, it is gone. In contrast, streams provide a renewable supply which comes every year, with some fluctuations depending on the weather. Some things can be done to enhance or prolong the life of groundwater resources. These may include (1) artificial recharge: this may be feasible if there is an available resource; (2) limitation or restriction of groundwater pumping; and (3) efficient use of available supplies. Competition for Water. Severe competition for limited water supplies in some areas may make it necessary to choose between irrigation, streamflows for fish, or domestic needs. Abundant and cheap water supplies enhance the quality of life in the West, but in the future some locations may not be able to enjoy them. Most countries do not have the luxury of abundant, high quality water supplies to the extent that we do in the United States and Canada. In the past cities have had to restrict the watering of lawns or filling of swimming pools to ensure adequate supplies for drinking, washing, and fire protection. Many of those vying for control of water supplies have a single-track approach. Some typical comments have been: "My need is paramount." "Irrigation provides food; do you want to watch the fish swim upstream or would you rather eat?" "Fish have been nearly eliminated by diversions and pollution for nearly 100 years; this has to be rectified now!" "Recreation needs are increasing by leaps and bounds; waterbased recreation must be given a high priority." "Water is needed for power production. Power is the basis for our high standard of living. It means jobs!"
Narrow, unyielding approaches make it all the more difficult to find solutions to water supply problems facing the West. The competition is becoming keener every year. Cool heads and clear vision are needed to make good decisions that will influence the quality of the western lifestyle for years to come.
― 51 ―
Chapter 2— Legal-Institutional Limitations on Water Use by Gary Weatherford and Helen Ingram
Abstract For irrigated agriculture, water must be available not only physically but institutionally. Laws, customs, politics, and groups determine whether irrigated agriculture is favored or disfavored in the competitive arena of water management. The fourfold thesis of this paper is: (1) water reallocation and management is gradually replacing water development in the western U.S.; (2) irrigated agriculture's favored legal-political position is declining, but only marginally; (3) change in the relative position of agriculture is likely to continue to be incremental, but more innovative change caused by unexpected events is possible; and (4) in the face of uncertainty, more flexible water management institutions to promote conservation and water transfers, while protecting equities, are advisable. Two institutions spurred the growth of irrigated agriculture by delivering cheap water: the prior appropriation doctrine of water law and the federal reclamation program of the Bureau of Reclamation. As the water available for agriculture declines, the prior appropriation system of water rights can be expected to (1) aid the farmer who desires to profit from the sale of his water rights to other users; (2) compensate the farmer whose land and water is condemned against his wishes; (3) require the farmer to waste less water; (4) allow the farmer with junior rights to be displaced by senior rights, such as Indian water rights; and (5) provide a cause of action for the farmer whose water rights are impaired by one or more late-comer appropriators. Irrigated acreage in the West has doubled since World War II, expanding increasingly away from the southern arid tier to the central and northern high plains states. The reclamation ethic appears to have crested, however, and the federal influence in water policy seems to be waning as the water management role of the states is waxing. Unexpected events, such as an unparalleled oil crisis or expanded famine, could alter current trends.
Whatever the future holds, more flexible water management institutions are advisable for the welfare of all the water use sectors.
― 52 ―
From Reclamation to Reallocation: Historical Overview Agricultural growth in the West was spurred by legal-political institutions that delivered cheap water. Chief among those institutions were the prior appropriation doctrine and the federal reclamation program. Early settlers had little incentive to commit capital and labor to construct water diversion and distribution systems if there were any risk of other users moving in upstream and leaving them high and dry. Therefore, western states developed the doctrine of "first in time, first in right". This law of prior appropriation allowed the first user on a stream to obtain a priority over all other subsequent users, and so on down the line. Prior appropriation facilitated western expansion and agricultural development because water could be parcelled out to a large number of irrigators, and priority dates signalled the extent of risk in situations of drought. Even when existing streams were fully appropriated, agriculture continued to expand by augmenting supplies through the federal program to reclaim the arid and semiarid West. The 1902 National Reclamation Act codified the goal of making the deserts bloom, ushering in the developmental era of heavily subsidized, and increasingly centralized, large-scale irrigation projects.[1] The Act, its amendments, and individual project authorizations provided the legal structure for long-term, interest-free financing based on "ability to pay", and further institutionalized the notion that unappropriated and undeveloped water was itself free, its only cost being the capital cost of constructing works and the subsequent operation and maintenance cost. The government's powers of eminent domain, navigation, and commerce were available for these projects constructed by the Bureau of Reclamation. The Bureau intercepted most major waterways in the West with a series of dams and diversions. Interbasin transfer projects were commonplace. The reclamation program spurred the creation of water districts (mostly public, special districts) as entities responsible for repayment, operation, and maintenance functions. Contract obligations were deferred in projects experiencing hardships. Areas with the most political power in Congress were generally benefitted first. In the post-World War I period, the public works ethos mitigated hard economic times and was further
― 53 ―
institutionalized. Law was viewed as an instrument to harness the unruly forces of nature through public resolve, sweat, and engineering. Public hydroelectric power production was promoted as a major means of subsidizing irrigation water development. Indian tribes were largely neglected by this reclamation process. In 1908, the United States Supreme Court held that water rights had been reserved to Indian tribes for their future use incidental to the creation of reservations.[2] These so-called reserved water rights, unlike state-created appropriation rights, are not dependent upon use, and thus may be claimed at any time and are not lost by nonuse. For the most part, Indian water rights remain unquantified, pending court determination and/or Congressional action. However, tribes are becoming increasingly assertive in claiming large quantities of water. Were such claims to be honored, some present irrigationists would be affected, especially along streams such as the San Juan in New Mexico, which may already be over-committed. With water demand pressing close upon water supply all over the West, and with few good prospects for increasing supply, there seems little alternative to a reallocation of existing supplies among new and established users. Since irrigated agriculture consumes between 80 and 90 percent of total water supplies in most western states, and since the value of water for crop production is ordinarily lower than for alternative uses such as energy, some agriculture is in the position of being bought out. The relative position of agriculture with respect to water supply will now be explored from the perspective of legal and institutional history.
Water Law and Agricultural Water Scarcity Layers of Law[en3]Layers of Law[3] Water law in the West often comes in layers, ranging from the macro to the micro. If an international drainage is involved (like the Colorado, Rio Grande, and Columbia Rivers), a treaty normally governs the division of water between nations. If the water flows between states, an interstate compact (or possible litigation) apportions it. Within a particular state, the water laws (statutes, court rulings, and administrative decisions) define how individual property rights in water are created, exercised,
― 54 ― and protected, except to the extent that superior federal or Indian rights are involved (e.g., navigation servitude, "reserved" water rights, and federal eminent domain). Generally speaking, the international, national, and
interstate laws make the broad allocations which determine "state entitlements"—the amounts of water which, when added to the water local to a state, are available for use within that particular state. Agriculture can be affected by laws at all these levels, as a few references to the Colorado River Basin will illustrate. The U.S.-Mexican Water Treaty of 1944 contained no express provision for water quality. Highly saline irrigation drainage from the United States' side precipitated conflict in 1961, leading to U.S.-Mexican agreements and a United States salinity control program which together affect irrigation water management in the states of the Colorado River Basin. Two interstate compacts—the Colorado River Compact of 1922, and the Upper Colorado River Basin Compact of 1948— together control allocations between the upper and lower parts of the basin and between the seven states of the basin, subject to unresolved claims relating to federal and Indian "reserved" water rights. Because the flow of the river was overestimated in 1922, the upper basin's legal obligation to deliver water to the lower basin means that the upper basin has 1 to 2.25 MAF less each year than originally planned. That kind of shortfall raises the level of competition between agriculture and other uses. The 1922 Colorado River Compact contains a pro-agricultural bias, declaring domestic and agricultural use to be superior to the generation of electricity. Both the 1922 and 1948 compacts preserve Indian water right claims which, when quantified, could displace or devalue the agricultural water rights of non-Indians. Federal authorization of the Central Arizona Project (CAP) conditions agricultural water delivery on reducing pumping, practicing conservation, and not irrigating new acreage. When the CAP comes on line several years from now, some California irrigation (which has been based on flow destined ultimately for Arizona) could be cut back. With most of the federal reclamation projects in the western U.S. completed or authorized, state water laws provide the layer of legal rules that now most influence water availability for irrigation. Each state has its own water law system, although similarities exist across state lines. The state water law systems decide who gets how much for what uses. While mining predated irrigation in some of the western states, on the whole
― 55 ― irrigated agriculture has dominated the acquisition of water under the water right systems of the West since the early days of those systems. The water laws of the western states variously were initially designed or later shaped to promote, not limit, irrigation development.
State Law of Surface Waters: Prior Appropriation[en4]State Law of Surface Waters: Prior Appropriation[4] Under the "riparian doctrine" which has prevailed from the outset in the humid eastern states, the right to use water from natural water courses is held by the owners of land adjacent to the water. The western states for the most part rejected the riparian approach, adopting the "prior appropriation doctrine" which allowed water to be diverted away from riparian land. (See map of surface water rights systems, Figure 2.1.) The appropriation doctrine rests on two fundamental principles: (1) priority in time, and (2) beneficial use. The priority principle—first in time, first in right—allocates available water in times of shortage to those who first began their use of water from the source. Persons with the earliest priority may have their rights completely satisfied, while persons with the latest rights may receive no water at all. This "first in time" rule is offset by three large exceptions. First, in most states, certain preferred users receive their full appropriation regardless of their priority. Preference is normally given to domestic and municipal uses and often to uses for agricultural purposes. Some states also provide a judicial mechanism through which preferred users may condemn the water rights of less preferred users. Second, appropriators may agree among themselves that during times of shortage the burden of the reduction in supply will be shared by a system of rotation or some other way. Third, sharing of shortage is often found in large projects where a number of irrigators share in the project's priority. The term "beneficial use" is not subject to precise definition, but it generally includes two related, but somewhat different, concepts: social utility and engineering efficiency. That is, a use is beneficial if it involves some socially accepted purpose and if it makes a reasonably efficient use of water. In the past most consumptive uses, particularly irrigation, have been considered beneficial. The types of uses socially accepted as beneficial uses have been increasing. Gradually, "instream" uses, such as the preservation of minimum flows to preserve fish, wildlife, and recreation values, which do not involve the "appropriation" of water, are becoming recognized as
― 56 ―
Figure 2.1 Surface Water Rights Systems Source: Gary Weatherford (ed.) et al, Acquiring Water for Energy (Littleton, Colorado: Water Resources Publications, 1/82), p.32. John Muir Institute
― 57 ― beneficial uses. New energy-related uses, such as dewatering mines and slurrying coals, are being regarded as beneficial by most affected states, increasing the basis for competition and the justification for public regulation involving the exercise of broad administrative discretion in assessing tradeoffs and balancing interests. Thus, beneficial use is a dynamic, not static, principle.
A person who wishes to divert water for a beneficial use must apply for a permit to a designated state agency. The typical scheme is generalized in Figure 2.2. Public notice is given and a hearing is offered to other right holders—sometimes to affected members of the public also—who object to the proposed diversion. The date of application usually determines the priority of the use. The state will generally issue the permit if it determines that the proposed use will not interfere with existing uses ("nonimpairment"), that unappropriated water is available, and that the project is not otherwise contrary to the public interest. Upon completion of the diversion and application of the water to a beneficial use, an appropriator must file proof of appropriation which, upon verification, is followed by the issuance of a certificate of a perfected right. This right extends only to the amount of water actually diverted and applied to a beneficial use, even if a larger quantity was originally intended. Under most irrigation uses of surface water, a significant portion of water applied returns to the watercourse as "return flow." A purchaser of appropriation rights who merely continues the same use as his predecessor need only comply with local recording laws to perfect the right. An application for a new permit must be filed, however, if either a purchaser or the same owner intend to change the nature of the use, which may mean a change in the point of diversion or in the purpose or place of use. State approval helps to guarantee that the proposed change will not interfere to a greater extent than did the prior use with the existing rights of others, and that the new use is in the public interest. The application process for proposed changes is similar to that followed for the initiation of new rights. Approval depends on a determination that other rights will not be impaired and that unappropriated water is available (in the event that the change of use is more consumptive than the prior use). Some states will not permit a transfer in the place of use if it involves the transport of water outside the watershed of origin or outside the state. And some states will not authorize a change in the type of
― 58 ―
Figure 2.2 Permit Procedure: Prior Appropriation States Source: Gary Weatherford (ed.) et al, Acquiring Water for Energy (Littleton, Colorado: Water Resources Publications, 1982), p.50. John Muir Institute
― 59 ― use where the prior use is preferred over that use which is to replace it. With the prior appropriation doctrine thus described, the question arises: What relationship might exist between this prior appropriation system and diminished water for agriculture? The simple answer is that the system in
most instances will (1) aid the farmer who desires to retire by selling his land and water profitably to nonfarmers; (2) compensate the farmer whose land and water is condemned against his wishes; (3) possibly reduce, under changing notions of conservation and "reasonableness," the amount of water the farmer has been diverting or consuming; (4) subordinate the farmer with junior rights to newly asserted senior rights, such as Indian water rights; and (5) provide a cause of action for the farmer whose water rights are impaired by one or more late-comer appropriators. These results will occur in the following ways. Appropriative rights are quantified and, in most areas, marketable.[5] (See Chapter 18.) Individual farmers and farming interests themselves will reduce the water available for agriculture by selling out at attractive prices to nonagricultural users, such as cities and energy companies. Appropriative rights are property rights; if they are condemned by a public agency or authorized utility, compensation must be paid. For the farmer who continues to exercise his appropriative right, he may find that changing legislative, judicial, or administrative notions of "reasonable use" and "public interest" require that he be more efficient in his water use, that is, use less water on the same acreage. In some cases, he may be allowed to use the water saved on expanded acreage, in which case no overall reduction in agricultural water occurs. If the farmer's priority date is later than that of an unexercised Indian water right, the initiation of the Indian water use can reduce or eliminate the farmer's supply. To the extent that he is the senior appropriator in time, however, competing junior uses cannot lawfully impair his right, although problems of proof and costs of enforcement place practical limits on this protection. Because irrigated agriculture enjoys 80 to 90 percent of the water consumption market in the West pursuant to these vested property rights, it is in a position generally superior to other water competitors. Agriculture acquired permanent rights in the water, with the aid of public subsidy, in the formative days of settlement and water rights administration. Within limits, those rights are subject selectively to superior claims and to
― 60 ― redefinition in the public interest. For the most part, however, irrigated agriculture will bargain from a position of strength in the competitive arenas of water scarcity, even though not all individuals or interests in the agricultural community are benefitted or protected in the process.[6]
State Groundwater Laws[en7]State Groundwater Laws[7] Present indicators are that much of the decline in agricultural water supply in the West will result from dwindling groundwater resources in such overdraft
areas as the multistate Ogallala Aquifer, central Arizona, and the San Joaquin Valley of California. Overdraft conditions have been permitted or countenanced by the groundwater legal systems of the affected states. Most groundwater basins are hydrologically connected to surface flows and ought not, from a management perspective, to be regarded apart from surface flows. There are four principal legal systems governing groundwater acquisition in the western states: absolute ownership, reasonable use, correlative rights, and prior appropriation. We do not offer here exposition of the various state groundwater systems. (See Figure 2.3 for a map showing the diversity of approaches in the West.) Some states have drawn geographic lines between those areas which are critical and those which are not. The definition of a "critical area" or "capacity use area" is generally an area in which the annual rate of withdrawal exceeds the average annual recharge (the common definition of groundwater mining) or threatens to do so. The distinction between critical and noncritical areas may determine whether a proposed well is subject to regulation at all, or the degree of scrutiny the permit application will receive. In some cases, critical areas are subject to governance by local groundwater management districts. Also, critical areas may be controlled by express statutory prohibitions. Sometimes special protection or preference is given to groundwater service areas which are more expansive than just the land overlying the aquifer itself. Many of the observations made earlier about the role the prior appropriation doctrine plays under declining water conditions apply to groundwater systems as well. Groundwater rights likewise are property rights; generally they are transferable and enforceable against impairment. To the extent that groundwater becomes more regulated, with more controls on the depletion of critical aquifers, it is probable that less water will be available to
― 61 ―
Figure 2.3 Groundwater Legal Systems Source: Gary Weatherford (ed.) et al, Acquiring Water for Energy (Littleton, Colorado: Water Resources Publications, 1982), p.100. John Muir Institute
― 62 ― overlying agriculture. It is likely, however, that the decline in groundwater for agriculture will be more attributable to rising pumping costs than to legal regulation.[8]
Political Institutions and Changing Patterns of Influence The reclamation era of large-scale water resource development was dominated by the federal government. The sources of federal influence were the geographic scope of its jurisdiction, its financial resources, and its technical expertise residing in federal agencies. The development of numerous water projects up and down whole river basins spilled across state lines. Control naturally gravitated towards the federal level because the geographical reach of state boundaries was too limited. Moreover, water resource development projects were expensive, and required access to the federal treasury which is much less restricted than the coffers of the states. In addition, the manpower and technical expertise requirements of major water projects led to federal responsibility for large-scale construction. The Bureau of Reclamation, the Army Corps of Engineers, and the Soil Conservation Service had a continuing critical mass of engineers and water planners that no state could hope to maintain. In what observers have termed classic distributive politics, federal agencies orchestrated blends of local and state interests in providing basic support for individual projects.[9] Different project features lured different interests. Farmers were attracted by irrigation water, urban interests were promised water supplies and flood control, recreation groups appreciated lakes created by impoundments, and businessmen and bankers desired water projectgenerated economic growth. Agriculture was important in this coalition of interests because its demands could justify the development of large quantities of water. The rewards for agriculture's backing were long-term contracts for federal water at very reasonable rates, and agencies were generous to farmers in matters of eligibility. For instance, the 160-acre limitation was loosely applied by the Bureau of Reclamation. The role of the states in water development policy was to deliver a unified state congressional delegation in support of projects within state boundaries and the favorable testimony of governors and state agency officials. Mainly the federal piper called the tune in the 1950s and 1960s.
― 63 ― The 1970s witnessed the decline of federal construction agencies and the challenge to federal dominance of water policy. Because of the facts and forces already described, traditional water development patterns were severely disrupted. The number of new starts in water development projects declined, and the share of water agencies in the federal budget grew smaller. The Soil Conservation Service, the constituency of which was mainly agricultural, was brought to task for channelizations that destroyed fish and wildlife habitat. The Bureau of Reclamation, which once was the largest agency in the Department of the Interior, and in 1950 commanded 61 percent of the Department's budget, fell upon even more difficult times.[10] Plans for large-scale construction, such as the two dams proposed for the Grand Canyon, were repeatedly defeated on economic and environmental
grounds. In a symbolic act, meant to signal the end of the Bureau's mission of large-scale construction, the Carter Administration stripped the Agency of its name, and for a period of three years it was called the Water and Power Resources Service. The failure of the Carter Administration to achieve its aims in water resources has been popularly recognized as a defeat for environmentalists, while the decline of the federal government's influence in water has received less notice. An important dimension of the water conflict lurked behind the headlines of the time—a struggle between the states and the federal government over their respective influence and roles in water allocation. Carter's "hit list," which zero-budgeted thirty-two projects, was a direct challenge to the states' growing determination to set their own priorities regarding water resources. The negative reaction from Congress and state houses was marked. The second line of attack for water reform was a federal agency review of water policy which involved little state and local participation. The Carter Administration's issue and options documents which resulted from the agency review were coldly received by the states, especially the option of federal intrusion into water rights granted by individual states. In the end, most of the projects on the original hit list went forward, and a considerably watered down version of the new national water policy was adopted and then was implemented only partially.[11] The new Secretary of Interior in the Reagan Administration dismantled the water policy machinery, including the Water Resources Council, and made it clear that he recognized water resources as primarily a matter of state rather than federal concern.
― 64 ― The lesson from these events is clear. Since the federal government can no longer afford to award large numbers of federally funded and constructed water development projects as prizes, its influence over water management is considerably weakened.
Increasing State Influence The events of the Carter years pointing toward an increase of state influence vis-a-vis the federal government have been reinforced by other forces. One such influence has come from the courts, which in the late 1970s landed some judicial blows on the notion of federal dominance. First the Court said that federal reserved water rights were more restricted than previously imagined. The attempt by the U.S. Department of Justice to expand the reserved water rights of national forests to protect instream water for fish and wildlife was rejected by the Supreme Court on the grounds that such federal claims infringed on the historic role of states in water allocation.[12]
Further, in a California case, the Supreme Court held that the federal government must follow the rules and regulations of the State in the operation of a project even though the project was federal.[13] Considerable constitutional power to affect water management is still lodged in the federal government, however, as the U.S. Supreme Court reminded us on the last day of its term in 1982 in Sporhase v. Nebraska (No. 81-613; July 2, 1982). This case held that the interstate movement of groundwater, as an article of commerce, cannot be restricted by states engaged in economic protectionism. The decision buttresses the free market and federal regulation (those estranged bedfellows of old), and undercuts states' rights. It is not likely, however, that the equitable and distributional values asserted by states will evaporate simply because there has been a judicial pronouncement. It would not be surprising to find the western states seeking federal legislation (congressional exercise of the commerce power) legitimating to the degree possible the states' efforts to control and manage water resources. The capability of states to manage water resources has grown in the last couple of decades. The focus and reliance upon federal agencies during the reclamation era worked to stunt and distort the growth of state water planning agencies and policy-making structures. Up until the mid-1960s, the number of professional planners was quite small and there was little attempt at state water planning independent of federal plans. The picture is enormously changed in the 1980s. While legislative authorization for
― 65 ― addressing water resource planning is far from sufficient evidence of state capability, the presence of such mandates facilitates forceful state action. As Figure 2.4 illustrates, the types of legislative mandates given to states vary enormously, yet the map shows that most states provide for comprehensive water quantity planning, and in many cases this is combined with management, and/or water quality planning and/or management. While undoubtedly these structures were developed partly in response to the availability of federal grants-in-aid, agencies now represent a considerable pool of expertise and influence that is likely to survive, at least in part, even if federal monies are withdrawn.[14] The independent actions of individual states in relation to water resources both contribute to and are evidence of growing state influence. These actions are sometimes not consistent, indicating considerable differences in the priorities of different states. For instance, in 1977 the Montana legislature declared "the use of water for slurry to export coal from Montana is not a beneficial use."[15] On the other hand, South Dakota determined to sell a share of the state's Missouri River water out of Oahe reservoir to an interstate coal-slurry pipeline company on terms that provided low-cost
water to several towns along the pipeline route.[16] Numbers of other states similarly are acting on the allocation, use, and preservation of state water resources. In 1982 the Governor of Wyoming proposed to the legislature that the state appropriate $100 million per year for six years to develop the state's water resources.[17] In 1980 Arizona adopted a comprehensive new groundwater code aimed at bringing the state's depleted aquifers into a "safe-yield" situation by the year 2020.[18]
Implications for Agriculture Land irrigated for agriculture in the West has roughly doubled since World War II, and the addition of 25 million acres in the West has contributed heavily to American agriculture's 70 percent increase in crop production during the post-war years.[19] A healthy chunk of this expansion has come from high production farming on arid lands, perhaps as much as 13 million acres, that are unsuitable for commercial agriculture without irrigation. The focus of growth in the initial phase, 1945-1954, was in the arid southern tier of states extending from Texas and Oklahoma
― 66 ―
Figure 2.4 State Statutory Authority for Water Resources Planning and Management Source: Kenneth Rubin, "The Capacity of States to Manage Water Resources Given a Decreased
Federal Role," prepared for Symposium on Unified River Basin Management, Stage II, Oct. 1981.
― 67 ― to California. Subsequently, increases in irrigated acreage have come from central and northern high plains states.[20] Among the most important factors underlying this growth has been an abundance of relatively inexpensive water. While the accomplishments of the National Reclamation Act of 1902 that made the Great American Desert bloom have been striking, there are many signs, noted above, that the reclamation ethic has crested. The decline of federal influence in water allocation has a mixed bag of consequences for irrigated agriculture. Clearly the closing of the option of developing large-scale additional supplies at the same time as demands are growing generates pressures upon the largest of the users of existing supplies. At the same time it is possible to question the extent to which agriculture ever controlled the flow of benefits from federal water projects. In the interests of gaining broad support, federal agencies regularly served numbers of other interests including urban users, energy, industry, and fish and wildlife at the expense of agriculture. A retrospective study of the Central Arizona Project indicates that in the thirty-three year history of negotiations, farmers were forced to make a number of compromises to save the project. The current project design will afford farmers far fewer benefits and more costs than if they could have continued to pump groundwater.[21] The change of emphasis at the federal level in the management of existing projects has important implications for agriculture. While the Carter and Reagan Administrations have differed enormously in their approaches to water resources, both have emphasized the principle that users should pay more nearly full costs. Irrigation interests are likely to be charged considerably more for water when long-term contracts for water at existing federal installations fall due. Whether or not the federal government will use the leverage it has for other purposes remains to be seen. With the support of the Reagan Administration, Congress has modified the 160 acre limitation to the point where it poses little or no problem to most agriculturalists. In the case of the Central Arizona Project the federal government appears to be making good on its trust obligations by influencing allocations to benefit Indian tribes. The future of federal support of Indian water rights is not at all clear, however. The Reagan Administration has favored negotiation rather than litigation in securing Indian water rights. The reserved water rights position of many tribes is legally very strong, and even without active federal government backing may fare well in the courts. Indian
― 68 ― victories in water allocation mean all junior users, including irrigated agriculture, stand to lose. The shift of influence in water allocation towards the states raises the issue of the relative influence of agriculture in federal and state arenas. On the face of it, the structure of Congress would appear more favorable to agriculture than state legislatures. Rural farming states have the same number of votes in the Senate as do more urban and more populous states, while both bodies at the state level are apportioned on the principle of one man-one vote. Further, the influx of people into urban areas in many agricultural states, and the depopulation of the hinterlands, especially in the West, has resulted largely in urban populations. In Arizona, for instance, seventy-five percent of the population lives either in Phoenix or Tucson. Yet the preferences of legislative bodies are often different from what one might expect. In practice, the U.S. Senate has been more oriented toward urban interests than the House, because practically every Senator has at least one large urban area in his or her state. Further, the court ruling requiring apportionment of state legislatures on the basis of population has had less impact on the traditional rural bias of state legislatures than one might suppose. In many state legislatures agriculture has had influence far in excess of what the number of rural districts would suggest because urban areas lack cohesion and rural legislators often have skill, seniority, and command of formal positions. The attitudes of state voters is likely to be important in determining how state governments will treat agriculture. While public opinion surveys on questions of water allocation are infrequent, those that have been reported should be reassuring to agricultural interests. A survey of voters in the four corners states of Arizona, New Mexico, Utah, and Colorado found more than 90 percent of respondents in favor of allocating more or the same amount of water to irrigated agriculture in the future. This support was strong even among urban residents.[22] Customers in the Salt River Project area were asked in another survey if as a conservation measure they favored or opposed raising the cost of water to farmers growing food and fiber. Eighty-three percent of respondents opposed such action, compared with 64 percent opposition to similar price increases for residential users and 54 percent opposition for business and industrial users.[23] While such data cannot be construed as a reliable indicator of what urban users would do if they really had to choose between their own interests and those of agriculture in
― 69 ― water matters, those surveyed do testify to the reservoir of positive attitudes
toward agriculture. The policies pursued by some states in water allocation evidence similar basic concern for the welfare of agriculture. Henry Caulfield has written of the predilection of Colorado water leaders toward the development by the state and private entities of unappropriated water and surplus water from wet years to serve the energy industry and growing populations. This is viewed as much preferable to cutting back agriculture's share.[24] The Arizona groundwater reform act does envision the reduction of agricultural consumption of water to a level of "conservation use" to be set by the State Department of Water Resources. At the same time, "grandfathered water rights" favor all existing water users at the expense of future users who are likely to be residential and industrial.[25] To summarize, the rise of states in the changing pattern of political influences is affecting irrigated agriculture, but there is much to suggest that the position of agriculture remains strong. State houses are likely to be as sympathetic to agriculturalists as were federal agencies that dominated water politics in the reclamation era. Particular pressures will be brought to bear upon agriculture because it historically has used large amounts of water and paid little, and demands of new water users must somehow be satisfied. At the same time it is reasonable to expect that state governments will do what they can to cushion the impact of water reallocation upon agriculture in the name of perpetuating the agricultural economy and preserving the rural lifestyle.
Unexpected Events and Unanticipated Consequences The discussion up to this point has assumed an incremental future. In a world where dominant events are often unforeseen, however, it is risky not to consider the unexpected. It is possible to imagine in passing a number of events that would thrust water once more into the national arena commanding federal attention. It is also possible to imagine that the devolution of power over water allocation from the federal government to the states might be more rapid than we anticipate. Because water is so crucial an element in energy, agriculture, and economic productivity, it may be that a crisis in any of those
― 70 ― sectors would quickly put water on the national agenda. If our oil supplies were threatened again, more seriously than the Iranian oil embargo, as by a revolution in Saudi Arabia, unparalleled pressures would be brought to make the U.S. energy-independent. The federal government undoubtedly would have to take the lead in directing such domestic energy development. The
record of private enterprise on synfuels in the past, even with healthy subsidies, does not warrant the expectation that the response of the private sector alone would be adequate. The energy industry by now is clearly skeptical of risking capital in synfuels development, as Exxon did in the oil shale boom. The federal government might well react to an energy crisis by causing large amounts of water to be shifted from agriculture to energy. It might be that states could bargain to protect agriculture, and the time necessary to get energy projects under way could be long enough that agriculture could outlast the crisis. Nonetheless, rapid federal energy development in a crisis situation bodes ill for farmers' retention of water. On the other hand, an enlarged famine caused by crop failures abroad, in conjunction with the growing importance of agriculture in U.S. balance of payments, could help U.S. farmers. Expanding food crises could boost federal assistance to farms and raise farm prices. The already favorable public attitude toward irrigated agriculture in the West could be amplified. New federal projects that benefit agriculture might be authorized and funded. The authorization and funding of a large number of new projects, for agriculture as well as other purposes, could be spurred by an economic crisis prompting a New Deal type of public works response employing lots of people. Other changes could be ushered in by a rapid rise in the interstate movement of water.[26] As water comes to be treated more like any other commodity, and becomes more overtly commercialized, many private water rights could become transferable to the highest bidder across state lines, and interstate water compacts could be undercut. It is even possible that agribusinesses engaged in high-value production might be buyers in an interstate water market, although farmers as a whole more often would be sellers. Could equity considerations be protected in such a "free market" environment? Possibly, through either: (1) an Act of Congress and/or (2) state ownership (purchase/condemnation) of water rights to prevent uncontrolled operation of the private market. Would this not pose an identity crisis of significant proportions in the irrigated West? In order
― 71 ― to protect lower-value uses and the natural resource base of each state, a movement could arise to either "federalize" or "socialize" more of the water —alternatives foreign to the current political imagery of western states (although western settlement was partially subsidized by free land and water in the past). Agriculture's historical water rights granted by state governments could be profoundly altered by the emergence of an interstate water market. Two scenarios in which states become more powerful more quickly than we envision here have been offered in a paper by Henry Caulfield.[27] In the
first, power and money is transferred from the federal government via "new" federalism. In the second, states seize the initiative on their own. The second scenario assumes states can determine their own values concerning water, and that they have or can develop the financial and technical capability. Under such conditions we would expect agriculture to fare reasonably well, as we have predicted, although we would not expect states to be equally favorable to farmers.
Conclusions The support for continued agricultural use of large amounts of cheap water is high among state residents, even those in urban areas. Further, irrigated agriculture bargains in state arenas from a position of strength. State water law grants vested property rights to users with long-term, established records. Agriculture acquired permanent rights in water in the formative days of settlement, and those rights are subject to only limited redefinition in the public interest. It is in the long-term interests of agriculture as well as other sectors to develop more flexible water institutions that facilitate conservation and water transfers. The lesson to be learned from the decline in supply solutions for water shortage is that water must be managed for reallocation to highervalue uses and waste needs to be reduced. Barring unexpected events, this will mean some reduction in irrigated agriculture in the arid regions. To a large extent this shift will probably be accomplished through the sale of water rights in the market. Transactions that move water out of irrigated agriculture will cause some negative externalities, such as social and environmental disruption. There may be ways to soften such impacts, however. Rural people may band together through water districts, corporations, or other
― 72 ― arrangements to direct the flow of water to purposes consistent with rural values and the need for rural employment. State governments may decide to enter markets themselves, buying water rights for equity, aesthetic, or fish and wildlife purposes. The use of water that remains to agriculture, that is not sold or leased, will become more regulated. The Arizona Groundwater Act of 1980 devised a flexible groundwater right that is to diminish in quantity over time as conservation technology develops and conservation requirements under the law tighten. The concept of beneficial use, as we have indicated, can be used flexibly, and it is likely that in some states water uses tolerated in the past will be disallowed in the future as not in the public interest.
The lesson to be learned from the marginal decline in the influence of agriculture vis-a-vis other water users is that accommodation rather than outright opposition to modifications in water institutions is advisable for agriculture. Because irrigated agriculture is the largest water user, it is the obvious focus of policies aimed at stretching supplies. While agriculture's legal and political position remains strong, it nonetheless represents only a small percentage of the population in most states. In the final analysis, irrigated agriculture is likely to fare better if it is not perceived to be in direct conflict with other users.
Discussion: Jon Kyl There can be little disagreement with the fourfold thesis of this paper. (1) Even as one of the largest reclamation projects ever developed, the Central Arizona Project, nears completion, western water development inexorably is being replaced by water reallocation and management. (2) The relative position of agriculture is declining, though in different degrees among the western states. (3) In an overall sense, this change is gradual; but in specific areas it is and will be traumatic. (4) Depending upon how one defines the term, flexible water management to promote conservation and water transfer is, indeed, advisable. Whether it must be effected through "institutions," as opposed to incentives, legal requirements, or the free market, will be subject to debate. Laws and public policy respond to the times. As more people compete for scarce resources, one of two things happens. If the free market is allowed to operate, the price of the commodity goes up, resulting in some measure of conservation. Alternatively, if the price goes too high, or if the owners of the resource are too politically weak, or if, for other reasons, policy makers deem it necessary or expedient to regulate the resource by exercise of police power, a nonmarket political redistribution of the resource may result. Such a result is inevitable if the regulation is stringent and pervasive enough to amount to a "taking" of the resource. Reallocation of the scarce water resources in the West is occurring through both operation of the market and newly-imposed regulation and management schemes. What may most influence the allocation of our scarce water resource is the Indian water claim. This emerging problem calls for more discussion, because it could dwarf the difficulties heretofore encountered by competing non-Indian claims. In Arizona, for example, application of the "practicable irrigable" acreage test of Arizona v. California, 373 U.S. 546, 600 (1963), would result in allocation of the entire dependable water supply of the State to just one-third of the Indian tribes, leaving two-thirds of the tribes and all non-Indian Arizonans with nothing.[1] No solution to this problem is yet evident. Congress has been unwilling to initiate any process for quantification of Indian claims, and the Tribes have been unwilling to cooperate in such quantification through the courts—especially in state-court McCarren Act proceedings. With the stakes as high as they are, it is quite possible that changes brought about by resolution of
― 75 ― Indian water claims will not be incremental and could be traumatic. Even if it is assumed that Indian tribes which cannot use the large amounts of water claimed can and will sell part of their entitlement to non-Indians, recent expansion of Tribal "sovereignty" by the Supreme Court[2] casts doubt on the extent to which non-Indians will do business with the Tribes. Since there is no practical way of resolving legal disputes with Indians (because of Tribal immunity in state and federal courts), it is doubtful that many entrepreneurs will place their operations and fortunes at risk on agreements to use Indian water. Indian reserved water claims are, in short, much more significant than suggested in this paper. In the section on state groundwater laws, several statements deserve comment. First, it is not necessarily true that most groundwater basins are hydrologically connected to surface flows. In Arizona, for example, most groundwater aquifers have no hydrological connection to surface flows. It is likewise incorrect to assume that, from a management perspective, surface flows ought to be treated with "flows" of groundwater. Second, at least according to a recent pronouncement of the Arizona Supreme Court, it is not necessarily true, as the authors state, that "groundwater rights likewise are property rights . . . transferable and enforceable against impairment." Both the State Supreme Court and the Federal District Court in Arizona have now held that there is no constitutionally-protected property right in groundwater in one's land—that the doctrine of reasonable and beneficial use gives the landowner only a right to use, which can be regulated and taken by the state.[3] This recent interpretation and the Supreme Court's validation of the comprehensive 1980 Groundwater Management Act also cast doubt on the authors' prediction that, in Arizona at least, ". . . the decline in groundwater for agriculture will be more attributable to rising pumping costs than to legal regulation." These corrections are not meant to take issue with the validity of the paper's observations, only to point out that recent legislative and court actions in Arizona have changed the facts. Even though the doctrine of reasonable and beneficial use gives a landowner only the right to use, the authors are correct that that right has been characterized as a constitutionally protected property right.[4] As to the statement that reductions would occur through increased pumping costs, the minority report to the State Commission which developed the Arizona law agreed with
― 76 ― the authors—that the natural market forces of price and increased pumping costs (due to lower water depths and higher gas and electric charges) had in fact reduced and would continue to reduce agricultural pumping without the necessity of a regulatory law designed to accomplish the same objective. Two additions to the short discussion of the Arizona Groundwater Act are suggested. First, though "grandfathered rights" favor existing water users, the transformation of a prior common law right into a new state-regulated statutory right has diminished the value of the "right" considerably. Second, after 2006, the Act authorizes the State to purchase and retire agricultural lands if, in addition to other conservation measures, that action is necessary to achieve a balance between water consumption and supply in management areas. Finally,[5] it is difficult to argue with the last paragraph of the paper. However, that conclusion also reveals the difficulty of the challenge to agriculture. When "vested property rights" were, in the view of many in agriculture, eliminated by competitors in the State of Arizona,[6] it is a significant challenge indeed for agriculture to portray its uses of water as not being in conflict with other users. In conclusion, the paper substantially contributes to an understanding of the water problems facing agriculture. Its value would be enhanced by more discussion of two points. First, the changes already brought about and those predicted may pale in comparison to the accommodations which would be necessitated by full-scale application of the "practicable irrigable" test for federal reserved water claims on Indian reservations. Second, competition for water among non-Indians has already resulted in at least one state redefining the legal status of a right to use groundwater, with the result that agriculture's "vested property right" became a noncompensable stateregulated ability to use. Depending on how Indian claims are resolved, and on political conditions in other states, future changes in western agricultural water rights and uses could be dramatic.
Discussion: Frank J. Trelease Ordinarily the job of a discussant is an easy one, but this assignment has suddenly turned into a difficult task. Usually the discussant's plan of action is to challenge the premises of the paper, meet them head on, and engage in close combat. In this instance the search for the fatal flaw failed. The first reading disclosed only tiny chinks in the opponent's armor, and hope failed as the conclusion finally revealed the awful truth: I agree with practically everything said by the authors.
― 78 ― The authors end with predictions and forecasts, and even the unexpected and unanticipated is explored. Any prediction can be attacked as unrealistic. Yet my crystal ball seems no more free from cloudy spots, cracks, and distortions than theirs, and since I have lived long enough to see many of my own doom-sayings exposed as wrong, naive, and even foolish, I hesitate to claim any superiority as a seer. The most I will attempt is to throw a few more straws into the wind and see which direction they point—always remembering that a straw has two ends. Some seem to fall crosswise. The paper identifies reserved Indian water rights as threats to present agriculture, but the sad fact is that while Indians have the best water rights in the West, they have the least water. On most reservations, substantial projects would be needed to translate the dry paper water rights into wet water in the ditches, and in my opinion there is small chance of obtaining federal funding for works that would take water from present users. The best hopes seem to be for joint water from present users. The best hopes seem to be for joint on-and-off reservation benefits similar to the on-going Central Utah Project, the proposed Yamkima scheme, and the still viable Papago settlement. It is also possible that the era of federal agricultural subsidy may not be entirely over. Ogalalla aquifer underlying parts of seven high plains states has been overdrawn in Texas since the 1940s. Only two states on the fringes of the aquifer have recognized that irrigation use of this water is a mining process, and that when the water is exhausted (or fallen too deep) the overlying farmland must revert from irrigated crops back to dryland wheat or cattle grazing. Colorado and New Mexico have at least restricted pumping to ensure that farms could be amortized and that too-quick exhaustion would not bring bankruptcy before payout. Yet now that the "water mines" are nearing exhaustion, cries of help are heard, and the United States is investigating the possibilities of a massive rescue attempt by bringing water from the Missouri River and possibly the Sabine River. Initial guesses as to costs are tremendous, but so also can be the presures from seven Congressional delegations. The authors see possibilities of another energy crisis that might lead to quick conversion of water from farms to fuel. A third crisis, however, may convince us that we have a long-term energy problem that requires a long-term solution. In that case, urban and rural support for the notion that new energy demands must be satisfied by finding new supplies of water can probably be counted on to continue. "Let them find their own water, not
― 79 ―
take ours" could lead to more federal dams to store and make available the small amounts of unappropriated water left in many areas. Even in Montana, where unappropriated water still flows in the Missouri River and its principal tributary, the Yellowstone, the state's water reservation process sets aside all free flows and on-stream dam sites for future agriculture, leaving only expensive off-stream storage for energy. Future federal rescue and energy projects would be enormously expensive subsidies to agriculture. Recognition of this has led to some tension in the states between throwing roadblocks in the path of energy and improving procedures for orderly market transactions. If states are to react responsibly to the need for an efficient economic transition from agricultural use to energy, they must enact better laws. The present systems designed to protect agriculture and prevent transfers still allow cash to talk and spotty unplanned transfers to appear. Current procedures protect priorities of other water users, but not farming neighborhoods and lifestyles. Wyoming made a start with a requirement for something like an economic impact statement to support a petition to approve a transfer, and still better devices could be employed. The states should find ways to internalize the effects of large transfers of farm water on local communities, districts, and economics. There is a need to institutionalize the water right, to make it more easily transferable. The states should find ways to encourage marginal water to move to industrial and municipal use; currently these users seek the earliest and best water rights. Another need is to find ways to encourage conservation to cut back present agricultural demand. Most discussion of water management is either on a high moral plane or calls for tough regulation and imposition of expensive practices. There should be better incentives; the water user should reap where he has sowed, and he should not be asked or forced to spend his time and money for his neighbor's benefit. The authors pose a possible interstate market in water rights, inspired by the recent Sporhase case that struck down Nebraska's curbs on the export of water from the state. Yet Sporhase itself called attention to another recent case, New England Power Company v. New Hampshire, which opens the door to Congressional reversal of Supreme Court decisions that prevent state interference with interstate commerce. Currently the Senate is struggling with a coal slurry pipeline bill (S.1844) that would do just that: permit states to impose conditions on energy companies exporting water as a transportation medium. Yet this brings in
― 80 ― another countervailing consideration. Midwestern Congressmen see the slurry pipeline (which would take water from the Missouri River) as the tip of an iceberg that threatens to sink navigation. An Iowa Congressman has
introduced a bill (H.R.5278) that would prohibit a state from diverting water from an interstate basin unless all states in the basin agree—a move applauded by some from the Great Lakes states who fear an only slightly more remote threat. Since such legislation would undoubtedly mean the death of any more upstream interbasin diversions, the western states would be solid against it. A fair prediction on the outcome is that things will remain the same. As the authors try to foresee the unforeseeable, they instance two scenarios by Henry Caulfield for state development of water. One is the "New Federalism" approach that would divide federal water development money among the states. The other is state capability to do a large part of it alone. As for the latter, California (with its rejection of the "Peripheral Canal") may have run out of patience with rescue projects, Arizona may have run out of water, Nevada out of land, and most of the others out of money. Perhaps the federal block grant is a possibility. If the states do go for a supply-side solution that creates a bigger pie for all, rather than cutting a slice for energy out of agriculture's share, will the problem and the conflict merely be escalated to a new level? If agricultural interests are as strong in the states as the authors suggest, it should be interesting to watch how big a slice of the new "energy water" they will try to take for themselves.
― 81 ―
Chapter 3— Competition for Water by Kenneth D. Frederick and Allen V. Kneese
Abstract The growing scarcity of water in the West already has curbed the expansion of irrigated agriculture and promises to impose further constraints in the coming decades. Nevertheless, declines in irrigated acreage will be limited to the most water-scarce areas and will tend to be modest in scale. Since irrigation now accounts for about nine out of every ten gallons of water consumed in the West, large percentage increases in consumption for other uses can be accommodated with small relative reductions in agricultural uses. Opportunities for conserving water and increasing output per unit of water will further limit the negative impacts on irrigated agriculture. There are areas where water supplies are sufficient to support an expansion of irrigation. For the West as a whole, the Second National Water Assessment projects increases of 10 percent in irrigated acreage and 6 percent in water consumed for irrigation from 1975-2000.
Some of the adjustments which have only marginal impacts on overall western water use and development may have major impacts within specific locations. The point is illustrated by examining the potential impacts of energy development on the character and beauty of the Yampa River. Full appropriation of water supplies presents a major challenge to the institutions allocating western water. If these institutions permit flexibility of use in response to changing demand and supply conditions, water will not be a barrier to either agricultural or nonagricultural development in the West.
The West is undergoing a major transformation with respect to water. In the past, increasing water demands stemming from the rapid growth of population and economic and recreational activities within the region have been met largely through development of new supplies. This strategy is becoming increasingly costly. Projects under consideration in California, for
― 82 ― example, suggest it will cost several hundred dollars per acre-foot to increase water supplies for offstream use, and implementation of these projects would require diverting water from valuable instream uses. Groundwater also has become increasingly expensive due to rising pumping distances and energy prices. Furthermore, the opportunities for expanding groundwater use are limited, especially in the areas with the best agricultural potential; current use already results in the mining of more than 22 million acre-feet per year from western aquifers.[1] The transition to conditions of water scarcity has been under way for several decades in some areas of the West. In the 1950s western water supplies were sufficient to support a rapid growth of use. Total water withdrawals for all but hydroelectric generation rose 56 percent or 4.6 percent per annum from 1950-60. In contrast, withdrawals rose only 15 percent or 1.4 percent per annum from 1970-80. Much of this recent growth occurred in the northern plains states of Kansas, Nebraska, and North and South Dakota, where withdrawals nearly doubled over the last decade. In the rest of the West water withdrawals rose only 0.9 percent per annum in this period.[2] Irrigation spurred by the availability of inexpensive water and energy was the dominant factor in the expansion of western water use. Currently about five of every six gallons withdrawn and nine of every ten gallons consumed go for the irrigation of nearly 50 million acres in the seventeen western states.[3] But as both the largest and a relative low-value user, irrigation is the sector most directly affected by the changing water situation. Some of the impacts of the transition already are becoming evident. Nonagricultural
water consumption in the West grew twice as fast as irrigation use from 1960-80. In areas where water has become particularly scarce and expensive, water for irrigation has started to level off or even decline. In Arizona, for example, total water consumption declined by about 6 percent from 1970-80, even though consumption for nonagricultural uses rose by 67 percent. Only in the northern plains did the growth of water consumption for irrigation exceed the growth for other uses during the last decade.[4] The early expansion of irrigation relied almost exclusively on diverting surface waters. Since the mid-1950s, however, groundwater has accounted for virtually all of the net increase in irrigation water withdrawals. Total surface water withdrawals for irrigation have not increased significantly from the level of 88 million acre-feet (maf) reached in 1955. Groundwater
― 83 ― withdrawals, on the other hand, rose from 11 maf in 1945, to 31 in 1955, and to 56 in 1975.[5] Nearly 40 percent of total irrigation withdrawals now come from groundwater. As a result the aquifers in some of the principal irrigated areas are being depleted, and millions of acres now depend on a diminishing supply of water. The overall growth of groundwater use already has slowed markedly, and in some areas has become negative.
Future Changes in Water Use Demand for western water continues to grow as new investment and people are attracted by the region's mineral, energy and amenity resources. But as supplies fail to grow apace, the competition for water intensifies. In areas of scarcity, irrigated agriculture will increasingly be the sector that others look to for water to meet their growing demands. Water is transportable, but the costs are high in relation to its value in agriculture. Consequently, irrigators in a given area must rely largely on water currently available either naturally or through water importation structures already in place. And as water demands in other sectors grow, irrigators will be confronted with increasingly attractive opportunities for transferring their water to other uses.
Assumptions and Projections of the Second National Water Assessment The Second National Water Assessment provides a useful starting point for examining the implications of future development forces on the allocation of western waters. The Assessment provides water use estimates under average and dry year conditions for a base year 1975 and projections for 1985 and 2000 based on a consistent set of assumptions regarding national growth and change. Principal assumptions underlying the Assessment's
National Future projections include:[6] · National population will grow at slightly less than 1 percent per year and will reach zero growth early in the next century. There will be 268 million people by the year 2000. · Gross National Product will increase at about 4 percent per year.
― 84 ― · Attainment of water quality goals and higher water costs will improve water use efficiency. · Agricultural production and marketing will reflect 1971-73 trends in per capita consumption and export levels. · Fish and wildlife and recreation needs will continue as they have in the past 10 years. Table 3.1 indicates projected changes in population, employment, cropland harvested, and irrigated farmland from 1975-2000 for each of the seventeen western states.[7] These numbers, which have been converted from subregional data in the Assessment to state boundaries, contain some real surprises. In contrast to recent experience, western population and employment are projected to lag behind national growth. Higher than average population growth is projected for the southwestern states of Arizona, California, and Nevada, but population is projected to actually decline over the rest of the century in five northern states. In Wyoming, one of the fastest growing states in the 1970s, both population and employment are projected to decline by more than 10 percent. It is hard to imagine what might cause such a drastic change in regional growth trends (perhaps a complete collapse of energy markets); as noted below, some of these assumptions raise questions about the usefulness of the Assessment's water use projections. The projected changes in western irrigation are more in line with past trends and expectations even though, as discussed later, the Assessment likely understates the level of irrigated acreage. The 10 percent increase in irrigated acreage from 1975-2000 suggests a continuation of the decline in the rate of growth of western irrigation that has been under way for several decades. Irrigated acreage is projected to decline in Arizona, Nevada, New Mexico, and Texas, all of which are faced with major problems of groundwater depletion.
Table 3.2 presents the projections (derived by converting the Assessment data to a state basis) of water consumption for irrigation and other uses. Western water consumption from 1975-2000 is projected to increase only 6 percent for irrigation, compared to 88 percent growth for all other uses. In view of irrigation's dominance as a user of western water, total consumption increases only 13 percent in the West, less than half of the national average.
― 85 ―
Table 3.1 Projected Percentage Changes in Selected Socioeconomic Factors Affecting Water Use, 1975-2000 State and Region
Population
Employment
Cropland Harvested
Irrigated Farmland
Arizona
36
42
2
–12
California
26
36
–1
16
Colorado
21
27
39
2
Idaho
–9
–2
15
14
Kansas
0
0
34
38
Montana
–13
–14
12
44
Nebraska
3
4
–2
19
Nevada
47
48
52
–7
New Mexico
2
12
8
–15
North Dakota –16
–16
28
145
Oklahoma
14
22
28
4
Oregon
16
20
24
20
South Dakota –8
–12
10
74
Texas
18
24
25
–17
Utah
16
25
20
1
Washington
10
22
–4
42
Wyoming
–13
–11
22
8
Western States
Total National Total
18
29
18
10
22
33
19
15
Source: Oak Ridge National Laboratory, State Water Use and Socioeconomic Data Related to the Second National Water Assessment, prepared for the U.S. Water Resources Council (Oak Ridge, Tenn., 1980).
― 86 ―
Table 3.2 Water Consumption for Irrigation and Other Uses by State, 1975 and 2000 Millions of Gallons Per Day 1975
Percent Change 2000
1975-2000
State
Irrigation All Other
Total
Irrigation All Other
Total
Irrigation All Othe
Arizona
3,888
426
4,314
3,590
663
4,253
–8
56
California
23,917
2,184
26,101
25,831
3,327
29,158
8
52
Colorado
5,143
267
5,410
5,408
583
5,991
5
118
Idaho
4,891
143
5,034
5,483
259
5,742
12
81
Kansas
2,548
291
2,839
2,972
567
3,539
17
95
Montana
2,780
172
2,952
4,646
257
4,903
67
49
Nebraska
5,882
233
6,115
6,662
369
7,031
13
58
Nevada
1,694
120
1,814
1,854
176
2,030
9
47
New Mexico 2,396
250
2,646
1,993
328
2,321
–17
31
North Dakota
129
99
228
354
208
562
174
110
Oklahoma
881
365
1,246
846
683
1,529
–4
87
Oregon
3,081
145
3,226
3,833
415
4,248
24
186
South Dakota
292
88
380
593
163
756
103
85
Texas
13,960
1,936
15,896
10,558
4,579
15,137
–24
137
Utah
1,787
262
2,049
1,754
423
2,177
–2
61
Washington 3,149
389
3,538
3,844
941
4,785
22
142
Wyoming
121
2,804
3,355
166
3,521
25
37
17 Western 79,101 States
7,491
86,592
83,576
14,107 97,683
6
88
U.S. Total
18,560 104,677 92,313
2,683
86,117
40,702 133,015 7
119
Source: Oak Ridge National Laboratory, State Water Use and Socioeconomic Data Re the Second National Water Assessment, prepared for the U.S. Water Resources Coun Ridge, Tenn., 1980).
― 87 ― The relations between water scarcity and growth implied in the data and projections of the Second National Water Assessment can be examined for water resource regions and subregions, the geographical areas for which water supply data are provided. These regions and subregions are defined according to drainage basins which do not conform to political boundaries. Regions 9 to 18 and their 53 subregions are used as a proxy for the seventeen western states in the subsequent analysis. Water scarcity (measured as the ratio of total water use in the 1975 base year to average year streamflow) is negatively correlated (at a 95 percent confidence level) with the Assessment's projections of the growth of irrigated
acreage by water resource subregion. Nevertheless, the Assessment's projections of population, employment, and total earnings by subregion are positively correlated (at a 90 percent confidence level or better) with this water scarcity measure. These results suggest that the features that attracted people in the past and contributed to the pressures on water supplies will continue to give these areas faster than average overall growth in spite of the pressures on their water supplies. The water to support the fast overall growth of these subregions, however, will come at least in part from a slower than average or in some cases negative growth of irrigated agriculture. In examining the implications of water scarcity on water use by function, it is nearly as instructive, and conceptually much simpler, to differentiate between just two areas—a water-scarce area and the rest of the West— rather than to consider 53 different subregions. A water-scarce area of twenty subregions (identified in Figure 3.1 and in the note to Table 3.3) has been selected for this purpose. In all twenty of these subregions, 1975 water use exceeded average year streamflows. Most of these subregions also have relatively high ratios of groundwater mining to consumption; mining is 10 percent or more of consumption in sixteen of the subregions, and 25 percent or more in twelve of them. Estimates of instream use have an important impact on the perception of water scarcity. In thirty-three of the western subregions, the instream flows needed to maintain fish and wildlife populations are more than half of the Assessment's estimates of total water use in 1975. The benefits that accrue from instream flows are difficult to measure, and there is no consensus as to how much water should be allocated to these uses. This does not mean, however, that instream benefits are insignificant.
― 88 ―
Figure 3.1 Twenty Water Resource Subregions with Serious Water Supply Problems (cross-hatched area)
― 89 ―
Table 3.3 Sectoral Water Consumption Estimates for 1975 and Projections for 1985 and 2000 Water Use (thousand acre-feet per year) 20 Water-scarce
1975
1985
2000
subregionsl Irrigation
53,553
51,953
50,539
Livestock
559
629
730
Steam electric
234
606
1,294
Manufacturing
372
486
775
Domestic
1,792
2,009
2,284
Minerals
974
1,163
1,332
Other
926
1,015
1,144
Total
58,410
57,861
58,098
Irrigation
35,246
43,129
43,466
Livestock
769
974
1,077
Steam electric
233
785
2,075
Manufacturing
1,365
2,112
3,733
Domestic
1,525
1,695
1,929
Minerals
562
652
790
Other
997
1,202
1,567
Total
40,697
50,549
54,637
Irrigation
88,793
95,082
94,005
Livestock
1,328
1,604
1,808
33 Other subregions2
Totals for water resource regions 9-18
Steam electric
467
1,391
3,369
Manufacturing
1,737
2,598
4,508
Domestic
3,317
3,704
4,212
Minerals
1,537
1,814
2,121
Other
1,923
2,216
2,710
Total
99,102
108,409
112,733
Note: National future data for average water supply conditions. Source: U.S. Water Resources Council, The Nation's Water Resources, The Second National Assessment, vol. 3, app. II (Washington, D.C., GPO, 1978), table II-4. 1
This water-scarce area includes the following water resource subregions: 1007, 1010, 1102, 1103, 1105, 1106, 1203, 1204, 1302, 1303, 1304, 1305, 1502, 1503, 1602, 1603, 1604, 1803, 1806, and 1807. 2
The 33 other subregions are calculated as the sum of water resource regions 9 to 18 minus the 20 water-scarce subregions.
― 90 ― On the other hand, provision of many instream benefits need not be competitive with offstream uses. For example, the better recreational areas in the West often are in the upper reaches of the streams. Streamflows can be maintained in these areas for withdrawal downstream where the better agricultural lands are often located. Thus, adding instream uses measured at the outflow point of a subregion and offstream consumption may overstate a region's water use. Nevertheless, even when instream uses are ignored— which few people would advocate—water problems remain. Offstream consumption alone is equal to, or greater than, average streamflow in seven of the water-scarce subregions. And 1975 water consumption exceeded dry year streamflow (the natural flow that will be equaled or exceeded 80 percent of the time) in all the water-scarce subregions identified in Figure 3.1.
Projections from the Second National Water Assessment suggest that while total water consumption will be essentially constant within the water-scarce region over the last quarter of the century, the allocation of water among types of users will shift. According to the projections, a decline of nearly 6 percent in consumption for irrigation is expected to slightly more than offset the 56 percent increase in consumption for all other uses (see Table 3.3). But even after this reallocation of supplies, irrigation will remain the dominant water user, accounting for 87 percent of consumption in the year 2000. In contrast to the outlook in the twenty water-scarce subregions, there are opportunities for expanding both total and irrigation water consumption in the rest of the West for at least another decade. Indeed, the Second National Water Assessment projects that water consumption in the remaining thirty-three subregions will increase 22 percent for irrigation and 36 percent for other purposes between 1975 and 1985. Only a very minor further expansion of water consumption for irrigation is projected for after 1985, but consumption for all other uses is projected to increase 50 percent over the last fifteen years of the century. The twenty-five year projections for these thirty-three subregions suggest total water consumption will rise by one-third and consumption for purposes other than irrigation will more than double.
Limitations of the Projections in the Assessment The Second National Water Assessment is the only recent attempt to systematically examine the nation's water use and supplies. But, as alluded to above and as considered in some
― 91 ― detail below, there are good reasons for questioning some aspects of these projections.
Water for Energy Although nonagricultural demands on western waters have been relatively minor in the past, development of the West's vast energy resources, especially coal and oil shale, may alter that. While water consumption projections of the Second National Water Assessment include an allowance for steam electric production, petroleum refining, and fuels mining, there was concern that the Assessment had not taken adequate account of all likely energy developments and associated water requirements. This concern led to a supplementary study by Aerospace Corporation, which accepts all the Assessment's water supply data and all the demand projections except
those relating to energy.[8] From four federally generated energy development scenarios, the maximum feasible limits for energy development are determined along with associated water requirements, assuming standard size plants and no special provisions to adopt water-conserving technologies. Although these estimates are higher than any likely levels, they provide an upper bound to the demands energy development is likely to place on western waters. In comparison to the Assessment projections presented in Table 3.3, the high projections of water for energy development in the Aerospace report increase nonirrigation water consumption levels by 7 percent as of 1985 and 39 percent as of 2000. These estimates represent a 1 percent increase in total western water use by 1985 and a 6 percent increase by 2000. Although the percentage changes for the West are modest, the impacts would be localized, and within the affected regions major new demands on water supplies are implied. Where demand already exceeds renewable supplies, any increase requires either compensating reductions among other users or additional groundwater mining. The twenty water-scarce subregions account for about 47 percent of the consumption of water for energy projected for the turn of the century in the Aerospace report. In the absence of compensating adjustments by other users, this would increase energy uses to about 8 percent of this area's total water consumption. Water for energy would become particularly important in seven of these subregions, where energy uses would account for an average of 19 percent of total projected water consumption.[9] If these energy projections are realized, irrigation
― 92 ― certainly would be adversely affected. The Second Assessment had already projected that irrigated acreage in these seven subregions would decline from 16 percent of the West's total as of 1975 to 10 percent in 2000.[10] The percentage might drop further if the higher energy water use levels are realized. The Aerospace projections suggest that energy uses could become an even more important component of water consumption in some of the subregions where water currently does not pose such constraints to development. In nine of the other thirty-three western subregions, the combined energy uses of water account for an average of 35 percent of total projected offstream water use in 2000.[11] In general, however, these nine subregions do not rank among the more important irrigated areas; they are projected to account for only 6 percent of the water consumption and 4 percent of the land for irrigation in the West by 2000.
Alternative Population and Water Use Projections The data and projections presented above as the Assessment view are the product of the federal attempt to develop nationally consistent information on current and projected water use. They are known as the National Future (NF) estimates. But for some of the regions and some of the socioeconomic and water use variables, an alternate set of information is also presented in the Assessment. A study team representing state and regional perspectives was formed for each of the 21 water resources regions, and these teams developed State-Regional Future (SRF) estimates for their respective regions. The SRF projections are not comprehensive, nor are they based on a consistent set of assumptions as to the national growth. Yet, as the Assessment points out, they do reflect a more localized and perhaps more accurate view of regional and subregional conditions.[12] There are some striking differences between some of the NF and SRF projections of population growth and water use that raise questions about the accuracy of the National Future estimates. The SRF projections suggest a national population (including the Caribbean area) of nearly 284 million by 2000, nearly 6 percent more than the NF projection. While the NF figure is closer to and actually slightly above the Census Bureau's mean estimates of total population in 2000, the regional distribution of the NF projection is questionable. Virtually the entire difference between the alternative population projections in the Assessment is attributable to the lower NF projections for the western water resource regions. Despite the fact that
― 93 ― population in the seventeen western states grew at more than twice the national average from 1974-79,[13] the NF data project lower than average population growth for the West as a whole from 1975-2000 (see Table 3.1). This inexplicable result suggests that the NF data may understate the future demands for western water. The NF estimates of irrigated acreage in the West are also much lower than the SRF estimates in both the 1975 base year (40.6 versus 46.2 million acres) and in 2000 (44.9 versus 61.3 million acres). While there is considerable uncertainty as to the amount of land under irrigation, it is likely that the NF data grossly understate irrigated acreage in the base as well as in future years.[14] For instance, the National Resources Inventory estimate of 50.2 million acres irrigated in the West in 1977 is 24 percent above the 1975 NF estimate and 9 percent above the 2000 NF estimate.[15] The impact on water use estimates of understating irrigation levels is unknown. But again there is a possibility that the NF projections understate the competition for western water resources.
In view of the differences noted above between the base year levels of irrigation and the projected changes in western population and irrigation, it is not surprising that the NF and SRF estimates of water use also differ. The SRF estimates of total water consumption in water resource regions 9-18 are lower in the base year (84.7 versus 88.5 billion gallons per day) but considerably higher by the year 2000 (120.7 versus 100.7 billion gallons per day) than the NF projections. In both years, water consumed in irrigation accounts for more than 90 percent of the differences between the two sets of data.
A Case Study: The Yampa River Despite the reservations about the projections of the Second National Water Assessment, these data do indicate the broad changes in water scarcity likely to emerge from the increasing competition for western water and the implications of these changes on major categories of water users. These data, however, are not sufficiently detailed to provide much insight into local water problems or the nature of the competition for water. Indeed, there may be serious conflicts over the use of a region's or subregion's waters not revealed by the Assessment's aggregate supply and consumption data. Changes which have only
― 94 ― marginal impacts on the overall level of western irrigation may have dramatic impacts on local areas, even within regions and subregions where water does not appear in the Assessment as being particularly scarce. These points are illustrated in the following discussion of the Yampa River, a tributary of the Green River which in turn is a tributary of the Colorado River.[16] The Yampa River is celebrated for its beauty and is a prime sports fishery. It also contains abundant resources of coal and is being considered for possible energy development. To assess the effect of energy and fuel production on the Yampa River flows at Maybell, Colorado (USGS gauging station 2510), scenarios were assumed for 1990. A. 2,000 Mw thermal electric power plant using 6.7 million tons of coal per year; the remainder of the 24 million tons per year of coal mined shipped out of the basin by unit train. B. 2,000 Mw thermal electric power plant; 250 million standard cubic feet per day coal (SCFD) gasification plant using 6.94 million
tons of coal per year; the remainder of the 24 million tons per year of coal mined is shipped out of the basin by unit train. Details of these two energy development scenarios are presented in Table 3.4. For assessing the water consumed in these two scenarios, a "base case" plant and a "complete" plant are considered for both the power plant and the coal gasification plant. The "base case" represents a situation in which no restrictions are placed on waste discharges to the environment; the "complete" plant, a situation where zero wastewater discharges are allowed. As shown in Table 3.4, the two energy development scenarios, plus the "base" and "complete" plant options for both the thermal power plant and the gasification plant, result in six possible combinations of water consumption. For these six combinations, the water consumption rates for the year 1990 range from a low of 59.4 cubic feet per second (cfs) (43 thousand acre-feet per year) to a high of 101.3 cfs (73.3 thousand acre-feet per year). The effect of this consumptive use of water on the flow of the Yampa River at Maybell is depicted in Table 3.5. For comparison, energy scenario B with "complete" plants for both the thermal power and coal gasification facilities was assumed (scenario B4 in Table 3.4). This consumptive use of water is compared with the mean annual flow, the mean monthly flows, and various measures of the low flow in the Yampa River at Maybell, Colorado. It is clear from Table 3.5 that energy development
― 95 ―
Table 3.4 Consumptive Use of Water in the Yampa River Basin Under Energy Development Assumptions Energy Development Assumptions Development projection:
1990
Surface mining of coal:
24 million tons/year
Thermal electric power plant:
2,000 megawatts
Coal gasification plant:
250 million standard cubic feet/day
Coal input: Power plant:
6.70 million tons/year
Gasification plant:
6.94 million tons/year
Excess coal:
10.36 million tons/year
(shipped by unit train out of the Yampa River Basin)
Water Consumption Scenarios (cubic feet per second) Scenariosa Al Power plantb —base casec
A2
54.8
B1
B2
54.8
54.8
49.4
complete plantd Gasification plant— base casec
36.5
B3
B4
49.4
49.4
36.5
27.9
complete plantd
27.9
Mining and land reclamation
10.0
10.0
10.0
10.0
10.0
10.0
Total water consumption
64.8
59.4
101.3 92.7
95.9
87.3
Source: Nicholas C. Matalas and Richard Smith, "Yampa River Case Study," paper presented at the Resources for the Future Forum on the Impact of Energy Development on the Waters, Fish and Wildlife in the Upper Colorado River Basin, in Albuquerque, New Mexico, October 1976. a
Scenario A—power plant only; scenario B—power plant plus gasification plant. b
Mechanical draft-cooling towers.
c
No restrictions on waste dischargers.
d
Zero waste discharges (except for condensate).
― 96 ―
Table 3.5 Comparison of Streamflows and Consumptive Use of Water for Energy Development in the Yampa River Basin (USGS gauging station 2510 at Maybell, Colorado) Streamflows (cubic feet per second)
Streamflow at USGS Station 2510
Water Consumption in the Yampa Caused by Energy Developmenta
Net Flow at Maybell, Colorado
Mean annual
1,560
87
1,473
October
343
87
256
November
345
87
258
December
298
87
211
January
272
87
185
February
320
87
233
March
671
87
584
April
2,620
87
2,533
May
6,280
87
6,193
Mean monthly
June
5,540
87
5,453
July
1,360
87
1,273
August
380
87
293
September
241
87
154
1-day
41
87
b
3-day
41
87
b
7-day
45
87
b
30-day
62
87
b
365-day
1,060
87
973
Low flows (10year)
a
Water consumption scenario B4, Table 3.4.
b
Storage will be required for the low flow periods.
― 97 ― could not occur in the Yampa River Basin without surface or groundwater storage, or supplemental supplies from another subbasin. There simply is not enough water for energy and fuel production purposes during the low flow periods. Moreover, tradeoffs with other uses of river waters might have to be made during parts of the year, especially the seven-month period from August through February. Apparently, from this rough analysis of streamflows in the Yampa, the fisheries might be in serious jeopardy if energy development occurs, or hydraulic works might have to be undertaken that many think would adversely alter the character of the basin.
The only way to understand the full implications of energy development is to look at the details of specific situations. Unfortunately, such analyses are seldom part of studies assessing the energy potential of a region. Such studies should have high priority.
Conclusions and Implications for Water Management[en17]Conclusions and Implications for Water Management[17] While the West is not running out of water, it is running out of readily available, inexpensive water. Although some additions to the usable water supplies of the region may be developed either through streamflow augmentation or exploration and development of groundwater, the end may be coming of any large-scale schemes for further diversions of water into the region, or even any sizable shifts of water from one basin to another within the region. Thus, for practical purposes it would seem that the region must accept the limited nature of its water supplies and should move strongly to adapt itself to that condition. The limited nature of water supplies, however, does not absolutely preclude development within the region. Barriers to urban residential or other development are more a matter of social than of physical limitations. Such barriers may be the institutions that prevent the transfer of water from agricultural uses into other, more highly valued, uses; or they may be social insistence on artificially low prices for municipal water. Instead of promoting rigid constraints on water use patterns, political effort within the region should be directed toward increasing the flexibility of current water use practices among all users. Generally speaking, there is considerable opportunity for modification if regional institutions permit and encourage it.
― 98 ― For example, in planning new electrical generation facilities in the San Juan portion of the Colorado River that lies in New Mexico, utilities have available several options regarding the use of cooling water, even though the New Mexico State Engineer has projected a fully appropriated condition for the San Juan Basin without the addition of any new generating facilities. First, technological adjustments could be made in the cooling water required. Second, existing privately held water rights in the basin could be purchased, and with approval of existing authorities this water could be transferred into industrial use from its current predominant use in agriculture. Third, cooling water might be drawn from deep groundwater stocks rather than from currently used surface water supplies. These and other options illustrate the range of possibilities for flexible water use within the region. One general institution that contributes to flexibility is the existence, where
permitted, of an economic market for water rights. Such a market, if it works properly, signals all water users, in the form of the price that a water right may command, that (a) water is available, and (b) that competing demands for its use can be measured. With the information provided by the price signal, current and prospective water users can make informed decisions on water use options. In addition, as the price of water rights increases, there is a strong incentive to conserve water. The economic returns to water used in irrigation tend to be lower than in most other uses. Accordingly, where demand exceeds supply, and institutions permit water to be transferred among sectors, water tends to be bid away from irrigation. Nonetheless, these forces will not necessarily result in large transfers of water out of irrigation. Since irrigation is the dominant offstream use of western water, large percentage increases in other water consumption can be accommodated with relatively small percentage reductions in irrigation use. Furthermore, many new demands can be met without transferring water away from agriculture. Deep or brackish groundwaters generally considered unsuitable for irrigation are available in some areas, and some primary sites for energy development still have untapped surface waters. Thus, even if the Assessment has understated nonirrigation water demands, water transfers among sectors will have only marginal effects on the total quantity of water consumed for irrigation.
― 99 ― Regional irrigation trends initiated several decades ago in response to competition for water will continue. Some decline in irrigated acreage within the area from the southern High Plains to Arizona and Nevada is likely, as nonagricultural users bid water away from irrigation and farmers reduce pumping in response to declining groundwater tables and high energy costs. These declines will be more than offset by continued expansion of irrigation in areas where relatively low cost water is still available. The Nebraska Sandhills area will be one of the few areas in the West that will experience a significant further expansion of irrigated acreage. The overall rate of growth of irrigated acreage in the West will continue to fall over the next several decades, but is not likely to turn negative during this century. Net expansion will depend in large part on agricultural prices. A modest 5 to 6 percent expansion (roughly 3 million acres) of irrigated acreage seems likely if real crop prices remain at roughly their 1975-80 average. A 25 percent increase in real crop prices might stimulate a net expansion of about 15 percent (nearly 8 million acres). In either case, however, the competition for increasingly scarce water supplies should bring the expansion of irrigated land to a halt early in the next century. Principal changes in irrigation will be qualitative rather than quantitative in the coming decades. The quantity of water consumed for agriculture is likely
to peak before irrigated acreage peaks. No peak in irrigated production is likely for the foreseeable future, however. As water costs rise, technologies and management practices that conserve water become more profitable. Since much of the irrigation in the West developed under and continues to be based on very low-cost water, the opportunities for substituting capital, labor, and management skills for water are great, and will be utilized with increasing frequency as water becomes scarce. The potential for such substitutions is illustrated in the High Plains Development Study which concluded that high energy costs would encourage a rapid improvement in irrigation efficiency. Average water use in the Texas High Plains is projected to decline from 1.38 acre-feet per acre in 1977 to 0.68 in 1990. Crop yields, however, are expected to continue to rise throughout the period and beyond.[18] Major constraints on western development over the rest of this century are likely to stem from institutional factors affecting water supply. As noted above, nonirrigation demands for water can be accommodated with only marginal effects on the overall
― 100 ― level of irrigation. But it is by no means certain that water will be transferred to higher value uses on a timely basis, or that farmers will have incentives to make the investments and management changes required for more efficient water use. The institutions, including the legal system, affecting water use were developed when water was plentiful in relation to demand. Often these institutions, which vary widely among states, restrict transfers to alternative uses and discourage conservation measures. To the extent that the competition for water is relegated to the courts and state regulatory agencies rather than the market place, overall western development is likely to suffer. Although such restrictions tend to favor agriculture since irrigators commonly own the most senior water rights, continued development of western irrigation depends on incentives for improving water use efficiency, not on locking water into low-value uses.
Discussion: A.N. Halter The views expressed in this paper reflect the opinions of the author and not the opinions of the Electric Power Research Institute or its members. In this discussion, my comments are divided into two sections. The first follows the outline of the Frederick-Kneese paper from the perspective of the adequacy of the methodologies used, with particular emphasis on water and energy. The second section discusses some of the implications of how pricing structures of electricity affect water use.
Review of Frederick-Kneese Paper In their "Overview" and "Past Changes in Water Use", past trends in water use are shown to be the history of the expansion of irrigation. Growth in irrigation relied on surface water until the mid-1950s, when groundwater took over as the major source of supply. The authors should have pointed out that it was low-cost energy that made it possible to lift groundwater inexpensively. In the authors' description of the projections of the Second National Water Assessment study, the following points should be noted: 1) Although assumptions of population growth are questioned and superficially related to the collapse of energy markets, other than referring to higher water costs and improved efficiency of uses, there apparently is no underlying pricing structure used to make the projections. 2) Frederick and Kneese relate water scarcity to the Assessment's projections of water availability, and projections of population, employment, and total earnings. Negative and positive correlations respectively suggest a methodology was used to make Assessment projections that is naive and devoid of economic dynamics and price structures. 3) Limitations of the Assessment are reviewed by the authors, and the supplemental study by Aerospace Corporation to cover the energy use of water is recounted. Though the authors point out that no special provision is made for including the possible effects of adopting water-conserving technologies,
― 103 ― they do little to convince the reader that a better methodology was used by the Aerospace Corporation than by the Assessment study. They also point out that National Future estimates likely understate the competition for water resources, and are different from those made by the State-Regional Future study. Under the heading of "Conclusions", the authors say that expansion in irrigated acreage in the West will depend in large part on agricultural prices, but do not relate it to energy prices in any general way. Institutional factors are given the major credit for limiting the use of water. This is the usual conclusion from resource studies in which the dynamics of supply-demand interaction are ignored. The current situation in energy speaks loudly for further demand constraint as pricing structures change.
The remainder of the Frederick-Kneese paper presents a case study of the Upper Colorado River Basin and its tributaries, a case that has been overstudied with little variation in the conclusions drawn. The Southwest Region Under Stress Project conducted by the authors' employer, Resources for the Future (RFF), justifies the use of the Colorado River as a case study as the authors are knowledgeable about the region. The RFF study uses a scenario approach to project energy development. The "speculative nature" of this approach is emphasized in that it ignores the price of electricity. The only factors said to affect water consumption in generating stations are the technology, quality of coal, and utilization rate; these in turn are said to be dependent on cost of water and other inputs. Pricing structures on the output or demand side are assumed away by the usual implicit assumption of the fundamental right to electricity and food. Again, institutional changes are emphasized as necessary in the concluding section of the paper. One such change recommended by the authors is an "economic market" for water rights. Supply and demand for water rights would set their price and exchange among users. But the authors do not indicate how such a market would adjust for the inevitable uncertainty in streamflows and consequent shortages of electricity. The cost of electricity outages to the society and the economy are not considered in a water rights market. The lack of a holistic approach to institutional development can be just as detrimental to water
― 104 ― allocation as the partial analyses used for making forecasts of water consumption. One must question the methodologies being used for planning water resource use. In most cases the methods are so unclear that one must ask: what is the methodology for long-range forecasting for water and/or energy? Do forecasts reflect only conventional wisdom and the subjective preferences of the experts and institutions doing the planning, rather than the dynamics of interactive components in society and the economy? Does longrange planning for water, rooted in long-range forecasting of energy demand, rest on shaky ground? Under foreseeable conditions, especially changing costs, associated prices, and rate structures, demands are very likely to depart from patterns of the past.
Impacts of Electricity Price Structures on Water Use Since I have emphasized that resource studies and long-range planning studies for water must be necessarily rooted in some expected schedule of prices for outputs and inputs, it is only appropriate that I also point out the impacts on water use of different pricing structures for electricity.
Prices for electricity are influenced not only by prices of petroleum, but also by utility regulation and rate structures. The unfortunate aspect of averagecost pricing, imposed by a 100-year-old regulatory environment, is that consumers do not experience the full cost of new sources of energy and hence of electricity. At a later time when prices must inevitably rise, many users of electricity are stuck with equipment and facilities required on the basis of former conditions. This can only lead to even more inefficient use of water. The water resource planner can no longer ignore the consequences of faulty regulation of the electric utility business. Clearly, electricity conservation and peak-load pricing affect the amount of water and its pattern of use in irrigation. Declining block-pricing structures for electricity formerly created an incentive for groundwater overdrafting, because it was cheaper per unit to lift larger quantities of water. New inverted blockrate structures will remove that incentive, and should help to reduce the problem of overdraft. Another innovative pricing structure being studied by energy economists and likely to be adopted by the electric utility industry is "responsive" pricing. As the term implies, electricity is priced essentially instantaneously as it is produced at its marginal cost. The communication and computer technology is already
― 105 ― available to implement this for large users such as water districts, industrial firms, and municipal institutions. This time-of-use pricing structure would have a profound impact on water use in agriculture, as well as in industry and public institutions. The proper pricing of electricity for the major share of users would allow the simplest of rates to be used for residential customers. The confusion being caused by the proliferation of rates for residential customers is unfortunate and unnecessary, leading to further mistrust of electric utilities and the misallocation of energy and water. The uncertainties of supply of electricity, given any pricing structure, must still be dealt with. The institution of a simple buy-back scheme could eliminate the consequences of shortage in an economic manner. The buyback scheme could be similar to the one used by airlines to buy back seating when there is overbooking of a flight. A similar institution in the water area would complement the Frederick-Kneese suggestion of a water rights market.
Discussion: Robert R. Curry This paper does a good job of assessing the inadequacies of the U.S. Water Resources Council's report, The Nation's Water Resources 1975-2000: The Second National Water Assessment. However, many factors of supply and competition are not considered in either this paper or the Second National Assessment. Some of these are reviewed briefly here. Groundwater availability is a serious problem, and groundwater quality is fast becoming equally serious. Technologic solutions are adequate for the short run, but when considered in a 25-50 year time frame, are probably worse than no solutions. As Frederick and Kneese point out, about 40 percent of western irrigation water is presently derived from groundwater, and five out of every six gallons withdrawn from the ground is used for irrigation. Further, of 56 million acre-feet withdrawn (estimated) in 1975, 22 million are overdrafted in excess of safe yield (mined). The authors further point out that, in half of the western watershed subregions, fully 50 percent or more of the consumption is derived from overdrafted groundwater. Groundwater law and the public institutional framework are archaic throughout the West, and in many cases are based upon wholly faulty assumptions and models of groundwater dynamics.
― 106 ― Thus, even in the most progressive states, water developers are encouraged to recover water with high energy costs from deep aquifers with poor water quality that will ultimately damage both surface soils and aquifers. In most cases the damage is irreparable. Particularly damaging is saline seep, which is an agricultural artifact of dryland farming techniques used in northern plains states. It renders unproductive tens of thousands of acres of agricultural land annually, at a rate far exceeding strip-mining, highway construction, and urban sprawl combined in those areas. Salt loading and destruction of soil structure and ultimate productivity is a concomitant of use of sodic saline water for agriculture. We are often told of the great advantages to be gained by development of salt-tolerant food crops and forage. While it is certainly possible to increase productivity even while utilizing water of declining quality, such technology has a very discrete and finite limit, beyond which sodic loading will render the site essentially nonproductive. The progressive character of such actions means that we must ultimately pay the cost for myopia. Groundwater pollution is another area of grave concern. Many of our
assumptions about future groundwater supplies for all uses assume that known high-quality groundwater reservoirs will remain usable. We are learning, however, that the publicized horrors of Love Canal are but a small localized example of a much more pervasive nationwide problem.[1] As cataloged by the Environmental Protection Agency, landfill and other sources of contamination have set serious limits on the period of time for which we may reasonably expect to recover groundwater from many significant and important local aquifers. Thus, even though we may not exceed safe yield pumping, we may have a limited lifetime for aquifers before we begin recycling our own wastes into domestic supplies or agricultural soils. Our projections of water supplies assume that supplies presently potable will remain so, despite saline intrusion, aquifer mixing, contamination through mineral extraction, industrial surface and groundwater pollution, and leachate contamination. The non-reversibility of such contamination seems to have escaped most analysts. Groundwater overdraft is also a serious problem not clearly addressed. While we may estimate safe yield and overdraft rather precisely, in fact we know very little about site details. It is actually very difficult to estimate overdraft. Since agriculture itself, particularly salt-tolerant agriculture, and other land uses
― 107 ― all tend to impede surface water infiltration through the root zone into the groundwater reservoirs, most observed overdraft is not a linear function of rate of withdrawal. Other things being constant, overdraft tends to increase with a fixed withdrawal rate, particularly where new lands are being brought into production and being urbanized. Thus, linear projections probably underestimate the true situation for the year 2000. Energy costs are an increasingly important factor in water costs. Analysis of competition for western water requires careful attention to the economic pricing and institutional factors governing costs of water and electricity. As more and more water is delivered at costs of several hundred dollars per acre-foot, as in the California Water Project, many forms of agriculture are unable to afford additional water. What this has meant in California is that only large-scale corporate farms occupying large acreages of previously marginal land of questionable long-term productivity, and growing specialized high cash-yield crops, can afford to compete with urban and industrial water needs in a quasi-open market. As Frederick and Kneese point out rather inadequately, the cost of electricity is an increasingly important factor in groundwater costs. But several other energy cost factors are equally important. The cost of energy is increasingly important in all water supply systems, particularly those utilizing offstream storage, large storage reservoirs of any sort, or extensive conveyance structures. There is also feedback between the rising cost of electricity and cost of water for irrigation. As irrigation costs increase and food costs follow, it becomes
economically feasible and desirable to store and transport higher cost food commodities. This means that an increasing fuel resource is utilized in food production and distribution, thus increasing competition for fuels for electricity production. Finally, there is critical social disruption caused by increasing supplies of high-cost agricultural water. This is well illustrated in the San Joaquin Valley of California, where high-cost federal and state projects deliver water to new sites for large, highly capitalized and mechanized farms. These large-scale operations, using expensive water on sites with drainage problems, salt loading, or poor soils, can temporarily compete with small family farms that have long-established food production systems often using gravity-feed streamflow irrigation sources or other lowcost riparian rights. The economic competition damages a diverse, efficient, long-productive food growing system in favor of a short-lived, high energydependent, unstable system. Thus pricing and delivery
― 108 ― institutions destroy a long-term resource base for short-term production gains. Regional autonomy also declines as large-scale water delivery systems increase. Ultimately, rising energy costs will preclude continued production on the energy-dependent sites, but the low-energy-demand sites will meanwhile have been lost to urbanization, or their gravity water rights sold for other purposes. Long term climatic change is a final factor that must be considered in a thorough evaluation of water resource demands. As pointed out by Harold Fritts in Chapter 1, the "historic" record of climate, including runoff and precipitation, leads to considerable overestimation of future resources. Study of tree-ring or other paleoclimatic records suggests that our concepts of drought used in present planning are rather naive. The unusual 20th century moderate climate cannot be expected to persist.
PART II— ALTERNATIVES FOR SATISFYING AGRICULTURAL WATER DEMANDS Chapter 4— Developing New Water Supplies by Harvey O. Banks, Jean O. Williams, and Joe B. Harris
Abstract The inadequacy or maldistribution of water supplies for agricultural and other water users throughout most of the western U.S. has historically been a focus of attention for the local citizenry, for water planners and developers, engineers, conservationists, economists, promoters and others concerned with the future of the region. This paper looks at the potential for developing alternative water supplies for the region, with special emphasis on meeting the future water needs of the agricultural sector. Prospects for importing excess surface waters into the region, either from international or domestic sources, are examined along with several local water enhancement or augmentation potentials. Weather modification, water harvesting/water banking techniques, desalination and/or use of saline water supplies, water Reclamation and reuse, surface/groundwater management, improvements in operation of existing projects to increase yields, and other prospects for local water supply enhancement are discussed. General conclusions are that the probabilities for large-scale new water supplies or developments for the region in the foreseeable future are not great. The potentials for significant breakthroughs in local water supply enhancement or any large-scale water importation for the semiarid West are limited.
Development of irrigated agriculture in the semiarid to arid regions of the Great Plains, the Southwest, and the far western states was an inevitable step in the westward growth in the United States. Given the physical conditions of the availability of land, deep, productive soils, advantageous terrain, and climate that appeared to be suited to large-scale dryland farming, the agriculturally oriented culture of the western expansion quickly established an economy of boom-and-bust dryland farming. Early reclamation programs demonstrated the potential for irrigation in these vast western lands. When, in the 1930s, deep
― 110 ― wells became more feasible and economic, extensive drilling tapped what were apparently unlimited groundwater resources, and irrigation spread rapidly throughout the Plains states, the Southwest, and wherever the combination of good land, favorable climate and cheap, plentiful water supplies could be found. Irrigation expanded even more rapidly after World War II. By the 1960s, it had become apparent that groundwater resources were being depleted. Commitments of surface water to irrigation through reclamation projects came under increasingly heavy fire from existing or potential competing water users. More sensitive environmental concerns were also expressed. Throughout the West, a critical water supply crisis was developing. Thus, water planners and developers, economists, politicians, and citizens concerned with the future have turned their attention to the potential for developing new water supplies. Simultaneously, the options for improving the efficiency of use of existing supplies have been subjected to intense study, as is reflected in other chapters of this volume. This chapter deals with the prospects for developing new or augmented water supplies. There are relatively few new water resources in the West remaining to be developed. The prospects of developing those are slight and the costs would be very high. There are, however, opportunities for better allocation of supplies from existing projects, for improvement in management of such projects, for intervention in the hydrologic cycle to modify precipitation events on a basis more nearly related to man's needs than nature provides, and for application of some of the newer technologies. With that understanding, we will look briefly at the potential for new or augmented water supplies for irrigation in the West.
Imports from Outside the United States Both Canada and Mexico share borders with the United States, and across those borders occur common problems of matching water needs with available supply. Yet within the continent of North America vast quantities of surface water occur, and the developable yield of all of those resources could meet the needs of all three nations for the foreseeable future, if it were possible to develop, allocate, manage, and use the water in the common interest. Realistically, the difficulty of this coordination, while
― 111 ―
not insurmountable, is awesome, particularly as regards the political/legal/institutional/financial aspects. Within our own United States, discussions of interbasin transfers of water within a state or between and among states are generally conducted with a great deal more heat than light, and often with extraordinarily slow results. While international development and allocation of available water resources may be difficult and very long-term in prospect, they are not impossible, and in most cases could be shown to be mutually advantageous for each nation and regional (or basin) participant. One of the axioms of any water transfer proposal is that there must be demonstrable benefits for all parties—both importers and exporters. But let us look at some of the international potentials that have been examined. These international water transfer schemes are highly conceptual and typically have been investigated at only reconnaissance levels of feasibility. Water development sites and facilities have not been identified specifically, nor have meaningful cost projections been prepared. Projected future costs in excess of $100 billion for complete system installation could be anticipated. Looking first to the case of Canada, we here give brief discussions of four proposals for moving water from Canada to the United States.
The Rocky Mountain Plan[en1]The Rocky Mountain Plan[1] The Rocky Mountain Plan, conceived by William G. Dunn, Consulting Engineer, is a potential massive, international water and power development project that would distribute water and power throughout the West from Canada to the Mexican border. Principal sources of water are the Peace, Athabasca, and Smoky rivers in northern Alberta (Canada), and upper tributaries of the Mackenzie River in northern British Columbia, which flows into the Arctic Ocean. Additional sources of water are the Kootenai and Flathead rivers and Clark Fork in western Montana, which are upper tributaries of the Columbia River. Water would be diverted for use within the Yellowstone, Missouri, and the Snake rivers in the northwestern United States, and upper tributaries of the North and South Saskatchewan rivers in Alberta. The water distribution system would include several large reservoirs with a total storage capacity of nearly 100 million acre-feet. Project yield would range from 12 to 25 million acrefeet per year, depending on aqueduct and reservoir sizing. This water would be distributed through more than 5,850 miles of
― 112 ―
aqueduct for use in southern Alberta, Montana, Idaho, Wyoming, all of the western states on both sides of the Rocky Mountains including west Texas and California, and northern New Mexico in the Colorado River and Rio Grande valleys. New energy developed under the Rocky Mountain Plan would come from a huge hydroelectric project called the Whitehorse-Skagway Division, collecting water from the upper tributaries of the Yukon River and releasing it through a 2,200-foot power drop into an interior inlet of the Pacific Ocean near Skagway, Alaska. The 33 billion kilowatt hours of power produced by this system would be conveyed in a 2,000-mile transmission line to Alberta, British Columbia, and the Pacific Northwest for general use in the power market, and for project purposes. Three large storage reservoirs with a total storage potential of 60 million acre-feet are proposed within the Columbia River Basin. These reservoirs would include large pumped storage facilities that would reregulate the power developed in the Columbia River plants and in the project power plants, and that also would produce some new power. The entire Rocky Mountain Plan, including power facilities, was estimated to cost between $40 and $50 billion in 1977 dollars. One of the significant advantages of the Rocky Mountain Plan is that it could be staged to provide significant water and power benefits during early development.
Canadian Proposal Three Canadians (Knut Magnusson, Edward Kuiper, and Roy E. Tinney) have proposed concepts for diverting waters from the Athabasca, Peace, and Laird rivers to be conveyed across the plains of northern Alberta, Saskatchewan, and Manitoba to the United States border in North Dakota. A full report on this conceptual plan was not available to the authors, but it is of interest, showing as it does the international concern with such possibilities.
North American Water and Power Alliance (NAWAPA)[en2]North American Water and Power Alliance (NAWAPA)[2] NAWAPA is a master plan concept that proposes taking advantage of the geographical and climatological factors of the North American continent in contrast to the single river basin plan. It would utilize the excess water of Alaska, the Northwest Territories, and the Rocky Mountain regions of Canada, and distribute it to the water-deficient areas of Canada, the United States, and northern Mexico.
― 113 ―
NAWAPA, conceived by the Ralph M.Parsons Company, includes a possible Transcontinental Canal for Canada—a navigable waterway from Alberta to Lake Superior. The canal system, plus the development of rivers in north central Canada, would distribute irrigation water across the plains and increase the flow through the Great Lakes-St. Lawrence System to alleviate water pollution and lowering water levels of that area. The NAWAPA plan is projected to generate 60 to 180 million kilowatts of electric power (net after meeting its own needs), and to supply more than 75 million acre-feet of water annually. The cost to implement the entire NAWAPA concept is estimated at several hundred billion in current (1982) dollars, with spending spread over a 30 to 50-year period.
Western States Water Augmentation Concept[en3]Western States Water Augmentation Concept[3] This plan, proposed by Lewis Gordy Smith, is for a new water system that would permit any available surplus waters from the Fraser River near Hope, British Columbia, and from the Coastal Range in British Columbia to be passed into the Columbia River, and from there conducted within a distribution system both east and west of the Continental Divide. This system would supply water to the Upper Snake, the Humboldt River system of Nevada, the Salt Lake area, the Missouri River system, the Green River and the lower Colorado, the Rio Grande below Albuquerque, and the entire High Plains extending from Nebraska to western Texas. The plan would also look to the ultimate possibility of extending to the far north, to sources of British Columbia, Yukon, and Northwest Territories of Canada, and of later placing this water in the initial water conveyance system within the United States. For the entire collection system from the Dean River to the Columbia, Smith projected a total of 26 dams, ranging in height from 200 to 1,200 feet, costing some $6.3 billion (1967 dollars). Approximately 26 power and pump plants would be required, with total pumping load and power generation potential about balanced. Almost 55 miles of open canal and five main tunnels totaling 56.5 miles, with capacities ranging from 5,500 to 49,000 cubic feet per second would be needed. The above features, along with transmission system, some railway relocation, and miscellaneous structures, would call for a total expenditure of about $11.5 billion in 1967 dollars. In addition to these proposals for moving Canadian water across international boundaries, some planners have discussed the potential of moving water from northern Mexico into the
― 114 ―
United States. These proposals have included capture and transfer of flood waters from the Rio Conchos in northwest Mexico and other potentials along the Mexican eastern coastal area. None of the discussions have been formally considered or presented.
Interstate Diversions of Water Interbasin diversions of water have been in place in many parts of the United States for many years. Rarely have they been carried out without controversy. Where such diversions are contemplated across state lines, the opportunities for conflict and the complexities of law and equity, increase exponentially. Certainly the major western intrastate, interbasin transfer project is the State Water Project in California, planned to have an ultimate firm yield of 4.3 million acre-feet per year and moving water from the north to the south through 715 miles of aqueduct serving municipal, industrial, and agricultural users en route.[4] A careful study of the history of that project—its conception, design, and probably most importantly the ongoing intrastate controversies, conflicts, and regional bitterness generated in its implementation process—should be required reading for water planners and decision makers concerned with acquiring new water supplies. The Federal Central Valley Project in California, also wholly intrastate, has been and still is subject to many of the same problems. Diversions from the Lower Colorado River to California and in the near future to Arizona through the Central Arizona Project are other examples. Major potential sources of water for interbasin diversion to arid western lands include the following.
The Columbia River Basin This potential source of new water supply in the West has been considered from a conceptual standpoint, but federal legislation, sponsored by Senator Henry Jackson of Washington, has since 1968 precluded detailed studies by federal agencies of the potential for diversion into the Colorado River System or into northern California. Legislation has been introduced in the current session of Congress to extend a similar prohibition to all interstate waters.
― 115 ―
The Missouri River Basin Central to much of the development of the Midwest, the Missouri remains
the object of interests in adjacent states as a potential export basin. Intrabasin states understandably object to any out-of-basin commitments of water from the Missouri in the absence of any institutional mechanism protecting long-term in-basin water needs. The Missouri River main stem is already extensively controlled under the Pick-Sloan Plan (Flood Control Act of 1944) by the six main stem dams and reservoirs—Fort Peck, Sakakawea, Oahe, Sharpe, Francis Case and Lewis and Clark—for navigation, flood control, hydropower, and in-basin irrigation, municipal, and industrial uses. Any large exportation would involve tradeoffs with these presently authorized commitments for in-basin uses. In the recently (March 1982) completed report on the Six-State High Plains Ogallala Aquifer Regional Resources Study, conducted under the auspices of the Department of Commerce Economic Development Administration, the U.S. Army Corps of Engineers (Corps) examined the potential of the Missouri as a new water source for irrigation in the six states of Nebraska, Colorado, Kansas, New Mexico, Oklahoma, and Texas.[5] The legislation authorizing the Corps study explicitly limited the source basins for analysis to areas "adjacent" to the six-state region to be served. This eliminated the Columbia River from possible consideration. The Mississippi was also ruled out, and thus the Missouri was selected by the Corps as a potential source basin for its work. Several diversion points and transfer routes were studied. Reconnaissance level design and cost estimates were made for ranges of transfer quantities. The Corps did not make a determination of the amounts of water that might be "surplus" to in-basin needs and thus available for diversion. Transfer quantities of less than two million acre-feet annually to 3.4 million acre-feet were investigated for alternative routings and sizes of facilities. Resulting cost estimates (total investment costs in 1977 dollars) ranged from $2.9 billion to $7.4 billion for a 10-year construction period, and from $4.4 billion to $11.2 billion for a 20-year period for delivery to terminal reservoirs. Unit costs (per acre-foot) of water delivered to terminal storage reservoirs under the alternative routes projected by the Corps from Missouri River sources ranged from $227 to $335. These costs are significantly in excess of the ability to pay for imported water by irrigation agriculture, in the time frame of
― 116 ―
the High Plains Study to year 2020. They also do not include the additional water distribution costs from terminal storage to farm headgates.
Western Arkansas Basins In addition to the potential diversions to the High Plains region from the Missouri River basin, the Corps also assessed the feasibility of interstate, interbasin transfers into the region from several streams in western Arkansas and northeastern Texas. The Arkansas, Ouachita, Red, and White rivers of western Arkansas, and the Sulfur and Sabine rivers in Texas were considered as possible sources. Water transfer quantities for the southern alternative routes ranged from 1.26 maf per year to almost 8.7 maf annual diversion. Unit costs per acrefoot of water delivered to terminal storage sites by the two alternative southern routes of importation to the High Plains region ranged from $430 to $569, considerably more costly than the projected northern routes.
The Mississippi River System The large flood flows of the Mississippi have long been studied as a potential source for water export. Key questions raised by in-basin interests are the long-term needs of in-basin users, high minimum flow requirements to repel intrusion of salt water up-river from the Gulf and for sediment transport, and the need for maintenance of fresh water inflows into coastal bays and estuaries of Louisiana. The extremely limited availability of storage for intermittent diversions of flood flows when they occur is a major roadblock to export from the Mississippi. A feasibility study by the Mississippi River Commission in 1973 of diverting water from the Lower Mississippi River Basin to West Texas and eastern New Mexico exemplifies previous studies of the Mississippi as a potential source basin.[6] The study indicates a technical feasibility for such diversions, but a high cost of delivered water, at about $330 per acre-foot. Total capital costs for the system were estimated at $19.5 billion in 1972 dollars.
Weather Modification Weather modification projects throughout the West have shown variable results to date. While some statistically significant precipitation enhancement results can be documented, they are not consistent and dependable, particularly for the
― 117 ―
convective (summertime) cloud systems of the Great Plains area. Wintertime and high altitude (orographic) cloud seeding programs have been relatively more effective than the summertime experiments, particularly for increasing snowpacks, but significant operational and institutional problems confront all weather modification projects. A related area of water supply augmentation is found in the treatment and management of snow accumulations in those regions or altitudes where significant snowpacks occur. Ongoing research and trials of methods and materials for improving water yields, decreasing evaporative losses, and managing the rate and timing of runoff from snow fields show promise of more dependable water supply management from this source. By the late 70s, the scientific community (cf. U.S. Interdepartmental Committee on Atmospheric Sciences or ICAS)[7] generally accepted the operational capability for seeding wintertime (orographic) clouds to increase precipitation by a factor of 10 to 20 percent. On the basis of a 15 percent increase in snowpack due to seeding, it has been projected that an additional 2+ million acre-feet of water per year, average, could be produced in the Colorado River Basin, at a (1977) cost of about $1.50 per acre-foot. In agricultural use, irrigation benefits are estimated at about $50 per acre-foot of available water. Most other uses have higher per acre-foot values than agriculture. Such large-scale precipitation enhancement would require much larger federal/state cooperative projects than have been attempted to date. A largely unresolved question is, who owns the additional water produced?
Water Harvesting—Water Banking A local water supply enhancement method that has seen extensive development and use in the Mid-East, Africa, and other parts of the world, but limited application in the U.S., is the so-called "water harvesting" technique. This consists essentially of intensive watershed and vegetative management on nearby non-cultivated lands, in order to capture or "harvest" the water for use on cultivated areas. There are extensive areas throughout the West where this technique could be applied. "Water banking" is a technique for capturing available surface water in excess of immediate needs and overwatering areas with favorable infiltration rates. Excess waters are "banked" in groundwater storage through deep percolation for later recapture.
― 118 ― Such projects would necessarily be extensive in nature and involve many landholders. Where state laws direct the acquisition of groundwater rights, many questions of law as well as equity arise with respect to ownership of the banked water supply.
Conjunctive Use The coordinated management of groundwater and usable underground storage capacity with surface water resources and surface storage as an integrated system can often increase available water supplies and reduce costs. The techniques for achieving conjunctive use vary with the specific situation involved. For example, where surface storage is limited or there is none, surface runoff that would otherwise be lost can be stored underground by artificial recharge for later extraction and use. Available surface storage can be used to regulate variable runoff to increase artificial recharge capability. Groundwater can be used to meet peak demands with resultant savings in transmission costs in some cases. Water storage underground minimizes evaporation losses. A degree of natural treatment results from passage of surface water through the soil column in transit to the water table. This is particularly important where polluted surface water or treatment and reclamation of wastewaters are involved. It is emphasized, however, that to achieve full benefits of the conjunctive use potential, the management plan must be based upon thorough considerations of hydrology, geology, and man-induced influences. A carefully planned program of groundwater extractions with respect to areal pattern, amounts, and timing is required in order to maximize the potential for use of underground storage. The possibility of interference with vested groundwater rights must be recognized and any necessary arrangements made for compensation, either in-kind or monetary. Conjunctive use has been extensively practiced in parts of Southern California in a variety of ways for many years with a high degree of success. Here, runoff is highly variable, available surface storage is very limited and costly, and groundwater basins are extensive, although the availability of land for artificial recharge operations is now limited. Artificial recharge and underground storage are used for conservation of local
― 119 ― runoff, for storage and distribution of imported water, and for treatment and storage of reclaimed water. Groundwater rights in several basins have been adjudicated. In at least one other basin, adjudication has not been necessary through acquiescence of the water users who have been more interested in assurance of an adequate water supply of good quality than in legal protection of water rights. Equitable physical solutions have been provided in all cases. The State of California and local agencies are now developing plans to conjunctively use underground storage capacity in Southern California for long-term carryover storage of surplus water from Northern California
imported by the State Water Project.
Desalting/Use of Brackish Water There are modest success stories to relate in agricultural water supply enhancement for the semiarid West. The U.S. Salinity Laboratory and brackish water use programs in Arizona, New Mexico, Texas and other western states have shown significant progress in water management, crop adaptations, soil treatments, and other agricultural techniques for the use of brackish and moderately saline waters. Most western states have sources of largely unused brackish water, both ground and surface, that could be developed for agricultural purposes. The State of New Mexico is estimated to have about 15 billion acre-feet of saline groundwaters (salinity ranges of 1,500 to 15,000 mg/L TDS). The economic and operational feasibility of using typical saline waters representative of New Mexico groundwaters has been investigated for several years. A variety of crops and cropping systems have been demonstrated to have suitable tolerance for such saline irrigation. Many of the more common field crops grown in the West—small grains, cotton, alfalfa, grain sorghums and others—demonstrate this adaptation. The processes of desalting have yet to be established as a large-scale solution to the problem of providing new agricultural water supplies. The increasing costs of the very large amounts of energy required for desalting have made this potential less and less attractive. Continued advances in geothermal or solar energy generation processes may provide in the future a way to treat the available brackish to saline waters on a large scale.
― 120 ―
Water Reclamation and Reuse The potential for reusing water, and the requirements for reclaiming it, restoring it to a quality suitable for reuse, and redistributing it among users, is a cycle of legal, engineering, esthetic, and environmental complexity. Yet, since water is not destroyed by use, it is a cycle nature has always provided. The problems are twofold: separation of use and reuse over time and geography, and the persistent pollutants which our civilization manages to insert into the cycle. The technology for treating wastewater to the point of making it suitable for reuse for irrigation is available, although public health questions about direct reuse for human consumption remain. Certainly the reallocation of reclaimed water to industrial and agricultural users is well within existing technology.
However, irrigated areas where significant volumes of reclaimed water could be used are generally at considerable distances, often with ranges of intervening hills or mountains, from the urban areas where large amounts of wastewater are generated, thus adding significantly to the cost. An example is irrigation in the San Joaquin Valley of California, many miles from the metropolitan areas of the San Francisco Bay region and Southern California. In irrigated agriculture, the increased efficiencies of present practices generally result in full use of applied water, with tailwater recovery and reuse a common practice. Opportunities for improved reuse of agricultural waters still exist on a limited basis, but do not represent significant potentials. Continued research into reuse, and its systematic inclusion in the water resource allocation planning process, are necessary steps in achieving the full potential of this measure.
Improving Existing Project Operations Many projects, in fact most existing projects for surface water development, were planned and authorized under planning concepts, standards and criteria, economic conditions, projected downstream needs, projected upstream depletions, operational criteria, contractual requirements, and political attitudes that differed significantly from those prevailing today. This is true of the main stem developments on the Missouri River, the Federal
― 121 ― Central Valley Project in California, and the California State Water Project, to mention but three examples. At the times these projects were originally planned and authorized, little if any thought was given to the potential for increased yield through conjunctive use with groundwater resources, to the potential benefits which could result from integrated operation with other projects on a "systems" basis, to requiring efficient use of water by water service contractors, or to operating the projects on benefit/risk basis, among other potentials for increasing yields. As stated above, the Missouri River was studied by the U.S. Army Corps of Engineers as a potential source of water for exportation for irrigation in the High Plains area of Colorado, Kansas, Nebraska, New Mexico, Oklahoma, and Texas, under the recently completed federally funded High Plains-Ogallala Aquifer Regional Resources Study. The Missouri is now controlled by six main stem dams and reservoirs—Fort Peck, completed in 1935, and the other five authorized under the Pick-Sloan Plan by the Flood Control Act of 1944. By the authorizing legislation, these projects are committed to navigation, flood control, hydropower, and irrigation, municipal, and industrial uses in the
basin states. The Corps studies indicated that, under the present authorizations and commitments, little if any surplus water would be available for exportation without encroachment on navigation, hydropower generation, and future inbasin uses. However, more recent projections of in-basin uses and depletions are significantly lower, and questions have been raised as to the justification under present conditions for the present allocation of storage and water for the limited navigational use of the Missouri River to Sioux City. More water might be available for both in-basin use and exportation were the allocation and the operational criteria to be changed to accord with today's projected conditions and needs. Were the Federal Central Valley Project and the California State Water Project, both of which divert from the Sacramento River and tributaries and from the Sacramento-San Joaquin Delta, to be operated as an integrated system with proper regard for hydrologic diversity, there could be a potential increase in yield of 500,000 to 1,000,000 acre-feet per year. Hydroenergy production might also be increased. Conjunctive use with groundwater resources would provide additional benefits. Any proposal to improve the efficiency of operation of existing projects would require Congressional and state approval. No
― 122 ― doubt there would be strong opposition from some present project beneficiaries. The potential for increased water supply and other benefits seems to warrant the attempt.
Better Allocation of Resources The discussion above of improved management and operation of existing projects implies reallocations of current supplies and allocation of augmented supplies in accordance with today's needs and conditions. There are also situations where undeveloped resources could be allocated and developed to sustain current uses. Only one example will be discussed here, that of the undeveloped groundwater resources of the High Plains-Ogallala Aquifer region of Colorado, Kansas, Nebraska, New Mexico, Oklahoma, and Texas. In 1980, of the total of 140.8 million acres in the High Plains area, over 15 million acres were irrigated with groundwater extracted from the Ogallala and associated aquifers. It is projected that 5.4 million acres will revert to dryland farming or be abandoned by 2020 because of physical or economic exhaustion of the underlying groundwater resources if no new remedial
actions are taken. The rate of reversion will accelerate thereafter. Of the more than 125 million acres of nonirrigated land in the region, another 17 million acres were in dry cropland. Of the total area, almost 30 million acres are classified as marginal for irrigation, but are suitable for some types of dryland production such as grazing. These nonirrigated areas are underlain with groundwater resources in amounts that vary with location. It is suggested that the groundwater resources underlying the marginal lands, and some of the other lands not especially well suited for irrigation, might be developed and conveyed over time to the presently irrigated lands and the nonirrigated prime lands that may go under irrigation. Of course, it would be necessary to obtain, by direct purchase or by condemnation, the water rights or surface development rights of those lands and owners from which the underlying waters would be purchased. Some changes in state laws would be necessary. There would be some legal/institutional difficulties to be overcome. This concept would have several advantages: · The lands from which the water would be taken could remain in their present uses or other dryland uses.
― 123 ― · There would be a number of relatively small projects which could be implemented at the appropriate times with respect to the declining availability of underlying water for the recipient lands, as contrasted to one or two very large importation projects. Implementation could be accomplished in stages. · The investments required at any one time would be relatively small. · Implementation could be accomplished by local public agencies rather than the master regional agency required for a large importation project. · The elevation differences are relatively small and pumping costs would be much less than for importation. · Surface storage reservoirs would not be required, thus minimizing evaporation losses.
· Total costs should be significantly lower. · At least some of the owners no doubt would welcome the money derived from sale of their groundwater rights, which they might not ever exercise on their own behalf.
Groundwater Management/Recharge Artificial recharge is frequently touted as a principal technique to be applied for alleviation of the present water supply deficiencies in the West. Artificial recharge is already being widely applied throughout the West. However, application of this technique to new situations will depend on the availability of water for increased recharge that would otherwise be lost for beneficial use. There is now little surface water wasted in the West on a regional or river basin basis; most surface water is already being used for one or more beneficial purposes. The feasibility of artificial recharge also depends on the availability of sufficient usable underground storage and transmission
― 124 ― capacities. Effective artificial recharge requires land and physical facilities. The investment and operation and maintenance costs may be substantial. In some states, there are legal questions as to the ownership of and control over the recharged water, i.e., the right to recapture. There are opportunities for further augmentation of usable supplies in the West through artificial recharge, but they are not widespread. Artificial recharge will be particularly valuable for the underground storage of imported and reclaimed waters.
Other Possibilities and Research Needs One very new technology may have potential application in areas throughout the West that have already seriously depleted available groundwaters. Methods are undergoing testing in the south area of the Texas High Plains for the secondary recovery of additional groundwater supplies from the unsaturated zones of an aquifer. The concept is that in many aquifers, as much or more water remains in the formations after depletion by usual extraction methods, due to molecular or capillary attraction, as was removed by normal gravitational (pumping) forces. This could represent a very significant supplemental water supply if this ongoing research demonstrates both a technical and cost-effective capability. A variety of techniques for reducing nonproductive losses of water by
evaporation, transpiration, and/or by losses to runoff or deep percolation to nonrecoverable areas such as saline sinks or aquifers are being investigated. Methods to improve infiltration and deep percolation on-site, and to reduce losses to nonproductive deep rooted vegetation like phreatophytes and noxious brush species, hold out strong prospects for local water enhancement in the West, but more research is needed.
Conclusions Certainly there are no "quick fixes" for new water supplies for the semiarid West. Nor, to continue in the vernacular, are there any "free lunches". With complete rational planning and management, and no objections from the source areas, interbasin diversions of water could be achieved to the probable benefit of all concerned. The reality is that even on a small scale, the
― 125 ― probabilities are not great. Fear of exploitation on the part of export areas, and an appearance of greedy provincialism in some areas seeking imports, combine to create almost impenetrable barriers to the successful implementation of any diversion scheme. Lack of available funding now precludes large-scale structural solutions to problems of water supplies for irrigation. Other processes show promise, but the potential for a significant breakthrough in local water supply or large-scale water supply augmentation for the West in the foreseeable future is limited. A state-of-the-art evaluation of a large set of emerging technologies for enhancing local water supplies, while not consistently discouraging or pessimistic, nevertheless offers small relief for the major irrigated agricultural production areas of the West, which are presently dependent on seriously overdrafted groundwater sources or very limited surface water supplies. Significant projects are still underway for agricultural water supply enhancement. Examples are the extensive weather modification and precipitation management research programs; the adaptation and use of brackish and saline waters for certain crops; and the secondary recovery of additional waters from aquifers where gravitational waters have already been depleted due to overdraft. These and other methods may provide some temporary and partial water supply sources for western agriculture, but none provide long-term solutions to the water crisis. These are nonetheless the only solutions, limited as they are, that appear to be implementable for many years.
Discussion: Herman Bouwer New water supplies or water importation schemes usually mean transferring water from places where the supply exceeds the demand to places where the demand exceeds the supply, or from places where the economic returns from the water use are low to where they are high, all in accordance with the second fundamental law in hydraulics: water runs uphill—to money! This does not bode well for agriculture, which traditionally is accustomed to inexpensive water for irrigation. Rather than for irrigated agriculture to acquire additional water supplies, current trends seem to be more in the opposite direction, i.e., sales of irrigation water rights for municipal and industrial uses. The authors have done an excellent job in summarizing the various large water-transfer schemes that have been proposed over the years, and other possibilities for augmenting local water supplies. One source not mentioned is icebergs that would be towed from the Antarctic. Is this no longer a viable concept? Accurate cost figures for large water transfer schemes are difficult to obtain. Preliminary estimates all indicate, however, that costs are high: capital costs of several thousand dollars per acre-foot per year capacity, and total costs of several hundred dollars per acre-foot at the aqueduct or reservoir. To this must be added the cost of further distribution of the water to the points of use. For a simple project like the Central Arizona Project where water will be pumped from the Colorado River and transported a few hundred miles into south central Arizona, construction costs are already about 2.4 billion dollars for a capacity of 1.2 million acre-feet per year (or about $2,000 per acre-foot per year), and this does not include the cost of getting the water from the main aqueducts and reservoirs to the points of use. The cost of the water to consumers is projected at $52 per acre-foot for agricultural users and $82.50 for municipal and industrial users, again at the main aqueduct. These figures will soon be revised, probably upward. The cost of water in southern California from the California Aqueduct is about $100 per acre-foot. This figure could double in 1983, as new contracts for electric
― 127 ― power will be negotiated. New projects can be expected to be a lot more expensive. Man-made obstacles (legal, social, environmental, etc.) to large transfer projects seem more difficult to overcome than the technical problems, which can be solved by good engineering. It should be possible, however, to develop long-range projections of water needs for selected basins, to identify basins of water surplus and water deficit, to design water transfer projects, and, if economically and environmentally attractive, to build them. The
Sporhase decision (Sporhase v. Nebraska, U.S. Supreme Court, 2 July 1982), which declared groundwater an article of interstate commerce subject to congressional regulation, may help overcome political opposition from water surplus states against export of water to deficient areas. Long-term economic and social values for the life of the project should be considered rather than payout period economic aspects which, because of present cost levels for water, are almost always unfavorable. To translate from the Dutch, "A nation that lives builds for its future"! If we leave out the element of moving water over great distances, development of new water supplies simply means transferring water from a use with a low economic return to one with a higher economic return. This, of course, includes water conservation, where losses and wastes of water are reduced and put to more beneficial use. In view of the costs and the many difficulties of water transfer schemes, water conservation is increasingly considered as the best and most immediate solution to problems of water shortage. The authors allude to water conservation and increased irrigation efficiency, as do other chapters in this volume. However, further discussion of some opportunities for water conservation seems warranted. One such opportunity is to reduce water use by agriculturally nonbeneficial vegetation such as phreatophytes in floodplains. Phreatophytes have been estimated to cover about 15 million acres in the western states and to consume about 25 million acre-feet of water per year. This is the equivalent of 20 Central Arizona Projects! Complete eradication of the phreatophytes, as advocated a few decades ago, is not compatible with wildlife and scenic considerations. Thus, selective removal will be more acceptable. Proper control can be achieved by keeping the phreatophytes away from the water (by selective cutting and floodplain management), or by keeping the water away from the phreatophytes (by lowering groundwater levels or reducing seepage from stream channels). Care should be taken that
― 128 ― replacement vegetation does not use appreciable amounts of water. With the high cost of imported water, saving water by phreatophyte control may become attractive. Runoff farming offers great potential for the millions of acres of marginal lands with insufficient rainfall or irrigation water for normal crop production. Crops can then be grown in widely-spaced rows at the base of contour strips that have been treated chemically or mechanically to increase runoff from rainfall, thus concentrating the rain on the crops. The systems can be designed to yield more runoff than can be used by the crops for evapotranspiration, thus increasing deep percolation from the crop rows and producing more groundwater recharge. Runoff farming and replenishment irrigation have great potential for the management of abandoned irrigated
land, which otherwise could develop problems of dust and tumbleweeds. The crops should be deep-rooted or drought-tolerant to survive long periods of no rain. Supplemental irrigation may be desirable. Reuse of wastewater, particularly municipal wastewater, requires considerable advanced planning to ensure that the treatment plants and the irrigated fields are not too far apart, and that land treatment or groundwater recharge opportunities can be utilized. If partially treated wastewater can be put underground with infiltration basins and pumped from wells after it has moved through the vadose zone and aquifer to become "renovated water", the cost of treating the wastewater to meet the public health, agronomic, and aesthetic requirements for unrestricted irrigation can be greatly reduced. There are also increasing trends toward local or on-site reuse of municipal wastewater for landscape irrigation, golf courses, cemeteries, etc. Last but not least, there is irrigation efficiency, which often is the center of attention because irrigation uses so much water (almost 90 percent of all water in Arizona, 85 percent in California) and field irrigation efficiencies are low. Many people have the misconception that a field irrigation efficiency of 60 percent means that only 60 percent of the irrigation water is effectively used, and 40 percent is wasted. Of course this is not true. The forty percent of the water not used by the crop in this case is in the form of runoff at the lower end of the field and/or of deep percolation from the root zone. Both types of water can be recovered and reused again. For this reason, the irrigation efficiency of entire irrigation districts or irrigated valleys is much higher than the efficiencies of individual fields. As the saying goes, "the upper basin's inefficiency is the lower basin's water resource."
― 129 ― The real loss of water is the consumptive use or evapotranspiration, and that does not change much with irrigation efficiency. However, if the irrigation efficiency is increased, for example from 65 to 85 percent, less energy is needed for pumping, and higher yields are generally obtained, because of better water management and reduced leaching of fertilizer. This is really the main purpose of increasing irrigation efficiency: to increase crop yield per unit of water consumptively used. It is, of course, also possible to reduce evapotranspiration by not growing crops in the hottest part of the year (late season cotton, winter vegetables instead of summer crops, etc.) and increase water use efficiency that way. However, the main prospects for water saving in irrigation lie in increasing crop yields. Average crop yields typically are only about 20 percent of record values, so there is still room for improvement in crop management. Also, research should be greatly stepped up to create new, high-yielding varieties, using new developments in genetic engineering. New approaches such as the use of growth hormones and biostimulators should be investigated with
vigor. If we can double the yield per acre, the same crop can be produced with half the land, essentially half the water, and essentially half the salt load on the underlying groundwater due to deep percolation. Thus, growing the proverbial two blades of grass where only one would grow before is still the name of the game.
Discussion: Marion Marts The chapter by Banks, Williams, and Harris is a realistic and comprehensive assessment of the prospects for developing large-scale new agricultural water supplies in the semiarid West. The authors conclude that the prospects are poor in the foreseeable future. This discussant shares this conclusion, and indeed with respect to large-scale importation would argue that the prospects approach zero. Let me elaborate on this latter point a bit, and then proceed to speculation on some broader issues. Large interregional transfer of water is an idea that won't go away, but whose time refuses to come. As the authors point out, the inhibiting factors have always been strong; my thesis is that they are growing stronger over time, so that whatever prospects once existed are fading. The Columbia River illustrates the point nicely.
― 130 ― Then Assistant Secretary of the Interior William Warne's famous "climb the ladder of rivers to the north" speech stimulated the first major review of large-scale interstate water transfer: the Bureau of Reclamation's United Western Investigation, which in 1950 and 1951 reported on a reconnaissance of a variety of possibilities for transferring "surplus" Pacific Northwest water to the Southwest, but concluded that tapping anything north of the Klamath River was economically infeasible. It is interesting that even in that heyday of water project development, economic feasibility was a constraining criterion. Also interesting was the fact that certain northwest waters—the Rogue River and Flathead, Pend Oreille, and Coeur d'Alene Lakes—were declared sacred and off-limits. The investigation was quickly and quietly terminated when Northwest congressmen discovered what was going on. A blizzard of proposals followed the 1963 Arizona v. California decision. Anyone with a roadmap and pencil could play the game. By 1969, Bingham inventoried 14 interregional and 10 international proposals, and there were many variants of these. Banks and colleagues describe four of the major proposals as illustrations. Senator Jackson of Washington saw fit to take the Columbia out of the game by imposing a congressional moratorium, which effectively stopped federal agencies from planning to rearrange the
Columbia. While high cost can be cured by massive subsidy, and political clout can erode over time, a new and very fundamental element has been added. This element is, surprisingly, shortage. Competition within the Columbia River Basin for water for hydropower, for anadromous fish, and for additional irrigation has become fierce—reinforced by two drought years in the 1970s. The Northwest Regional Power Council, for example, has accepted a calculation that provision of adequate spring flows for the juvenile salmon migrating to sea will cost in the order of 500 to 550 megawatts of firm power. In the same vein, irrigation expansion will impose annual power costs on the region amounting to more than $100 per acre irrigated—in some cases more than $200—from a combination of lost generation and consumption of electricity for pumping. Hydropower operation is now a claimant for water that once was surplus during the high flow season (late spring and early summer) as a result of upstream storage, the ability to sell electricity to the Southwest via the Intertie, and the gradual transition to peaking mode for the hydropower plants. Indian claims to water and fish are far from quieted, and will complicate the planning picture for years.
― 131 ― All of these factors mean that there are substantial opportunity costs of diverting Columbia River water which must be included in any responsible benefit-cost analysis. The days when outflow to the seas could be considered surplus are gone. By extension, the principle of opportunity cost applies to all available rivers, although the details and values will vary. This is a powerful inhibition on any river pooling scheme. The authors illustrate this principle in the case of the Missouri River by pointing to the trade-off between navigation and out-of-basin diversion. Banks and his colleagues proceed from the impracticality of large water transfers to an excellent review of the possibilities of improving the efficiency with which available water supplies are used, and point out institutional factors—water laws, property rights, custom, etc.—which inhibit increased efficiency. I applaud this discussion and can only add, let's get on with it. But all of this suggests some interesting speculation. If my thesis that large water transfers have been priced out of the market is correct, does this mean that federal intervention and federal subsidy have lost their efficacy? What potential irrigation projects remain if we can't afford to augment? Does southern Idaho claim more Snake River water for irrigation regardless of the downstream costs in lost hydropower and fish? And into what maze does enhanced efficiency lead us? Will Wyoming surrender its rights to irrigate pastures in high mountain valleys to expand the intensive agriculture of the Imperial Valley? The social cost of interregional efficiency, like the cost of augmentation, may be excessive. The sobering fact is that state boundaries
and state water codes constrain both efficiency and interstate transfer. If big augmentation and big efficiency are beyond us, what then? Perhaps the time has come to accept the proposition that there is an inevitable equilibrium between availability and use of western water resources. There will no doubt be some modest additions here and there using locally available supplies, and some abandonment here and there as water tables drop or salinity rises, but these are just perturbations on the way to equilibrium. We may have seen the last of the large new irrigation projects in the West. The next ones may be in the Mississippi Valley, as we proceed to emulate the Italian experience in the Po river basin.
― 132 ― A final comment about long distance transfer. We are habituated to think of interstate and international water transfers only in terms of large scale, and chiefly for irrigation. This creates the twin problems of large cost and low repayment capacity, compounded by the perception of unfair interregional competition. If we have long distance transfers in the foreseeable future, they will more likely be of modest volumes for specific and high-value uses, such as coal gasification or transport, or municipal use, analogous to oil and gas pipelines and perhaps even sharing the latters' rights-of-way. Such systems would have much greater social and economic acceptability than would canals built to move the equivalent of the Colorado River, and might help retard the transfer of irrigation water to industrial and urban areas in water-short areas. Macro-think has brought no large interstate water transfers in the three decades since the United Western Investigation, and may actually have impeded the search for more efficient allocation and use of available water. It may be time to try micro-think.
― 133 ―
Chapter 5— Increasing Efficiency of Nonagricultural Water Use by J. Ernest Flack
Abstract Increased efficiency in use of nonagricultural water can have a small but significantly important impact on water availability for irrigated agriculture in the West. Water withdrawal to meet commercial, industrial, and residential water demands is less than 5 percent of the withdrawal for agriculture, but meeting these demands ties up some of the most valued storage sites and earliest priority water rights. Conservation programs, if carefully designed, properly implemented, and fostered over the long term, can alleviate some of the adverse consequences that growing municipal and industrial water demands have on irrigation. Compared with flat-rate, nonmetered water usage, savings of as much as one-third can be realized. Conservation can, however, have adverse effects on return flows to receiving streams and groundwater aquifers.
The arid and semiarid West is the scene of important economic growth and opportunity, much of which is dependent on water resources development. While there are some disadvantages associated with this land of sharp contrasts, its attributes are attracting people and industry at rates well above the nation as a whole. A number of trends seriously impact the water resources of the area and its irrigation-based agricultural economy. These include rapidly increasing population concentrated in urban centers, industrialization, heavy recreational use of the natural environment, and energy resource development. The role of water is pivotal because there is not much undeveloped, unappropriated water remaining. Although all the water allocated or available to the various states is not now being used, virtually all of it is "spoken for" through various reservations, by conditional water rights, or preliminary permits to acquire appropriations. The result is sharp competition for water, especially in places and times of scarcity.
― 134 ― Users can follow three possible strategies in meeting their projected demands for water withdrawals. These are to (a) develop new water supplies, (b) reduce the demand, and (c) transfer water from lower economic uses. In this paper, we focus on reducing the demand for water by
nonagricultural water users. Since the municipal-industrial sector has the highest value-in-use of water, conservation is important because it affects transfers from lower economic uses, particularly irrigated agriculture. Agriculture uses by far the largest percentage of western water—90 to 95 percent in terms of both withdrawal and consumptive use. It must be emphasized, however, that just because one economic sector has a higher value-in-use than another, it will not necessarily "buy out" the entire lower valued use. For example, assume water is being transferred from a lower to a higher value-in-use. As the demand is met in the higher valued use, the marginal value per unit of water will fall until the incremental value-in-use of the two uses are the same and transfers cease. In plain language this means that municipal and industrial water users can, generally, purchase sufficient water from agriculture to meet their demands, but still leave large quantities in agriculture. A related but crucial issue is that the water rights acquired from agriculture, in order to be most useful to municipal and industrial interests, are the most senior rights that exhibit the greatest hydrologic and legal certainty.
Changes in Urban Runoff The development and control of urban runoff can, to a degree, both reduce the demand for urban water and add to the supply. Stored runoff can be utilized to meet landscaping irrigation requirements of both public and private property. For instance, impervious areas such as tennis courts, streets, and parking lots can be constructed so that the runoff is stored for use in forming blueways and maintaining greenways. At the least, this source can be used to water public parks, commons, golf courses, planted medians, etc. Judicious use of stormwater could possibly supply one-fourth to one-half of the public water demands of a city in the West.
― 135 ―
Reuse of Municipal Wastewater Water utilities have always sought to alleviate supply problems by developing new sources. Traditionally, water has been supplied to municipal residents, used, treated, and then discharged as wastewater effluent. The reuse of wastewater can reduce the demand for new water supplies.
Recycling Recycling of water has been practiced since the beginnings of civilization. The unplanned successive use of the wastewater of one settlement by downstream communities has increased with rising populations. The U.S. Environmental Protection Agency has estimated that during low flow periods the proportion of wastewater in some surface water supplies may exceed eighteen percent, with an average of about three and one-half percent.[1] The planned reuse of water for some uses, generally nonpotable, has been recognized by many as a viable alternative to new water supplies.[2] The advantages are obvious: water withdrawals and wastewater discharge are reduced in magnitude. A new level of interest in water recycling has been generated as the result of research in advanced wastewater treatment. The costs of advanced treatment have been reduced and approach more closely the costs for raw water supply treatment.[3] Recycling systems can be divided into two general categories, indirect reuse and direct reuse. Indirect reuse involves the discharge of a wastewater into a surface or groundwater supply and then subsequent reuse of the water in a diluted form. Wastewater can be used directly in irrigation, by industry, and for some nonpotable residential applications. A 1975 survey indicated that 358 municipalities, located primarily in the Southwest, reuse wastewater for such purposes.[4] Groundwater recharge using sewage effluent is presently practiced in many locations in the United States. The primary reuse is for irrigation with a small percentage being allocated for recreation, fire protection, and other municipal purposes. Endorsement of wastewater reuse has not been universal. Some authorities view it as a major solution to water supply problems, while others have voiced considerable concern.[5] The American Water Works Association and the Water Pollution Control Federation have issued a joint resolution recognizing the potential of wastewater recycling, but cautioning that further research is needed on the possible health hazards involved. Surveys of health officials have expressed similar concerns. The possible long-term effects of ingestion of low levels of viruses,
― 136 ― organics and heavy metals that may be present in treated wastewater have not been determined. Questions relate to the frequency and the amount of recycled water ingested. Before recycled water can be used as a drinking water supply, most authorities agree that there is much more to be learned.[6]
The acceptance of recycled water is of considerable importance in planning for wastewater reuse. Pagorski found that 81 percent of a sample survey population were willing to use recycled water if it was guaranteed to be safe.[7] Bruvold and Ongerth found that the degree of acceptance decreases with higher body contact.[8] A survey in the Denver area showed that half the sample population would accept purified wastewater for drinking.[9] On the other hand, Gallup reported that 54 percent of those surveyed opposed drinking recycled sewage.[10] Studies by Sims and Baumann[11] and by Greenberg[12] correlated higher reuse acceptance with higher levels of education. It appears that public attitudes currently oppose using recycled water for drinking, cooking, bathing, laundry, and swimming, but do not oppose its use for waste disposal and irrigation purposes. Methods of direct recycling range from those instituted on an individual basis to system-wide operations. The most cost-effective means of recycling water is to reduce or minimize the treatment required. To better understand how recycling of water in the home can be accomplished and what type of treatment is needed, several authors have looked at the quality of each use effluent.[13], [14] A number of recommendations have resulted from these findings;[15] see Table 5.1.
Individual Home Recycling The waste stream from the various domestic water uses can be categorized as grey water or black water. Those flows containing high concentrations of organic matter are termed "black water", while flows polluted primarily with soap and detergent wastes are termed "grey water". Currently these two wastewaters are combined and discharged into the sewer system. McLaughlin found that a system separating the two wastewater streams and reusing the grey water for toilet flushing saved approximately 23 percent of normal water usage.[16] In 1969 Bailey and others made cost estimates on a number of types of individual home treatment systems for in-home water recycling.[17] Their general findings indicated that treatment costs were too high to make recycling cost-effective. A follow-up study by Cohen and Wallman indicated that average savings of between 23 and 26 percent of total water use could be obtained
― 137 ―
Table 5.1 Potential for Residential Water Reuse
― 138 ― by grey water recycling for toilet flushing.[18] Widespread reuse of black water flows within households is extremely unlikely because of possible health hazards, although closed systems for households have been developed.
System Recycling The literature contains much discussion on system-wide reuse possibilities. The classic case of direct reuse of wastewater took place in Chanute, Kansas, when a severe drought brought about a water shortage and the recycling of wastewater was necessary to supply the town's water needs.
Windhoek, Namibia, has recycled part of its total supply for domestic uses since 1968. The use of dual systems to recycle water has been examined by a number of authors. Haney and Hamann based their calculations for a dual system on a need of 40 gallons per capita per day (gpcd) of high quality water.[19] Potable water would be furnished for drinking, cooking, dishwashing, bathing, and cleaning purposes. Nonpotable water would be furnished via a recycling system for toilet flushing, lawn irrigation, evaporative cooling, and clothes washer uses. Deb and Ives estimated that 85 percent of the total supply could be provided by the nonpotable system.[20] DeLapp found that by using reclaimed water for lawn irrigation, toilet flushing, and fire protection, the quantity of potable water supplied could be decreased by 73 percent.[21] Dual systems in Coalinga, California, and Catalina Island, California, are two examples of operating recycling systems, but widespread use is considered unlikely at present costs and availability of raw water.
Reuse of Industrial Water Conservation by industry, even more than urban use, depends on cooperative efforts by the industry, because the cost of the water compared with other inputs in production is usually so low that economic incentives cannot be counted on to effect reductions in demand, although there now exist incentives to reduce waste treatment costs. Reflecting this same relationship is the small price elasticity for low water-using industries, estimated at 0.1 to 0.2, or a 10 to 20 percent reduction in demand for a doubling of price. Demand reduction by commercial users such as restaurants, stores, and offices, is also difficult to effect except through pricing and utility encouragement. While very few studies of commercial price elasticity have been published, it appears that it is in the neighborhood of 0.2.
― 139 ― Once an industry or commercial enterprise has decided to implement water conserving practices, the results can be quite remarkable. Water can be reused within the plant, recycled within various processes, or use can be reduced by changing the operation or process. Closed systems may eliminate any discharge whatsoever. It should be recognized that while many of these conservation techniques can be included in plant modernization or remodeling, they do cost money. For instance, water demand could be reduced from 5 bbl to 2 or 3 bbl of water for every barrel of oil produced from oil shale, but at not insignificant additional cost.
Reductions in withdrawals from surface or groundwater sources obviously leaves more of the resource for other users. Reuse of industrial water will often reduce the quantity of effluent discharge. As with municipal return flows, these may be a major source of supply for downstream appropriators. Thus, the effect of conservation in industrial water use on downstream water users can be substantial unless there is a parallel reduction in withdrawals from the same water source.
Use of Return Flows Return flows are important in supplying downstream appropriators. Returns, especially from imported or developed water, can be effective in reducing the need for development of new supply sources, because western water law usually allows the developer of new water or the importer to retain ownership of the water as long as it can be identified. This is not true of salvaged water, that is, water native to a watershed that has been saved by some conservation means. Here the increased supply is usually considered to be added to the regular water supply of the receiving stream or groundwater source. Thus, return flows can be an efficient source of water for greenbelts and other environmental or recreational uses when not a part of the regular supply. The effects of urban water conservation on downstream receiving streams can be significant during low-flow periods. The effects are of two kinds. One is the reduction in sewage effluent entering the receiving stream. In many locations downstream, direct flow and storage appropriations are dependent on effluent return flows, or a municipal utility may be counting on its effluent to meet the rights of senior downstream appropriators when the utility diverts water upstream under a junior appropriation. In either case, any reduction in the effluent discharge can
― 140 ― adversely affect the downstream water users—in the first case by reducing the amount available to downstream junior appropriators and, in the second case, by either requiring reduced diversions upstream by the utility or the release of storage water to meet senior rights. The second effect of an urban conservation program is the reduction in lawn watering. Since an effective conservation program can reduce watering to a level at or below the consumptive use requirement for a good lawn, the deep percolation and runoff components of applied water are virtually eliminated. These excess waters either recharge the groundwater or enter the storm sewers and other channels leading to a receiving stream. If the groundwater is hydraulically connected with the receiving stream, the effect on the stream is the same as that of a reduced discharge to the stream.
Modifying the Demand for Urban Water Urban water conservation received national recognition in the report of the National Water Commission.[22] The Commission recommended metering, changes in building and plumbing codes, reduced leakage, and pricing as alternatives to increasing supply. The Clean Water Act and similar water pollution legislation have encouraged conservation as a means of reducing sewage flows, thus making possible reduced wastewater conveyance and treatment costs. The Executive Branch has initiated a series of steps and programs aimed at fostering water conservation at federal installations and in federal projects. Methods and means of urban water conservation can be categorized as follows:[23] structural methods, operational methods, economic means, and socio-political procedures. These alternatives are, in turn, subject to acceptance and implementation by three groups: the water policy decision makers, the water utility managers, and the water customers.
Structural Methods Included in this category are water-saving plumbing devices and fixtures. These include low-water-using showerheads, clothes and dishwashers, toilets, faucets, and similar appliances and fixtures. Meters can also be included because of the psychological effect they have, apart from the effect of price. Structural methods include various kinds of dual systems ranging from
― 141 ― single installations that recycle grey water to communitywide systems for potable and nonpotable water. Flow reducers which directly limit the flow rate can be included.
Operational Methods This category includes such things as reducing system pressure in anticipation of peak demands so that delivery rates are reduced. Detection, location, and repair of leaks is an important operational procedure, as is full accounting and control of public uses. The possibility of restricting deliveries to certain classes of customers in times of peak demand can result in conservation. The system over-design of utility water lines to meet fire requirements may impact conservation practices because the over-capacity allows increased peak demands.
Economic Means Rate structures which approach marginal cost pricing have direct conservation implications. Seasonal, peak, or demand pricing, including time-of-day pricing, can be justified by the resulting lowered demand. Development charges, or tap fees, can effect water use through growth limitation and through smaller meter size installations which limit delivery rates. Pricing and incentives can be used to encourage installation of watersaving devices and adoption of other conservation practices.
Socio-Political Procedures Included are rationing and restrictions, limiting water usages to certain times and for certain uses, as well as zoning and building codes which require conservation practices such as installation of water-saving plumbing fixtures. Horticultural changes can have important effects on water use by reducing sprinkling requirements, especially in arid and semiarid regions. Public education to increase acceptability of urban water conservation is extremely effective if it can be done with specific goals in mind.
Feasibility The adoption of conservation alternatives must meet four tests of feasibility: · Engineering and technological feasibility is perhaps the simplest to determine. A feasibility study answers the question of whether the alternative is physically possible, e.g., is the device available? · The second test is economic and asks the question, do the benefits exceed the costs?
― 142 ― · The environmental test is more difficult since it requires an evaluation of the environmental consequences, both positive and negative, which may result from adopting a particular alternative. · The fourth test is the most subtle and deals with changes in lifestyle or social well-being which may result from implementation of various urban water conservation alternatives.
Water Conservation Programs Combinations of the various water conservation alternatives described above can be designed to fit specific situations. All of the previously discussed conservation methods affect one another, and are not strictly additive; therefore, absolute savings cannot be predicted by adding up the savings of the methods adopted, but judgment must be used to estimate the total effect of a combined program. This is illustrated below.
Baseline Conditions To evaluate a program of water conservation, a baseline must be established against which savings can be measured. For illustrative purposes, a typical but hypothetical household is assumed; see Table 5.2. The household has three members, two bathrooms, a dishwasher and a clothes washer, and the lawn size is assumed to be 6000 square feet. The home is not metered and the rate of sprinkling application is 34 inches of water per year, well above the irrigation requirement of 23 inches needed to meet the potential evapotranspiration less effective rainfall for a semiarid location. In-house uses for baseline conditions are assumed as 64 gallons per capita per day (gpcd). Average daily water use for the three-member household is 192 gallons per day per dwelling unit (gpd/du) domestic use plus 348 gpd/du sprinkling use, or a total of 540 gpd/du. The ratio of maximum day to average day during the peak summer lawn water period is 2.1, and the peak hour to average day ratio is 5.3. The maximum day demand is 1134 gpd/du, and peak hour use is 2864 gpd/du. Sanitary sewer flows are equal to the domestic usage of 192 gpd/du. Return flow from excess lawn irrigation would be 113 gpd/du, or 56 percent of demand.
― 143 ―
Table 5.2 Residential Water Demand Daily Demand or Flow
Sector
Unmetered
Metered
Per Capita (gallons)
Per Per Capita Household (gallons) (gallons)
Per Household (gallons)
Average annual In-house
64
192
64
192
Sprinkling
116
348
78
235
Total
180
540
142
427
Maximum day
378
1134
340
897
Maximum hour
955
2864
859
2263
Sanitary sewer
64
192
64
192
Irrigation
38
113
3
10
Total
102
305
67
202
Return flow
Metering Having established baseline conditions on a flat-rate basis, the effects of metering can now be enumerated. While it seems reasonable that metering would reduce domestic usage somewhat (especially in older residences) because of leakage repair and better maintenance of plumbing fixtures, the in-house usage values are relatively conservative and for this reason no reduction is assumed. Lawn sprinkling would, however, be affected and it is estimated that irrigation usage would drop to be just equal to the irrigation requirement of 23 inches per year. The consequence of this would be to reduce the return flow from lawn irrigation to zero if the water is entirely consumptively used. Total efficiency in lawn watering is not likely, however, and some return flow from wastage is assumed equivalent to 10 gpd/du, which is about 4 percent of the applied rate.
The results of metering are also shown in Table 5.2. Total demand is reduced by 21 percent, sprinkling by 32 percent and return flow by 34 percent. Metering has been shown to be cost-effective in terms of water saved if costs of installation are not high.
― 144 ―
Water-Saving Household Devices Water-saving household devices cover a wide range of plumbing fixtures and household appliances. For retrofitting, the following items are sufficiently cost-effective, easy to install and maintain, and not disruptive to existing water use habits: · plastic bottles or dams in the toilet water closet to reduce water usage per flush. · low-water-using shower heads. · faucet aerators. Plastic bottles or dams are estimated to save from 4,000 to 6,000 gallons per year per household; shower heads save about 12,000 gallons per year per household; and aerators save about 3,000 gallons. The total savings are estimated at 20,000 gallons per year per household. All of these devices are cost-effective even at very low water prices.[15] Similar savings would be realized in new construction by installation of low-water-using toilets, faucet aerators, and shower heads. To have an impact on demand, it is necessary that these devices be installed in a large percentage of households. This is not difficult to do in new housing, where plumbing and building codes can require the devices. For retrofitting, however, a concerned public education program and ready availability of the devices are necessary. Recent research has shown that about 50 percent of the households questioned indicated they would install water-saving devices if these were made available at little or no cost. If 50 percent of a 10,000-household community installed such devices, the savings could equal 100 million gallons per year, or about 9 gpcd. This would be enough water to serve about 600 new customers. Residential water demand for households with combined metered service and household devices is shown in Table 5.3. The combined result of metering and watersaving devices is to reduce total demand by 25 percent and return flow by 40 percent.
Pricing Pricing policies can help achieve water conservation. The economic incentive for using less water is dependent on consumer attitudes and needs, as reflected in the elasticity of demand. Price elasticity, expressed as (D Q/Q) / (D P/P), measures the change in demand that occurs for a change in price, given the price-
― 145 ―
Table 5.3 Residential Water Demand (Metered, with Devices) Daily Demand or Flow
Per Capita (gallons)
Per Household (gallons)
In-house
57
171
Sprinkling
78
235
Total
135
406
Maximum day
284
851
Sector Average annual
Maximum hour 716
2148
Return flow Sanitary sewer 57
171
Irrigation
3
10
Total
60
181
demand relationship. In terms of residential use, in-house demand is less price-elastic than lawn sprinkling, i.e., with a given price increase the relative change in household use will change (decrease) less than sprinkling usage. Table 5.4 gives some price elasticity values for various categories of demand. Pricing theory and response have been studied by many investigators. Pricing methods have been devised in an effort to reduce demand, but more typically they are used to proportion the costs among consumers.
Peak demand rates and increasing block rates are two pricing structures that can promote water conservation. One procedure is to charge an extra fee for water used above some base allotment. For instance, a residential user may be charged significantly more per unit of water demanded any time his monthly usage exceeds, say, 130 percent of his average winter monthly demand. Increasing block rates charge water users higher rates for additional units above some minimum in one or more steps. As an example of the water savings that can result from a price increase, assuming the elasticities of Table 5.4 are applicable, Table 5.5 shows the residential water demands for a totally
― 146 ―
Table 5.4 Price Elasticities Demand Sector
Elasticity
Source
Residential
–0.225
1
Domestic
–0.26
2
Sprinkling (West)
–0.703
1
Average day
–0.3953
2
0.388
1
Maximum day
Sources: 1. Howe and Linaweaver, reference [24] . 2. Burns et al., reference [25] .
Table 5.5 Change in Daily Residential Water Demand with Price (30,000 population, 10,000 households) Demand Sector
Demand at $0.43
Assumed
Demand at $0.86
Difference (million
per 1,000 gal (million gal) Elasticity
per 1,000 gal (million gal) gal)
Household
1.92
–0.225
1.49
.43
Sprinkling
2.35
–0.395
1.42
.93
Total
4.27
2.91
1.36
Residential
― 147 ― metered community, whose household demand is given in Table 5.3, at water prices of $0.43 per 1,000 gallons and at $0.86 per 1,000 gallons. The net result of the doubling of water prices is a 32 percent reduction in total residential demand.
Revenue After conservation, the utility's demand of 2,910 million gallons (from Table 5.5, at $0.86 per 1000 gallons) would equal $2,502,600, an increase of $666,500, or 36 percent, in revenue. Savings from installation of watersaving devices only, however, with the original price left intact, would result in a $86,000 per year loss in revenue.
Water User Restrictions The imposition of water use restrictions is essentially a short-term method of conserving water. When water supplies reach a level at which officials project that there may not be enough water to meet near-future demand, voluntary restrictions are usually instituted. These may later be made mandatory. The primary difference between this method and the others is that restrictions inconvenience the water consumer, whereas most other methods are designed to inconvenience the customer as little as possible. Although some reduction in demand from restrictions has been reported,[26] the primary effect seems to be a reduction in peak demands.
Implementation The effect of the water conservation programs illustrated in the hypothetical case here, i.e., metering plus devices or doubling the price, is to reduce domestic in-house use from 64 gpcd to 57 gpcd by the use of meters and water-saving devices (if the latter are installed in 50 percent of all residences), and to reduce domestic use to 45 gpcd by doubling the price of water from $0.43 to $0.86/1000 gallons. Lawn sprinkling would be reduced from 78 gpcd to 47 gpcd by the price increase, and overall usage would drop from 142 gpcd to 97 gpcd, a 32 percent decrease. Three cautions to accepting these values need emphasis. These are the assumptions that (1) the elasticities of demand are correct, (2) the demands for in-house and sprinkling use are reasonable, and (3) 50 percent of all households would install and keep in good repair the water-saving devices.
― 148 ― Peak day to average day ratios would probably stay about the same under the conservation programs, with the peak day demand decreasing proportionately with the reduction in average day demand. A loss of revenue would result from installing water-saving devices, but revenue would increase markedly if the price of water was doubled. The combination of both practices would still result in a sizable increase in revenue. Reductions in return flow because of implementation of water conservation practices could have important implications to downstream water users, especially in water-scarce areas of the western United States. One of the more commonly overlooked recommendations in implementing water conservation programs is to use survey research to determine the attitudes and perceptions of the utility's customers toward water conservation, and to attempt to explore possible roles that influentials in the community can play in promoting conservation. In addition to garnering public support, it is necessary for the utility to measure the effectiveness of various conservation programs. Such a procedure compares the expenditures, perhaps on a per capita basis, with the benefits of the program as measured by reduced demand, delays in system expansion, and decreased risks of shortages.
Nonagricultural Conservation as Related to Agriculture From the foregoing discussion it is apparent that urban water conservation by residential, commercial, and industrial users can result in significant reductions in water demand withdrawals. The question now is, what effect can this have on water availability for agriculture? First, it must be admitted that on the broad scale the effect is not large. This is because irrigated agriculture diverts and consumptively uses such a preponderance of the water in the West. Any reductions in the demand for water by municipal or industrial uses would have a relatively slight effect on the overall water availability, even recognizing that cities and industries usually exercise senior appropriation rights. Second, in the growth of municipalities the conversion of irrigated land to urbanized communities can result in less water
― 149 ― being used on an area basis. In addition, the return flows for an equal area of urbanized development will exceed, on a percentage basis, the typical return flow from irrigated agriculture. This indicates that in terms of total water availability, more water is available downstream for irrigators after an upstream irrigated area has been converted to urban development. If conservation is practiced in the urbanized area, this effect will be enhanced. When nonirrigated areas are urbanized, of course, there is no such enhancement, but the depletion effects of urbanization can be decreased through conservation. Lastly, it can be argued that increasing the efficiency-of-use of the nonagricultural sector's water demand can result in benefits to irrigated agriculture, because less water is "tied up" by the municipal utility in storage and reserves, less is actually consumed within the community if on-site control of natural runoff is used to serve public needs, and less water is withdrawn by urban users when an effective conservation program is in operation.
Discussion: Richard C. Tucker It is possible to increase the efficiency of nonagricultural water use and, in the process, produce varying impacts on both water consumption and water withdrawals. J.E. Flack's paper does an excellent job of supporting this proposition and of presenting the various factors involved in pursuing the objective of more efficient water use. The paper presents a very good
categorization of the various kinds of efficiency increases, along with some interesting figures on the net effect of implementing a range of specific measures. Flack's work, along with the excellent references identified, represents a solid contribution to the literature on this subject. The following comments emphasize several of the paper's key points and suggest several areas which need more attention and evaluation. The U.S. Water Resources Council's Second National Water Assessment (1978) presented figures and assumptions about future U.S. water use. The Council estimated that total freshwater withdrawals for all off-stream uses (i.e., irrigation, domestic, manufacturing, mining, and steam electric power generation) in 1975 were 338.5 billion gallons per day (bgd); it projected that withdrawals will decrease to about 307 bgd by the year 2000. This projected decrease is based on assumptions about the implementation of water use efficiencies and recycling from available technology and conservation efforts. The most significant contribution to a reduction in offstream uses was assumed to be in manufacturing; total withdrawals in agriculture and steam electric generation were projected to remain about the same. The Council projected further that consumptive uses averaged 106.6 bgd in 1975 and will increase to 135 bgd by the year 2000. While both the withdrawal and consumptive use figures were aggregations for the entire United States, the figures and their changes from 1975 to 2000 are quite variable from region to region and by type of use. Both water withdrawals and consumption from domestic and commercial uses are predicted to increase considerably, while manufacturing withdrawals are predicted to drop by 60 percent, with consumptive use increasing by about 140 percent. The projections suggest little impact from conservation on domestic use but considerable impact on manufacturing use. Furthermore, manufacturing and mining withdrawals are nearly twice those of the domestic and commercial sectors, and manufacturing and mining consumptive use is expected to grow from equal to double that of domestic and commercial.
― 152 ― Flack's paper presents an excellent overview of the various factors pertaining to water use, but tends to concentrate on the domestic side. While there are potentially worthwhile reductions in all areas, it appears that the greatest opportunity for reductions is in the manufacturing and mining sectors. These areas should be addressed more fully. Certainly another area of great importance to the arid West is water use in the energy sector. In the last several years, many studies have focused on energy development and water supply in the western United States, largely because of the potential development of a major synthetic fuels industry. While most of the studies have concluded that sufficient water is available for a large western U.S. synfuels industry, the water is assumed to be available from irrigated agriculture. Of all possible nonagricultural water uses, water efficiencies in synfuels development and in basic steam electric
power generation may provide the greatest opportunity for total water savings. We have barely scratched the surface of this subject. I am confident that Flack's able research has uncovered the most timely research results available; nevertheless, with few exceptions, his cited references are to research done 8 to 10 years ago—a period when there was minimal effort to study water conservation measures on a national basis, much less implement them. In fact, this recognition led the U.S. General Accounting Office, in its 1979 report Water Resources and the Nation's Water Supply: Issues and Concerns, to state: Although these techniques generally are believed to save water, many have either not been thoroughly studied or had their cost effectiveness evaluated. No centralized data bank or clearinghouse on water conservation measures and techniques exists. Most, if not all, of the efficiency and conservation measures identified in Flack's paper require no significant lifestyle changes or alterations in basic industrial business practices. What could be achieved with a more concerted attack on water use inefficiencies? I believe that a continuing consciousness about water use—in combination with pricing—is necessary to have any dramatic effects. Flack presents an especially good discussion of the whole area of reuse and return flows. It reminded me of an incident that occurred some years ago while I was attending an ASCE meeting in Memphis. I was sitting in my hotel lobby, and an elderly gentleman sitting next to me suddenly said, "Young man, I
― 153 ― understand this is a conference on water, and I just heard that the people here take their drinking water from the Mississippi River. But did you know that St. Louis, which is upstream, dumps its sewage into the Mississippi River! This is just dreadful!" I really spoiled his day when I told him the people of Memphis got the same "present" from Pittsburgh, Cincinnati, Omaha, and a number of other cities to the north. Our national awareness of pollution control has changed considerably over the last several years, and few people would be surprised at such a statement today. But we still haven't gone far enough in alerting people to the need to conserve water, possibly because the national emphasis on energy conservation has diverted attention from the issues of water use. I am confident we will achieve the necessary water use savings to ensure a safe and adequate water supply for the future. We will undoubtedly, however, have to modify our perceptions of "need," heighten our national
consciousness about water use, and be prepared to modify our lifestyles and institutions to be more compatible with the realities of a finite resource. We need to heed the results of our own studies and develop a more detailed assessment of the impacts and cost effectiveness of implementing a multifaceted water conservation program on a regional and subregional basis. Increasing the efficiency of nonagricultural water use represents one means to free water for other uses, and savings on the order of 20 to 40 percent seem realistic. Will this have any significant impact on increasing water availability for irrigated agriculture? Compared to the water savings which can be achieved in irrigated agriculture itself, probably not.
Discussion: Dennis C. Williams The paper by J.E. Flack discusses the potential of water reclamation to augment existing water supplies and describes a wide range of water conservation measures which can reduce water demand in the urban sector. The following comments focus on the feasibility and effectiveness of some of the measures suggested by Flack from the perspective of a municipal utility that has been actively involved in promoting and implementing water conservation for a number of years.
― 154 ―
Wastewater Reclamation Wastewater Reuse Wastewater reclamation and reuse represents a potentially important supplemental source of water for urban areas. Nearterm uses for reclaimed water include landscape irrigation and industrial process water. Groundwater recharge using reclaimed water to replenish groundwater supplies is a potential use which is currently restricted in California due to health-related concerns. Studies presently underway are expected to lead to appropriate health standards for groundwater recharge. An important factor affecting feasibility is the cost of distribution facilities (storage, pumps, and pipelines) needed to supply reclaimed water from the treatment plant to the place of use. The Orange and Los Angeles Counties Water Reuse Study is a three-year, $4 million study nearing completion which has identified more than 30 potential projects in the study area with a total yield of more than 200,000 acre-feet.
The unit cost for water developed from these projects varies from $40 per acre-foot to more than $900 per acre-foot (1980 dollars). For purposes of cost comparison, Los Angeles currently purchases supplemental water from the Metropolitan Water District of Southern California at a cost of $140 per acre-foot.
Dual Systems A few areas have successfully installed dual pipeline systems to deliver potable water to homeowners and to deliver reclaimed water for irrigation purposes. This approach may be feasible in a carefully planned developing area where new streets and residences are being constructed, wastewater treatment facilities are nearby, and there are substantial greenbelt and commonly irrigated landscaped areas such as condominium and townhome developments. One example of a successful project is operated by the Irvine Ranch County Water District in Irvine, California. However, dual systems are generally not practical in established areas with typical single-family residences and an existing potable water distribution system. The cost of installing and maintaining a separate distribution system for reclaimed water would be excessive.
― 155 ―
Water Conservation Measures Water-Saving Household Devices Water meters, low-flow showerheads, low-flush toilets, and other structural methods can be very effective in reducing water use without inconvenience on the part of the customer. For example, a low-flow toilet uses about onethird less water than a standard toilet (5.5 vs. 3.5 gallons per flush). Most water utilities in California are fully metered, and homes built since 1978 are required to be equipped with low-flush toilets. In addition, all showerheads sold in the state since 1979 are required to be low-flow. Los Angeles and many other communities have provided free water conservation retrofit kits to residential customers. These kits typically include a plastic bag water displacement device for toilets, flow-reducing washers for showerheads, dye tablets to detect toilet leaks, installation instructions, and other water conservation tips. When mailed to the household, the installation rates range from 25 percent to 35 percent for the toilet devices, and 10 percent to 18 percent for the shower devices.
Water Pricing While it is generally recognized that increasing the price of water will tend to decrease its use, water pricing as a conservation tool poses a number of problems that must be considered by the utility. First, it is very difficult to estimate the impact that higher prices will have on water use and revenue to the utility. There have been many studies on the elasticity of water with the results varying significantly. Second, the determination of water rates must consider many factors, including revenue requirements, conservation, and the allocation of costs equitably among various customer classes. The rate structure of a municipal utility is generally subject to approval by a city council or other authority elected by the public. Local residents and businesses can be expected to oppose rate proposals that result in significantly increased costs to one customer class or group.
Industrial Conservation There appears to be significant potential for conserving water in the industrial sector through recycling and process changes. The City of Los Angeles has implemented a water conservation awards program to recognize commercial and industrial
― 156 ― customers who have shown outstanding conservation achievements. A variety of conservation measures ranging from innovating water recycling techniques to simple common sense approaches have led to water use reductions exceeding 50 percent for a number of businesses.
Leak Detection A number of utilities in California conduct leak detection programs as part of their water conservation effort. These programs typically use specialized monitoring equipment to "listen" for leaks in the distribution system. An effective leak detection and repair program can result in a variety of benefits including water savings, increased public awareness of the need to conserve, and customer goodwill when leaks found on private property are brought to the customers' attention.
Estimates of Conservation Savings Flack discusses in some detail an approach for estimating savings associated with implementing conservation measures. While an estimate of savings may be useful, it is important to recognize that estimates can vary substantially
depending on the assumptions made. For example, savings associated with the installation of low-flow showerheads have been estimated to be as much as 12 gallons per person per day and as little as 3 gallons per person per day, or a range of 300 percent. Brown and Caldwell, Consulting Engineers, are currently conducting a number of water conservation demonstration projects designed to document water savings associated with various conservation measures. The results should help improve the reliability of savings estimates.
― 157 ―
Chapter 6— Coping with Salinity by Jan van Schilfgaarde and J.D. Rhoades
Abstract Four independent management strategies are identified to cope with increasing levels of salinity. First, saline springs or other point sources of saline water can be intercepted; the water then can be evaporated, desalted, and reused, or diverted for use in industrial applications. Second, the amount of water applied for irrigation can be reduced, thus lessening the amount that seeps through the soil and reducing the salt load in return flows. Third, somewhat saline water can be used as a source of irrigation water for salt-tolerant crops. Such use reduces the amount of brackish water needing disposal and provides a substitute water supply. Fourth, the cropping pattern can be changed by choosing tolerant rather than sensitive crops. Through plant breeding more tolerant varieties of common species may become available. None of these options is without cost, and all have socioeconomic as well as technical aspects.
The primary theme of this volume is how to deal with water shortages. Water supplies, however, cannot be viewed solely in terms of quantity; clearly, the quality of the water must be considered as well. Water quality is nevertheless such a broad subject, that a restricted definition must be chosen for this discussion. The leading water quality parameter that affects irrigation agriculture no doubt is salinity; we will therefore focus our analysis on salinity-irrigation interactions and associated water management options.
Clearly agriculture is affected by, and affects, water quality in terms of pesticides, of nitrates and phosphorus, of heavy metals, and/or of sediment. The list could be extended, but none of these is uniquely tied to irrigation in the semiarid West, or is directly affected by diminishing water supplies. Salinity, however, is. As water supplies become more limiting, the use of sewage water for irrigation becomes a more important option; in fact 25 percent
― 158 ― (109 m3 /yr) is reused in California already.[1] Therefore, we treat this subject briefly in the context of alternate water supplies. Industrial development, such as the extraction of oil from shale, not only would compete with agriculture for water supplies, but also could well result in quality degradation of remaining waters; such degradation, however, would be dominated by an increase in salinity. Although salinity problems are indeed aggravated directly as irrigation water supplies are diminished, salinity per se is not restricted to irrigated lands. Salinity problems are widespread across the world. Although the literature is extensive, good statistics on the extent are hard to find. Szabolcs,[2] for example, implied that there are some 30 million hectares of salt-affected soils in Europe; and Shalhevet and Kamburov[3] estimated, from a mail survey, that worldwide 50 million hectares of cultivated land are salt affected, exclusive of the USSR. For the U.S., a recurring estimate is that up to one third of irrigated land is salt-affected, but reliable data are lacking.[4] Severe salinity problems are encountered along the Pecos River and the Rio Grande; it has been estimated that over one-third of the salt load of the Colorado River can be attributed to irrigation; and in California, salinity is a fact of life in the Imperial Valley, the lower San Joaquin, and elsewhere. Thus salinity problems are widespread, even if exact statistics are not available. The thesis of this discussion is that salinity is closely tied to water conservation measures. Before delving into options for coping with decreasing quantities of increasingly saline irrigation water, it seems appropriate to define some terms and to orient readers who may be less than fully conversant with salinity issues. The term "salinity", when applied to water, refers to inorganic ions (or compounds) in solution. Though an appropriate method for expressing salinity is to list the concentrations of the primary cations and anions in, say, mol L–1 , a common shorthand is to use concentration of total dissolved solids on a mass basis, in mg L–1 . With all its obvious shortcomings, this custom emphasizes the view that, as a first approximation, plants (but not soils) respond to total salt concentration, more than to its specific constituents. For reasons of analytical convenience, an equally common unit
is electrical conductivity, in terms of S m–1 . A rough conversion (rough because it depends on ionic composition and concentration) is 1 dS m–1 = 650 mg L–1 .
― 159 ― A similar usage has developed for soils, where the variable of interest is the salt concentration of the soil solution. Unfortunately, the soil water content changes all the time and so does the soil solution composition. In an attempt to standardize "soil salinity", there was introduced the electrical conductivity of an extract of a saturated paste made from a soil sample. The primary point here is that soil salinity is not an easily defined, single-valued parameter. Furthermore, soil properties are affected by the composition of the soil solution and thus, in turn, of the irrigation water. Though the interactions among soil properties and the salts in solution are numerous—and dependent on mineralogy—it is sufficient here to stress the adverse effects of sodium. At high levels of sodium relative to divalent cations in the soil solution and thus, at equilibrium, on the exchange complex, clay minerals in soils tend to swell, and aggregates tend to disperse under conditions of low total salt concentration. Whether from swelling or from dispersion, the soil hydraulic conductivity is reduced, and the surface tends to crust. Thus the ability of the soil to infiltrate and transmit water can be severely reduced. It is the relative amount of sodium on the soil and the total amount of salt in the water that are important. High total electrolyte concentrations tend to increase a soil's stability; thus we distinguish between saline soils and sodic soils, saline waters and sodic waters. Salinity is an inescapable concomitant of irrigation in arid areas. The water in pure mountain streams picks up salts as it moves over and through rocks. Part of the water diverted for irrigation evaporates, leaving the salts in a smaller volume of drainage water. This drainage water, in turn, may dissolve or displace salts of geologic origin. Evaporation also takes place from open water surfaces, such as lakes and storage reservoirs. In all, natural processes are accelerated by man's impact, and water generally becomes more and more saline as one moves downstream in the hydrologic system. To avoid a continuing increase in salinity in the soil water, there must be adequate soil drainage to remove the excess salts accumulating from irrigation. Drainage is also required to avoid water logging, or a high water table, which in turn increases the salinity problem. Hence the concept of salt balance: the amount of dissolved salt brought into an area in irrigation water must be matched by that removed by the drainage system, if salination is to be avoided. The salt balance concept is often misused and
― 160 ― misinterpreted.[5] Qualitatively, however, it is sound—and helpful in visualizing the situation. The reason we irrigate is to increase the production of agricultural crops, but salinity tends to decrease crop yield. A definitive description of what is meant by tolerance of plants to salinity is difficult to construct. Nonetheless, some crop plants are more tolerant to salt-induced stress than others. As with other stresses, plants expend energy to overcome the stumbling blocks they encounter. For example, it requires more energy to extract water out of a concentrated soil solution than out of a dilute solution, and for the plant cell there is a cost associated with manufacturing (or secreting) the compounds needed for osmoregulation. Though the details are complicated— if understood at all—a helpful working hypothesis for operational purposes is that plants respond to the total potential of the water in the rootzone, i.e., the sum of the osmotic potential (salt stress) and the matric potential (soil water deficit). The tolerance of crops to salinity is most readily expressed in terms of a threshold salinity (preferably in the soil solution) below which no adverse effect on yield is noted, and a rate of decrease in yield with increasing salinity beyond the threshold.[6] Though these indices imply an absolute tolerance, we prefer to think of them as relative values useful in ranking the tolerance of various crops. The values obtained depend on the management practices used and the environment in which the crops are grown; they do not take account of differences in sensitivity at various growth stages, such as germination versus grain filling. Aside from tolerance to unspecified (and presumed mixed) salts, we must sometimes be concerned with toxicity of specific ions. Some reports of Na toxicity may well have been misinterpretations of Ca deficiencies or salinity excesses. However, sensitivities of woody plants to chlorides and of almost all plants to boron are factors of concern. Returning to our main theme, we recognize that increased demands on a limited water supply tend to increase the salinity in the system. Because of increased use of water out of the Colorado, contribution from saline springs is a larger percentage of the remaining flow; recycling groundwater in a closed basin increases salinity; expanded irrigation in the Central Valley of California increases the need for disposal of saline drainage water. Many different situations are encountered, yet the end result is generally the same: water development in arid regions leads to increasing salinity problems. The question is, what
― 161 ― options exist for reducing the threat of salination? We shall consider several types of situations and attempt to illustrate them with some examples.
Management Options A number of options are open to us to minimize the adverse effects of salinity in irrigation in particular, and in water resource use more generally. For purposes of discussion, we here group these options into four classes, recognizing that they are not fully independent or, for that matter, truly parallel.
Diversion or Desalting First, we consider intercepting brackish water and diverting it out of the system, or desalting it for reuse. The latter part of this option, desalting, is one we can dispose of briefly. Though technically clearly feasible, and no doubt appropriate under special circumstances, we do not see desalting, now or in the foreseeable future, as a viable option for obtaining water for irrigation. Desalting is planned for the drainage water from the WelltonMohawk Irrigation District in Arizona, but the decision in that case was not based on best resource use or on economics.[7] The Department of Interior also has plans for desalting brackish water at LaVerkin Springs in Utah and Glenwood-Dotsero Springs in Colorado at costs estimated to be three times the benefits.[8] In California, there is continued interest in use of desalting technology in the Central Valley. Although we are not adequately informed to assess the progress, it is doubtful that the economics would come out very differently from those experienced by the U.S. Bureau of Reclamation. The other half of this option, diverting brackish water out of the system, offers some interesting possibilities. Several years ago, the Kern County Water Agency considered the use of brackish drainage water (around 6,000 mg L–1 ) for use as cooling water in a power plant. This option evaporated when, for other reasons, plans for the power plant were dropped. More recently, in the special report just cited, USBR engineers concluded that use of brackish water for power plant cooling offered substantial opportunities for reducing salinity in the Colorado River. Another interesting option that emerged was transport of coal in a slurry or—an intriguing concept— hydraulic transport of bagged coal through a pipeline. California hardly has the option to transport
― 162 ― coal to its shores, but Colorado well may be able to use some of its brackish
water in this manner. None of these uses deals directly with agriculture. Their implementation would affect agriculture by reducing the salinity of the water remaining, or by reducing the volume of drainage water needing disposal. Still, they are not central to the consideration of agricultural water quality. Thus we will not elaborate on them any further.
Decreasing Irrigation Water Use Claims are often made that irrigation water is used wastefully and that irrigation efficiencies can be increased substantially. Such claims must be put in proper perspective. Since on-farm water conservation is the topic of the next several chapters, we consider here only those aspects that deal specifically with water quality. Often the inefficiency that is observed is excessive tailwater. Though tailwater may well have other negative impacts, it is not likely to affect significantly the salinity of the receiving waters. On the other hand, excessive seepage (in-field deep percolation or seepage from ditches and laterals), while less obvious, can and often does affect downstream water quality in one of several ways. It may displace saline groundwater that has accumulated over time. Probably this is the case in the southwestern part of the Palo Verde Irrigation District, called the Palo Verde Subarea. It has been estimated that an increase in on-farm irrigation efficiency to 60 percent initially would reduce the salt discharge from the 4,000 hectares in this area by about 60,000 tonnes annually, or the salinity at Imperial Dam by about 8 mg L–1 .[9] In other cases reducing deep seepage may reduce the dissolution of salts from underlying formations. In the Grand Valley of Colorado, studies indicate that the salt loading of the Colorado River can be reduced by about 400,000 tonnes annually by decreasing the amount of irrigation return flow and conveyance system seepage moving through underlying saline substrata. Such a reduction would result in a decrease of the salinity of the river at Imperial Dam of approximately 43 mg L–1 .[10] Since current estimates, based on detailed economic studies, give the impact of a change of 1 mg L–1 at Imperial Dam as approximately $500,000 per year,[11] the economic impact of the Grand Valley project is indeed substantial. Changes in leaching fraction—i.e., the fraction of the irrigation water infiltrated that becomes deep seepage—can affect the
― 163 ―
salt regime in another fashion. As the electrolyte concentration of soil water is increased by evapotranspiration, the tendency of water to dissolve salts shifts towards a tendency to precipitate salts. Thus a reduction in leaching fraction—which leads to increased salinity of the drainage fraction—tends to reduce the total salt load in the drainage water. This principle, illustrated in earlier papers,[12] was applied to a set of hypothetical river and groundwater basins by Rhoades and Suarez[13] and by Suarez and van Genuchten.[14] They demonstrated that the effect of reduced leaching on the salt regime depends greatly on the nature of the irrigation water, on whether the receiving water is a groundwater or surface water and on certain hydrogeologic conditions. Reduced leaching is no panacea, but in the proper circumstances, it can have significant impact on the quality of the receiving waters; it always reduces the salt load of the drainage water that percolates below the rootzone. In the short run, before equilibrium conditions are obtained, the effects of salt precipitation can be far greater than predicted in the above studies.[15] Attempts have been made to extend the modeling of these systems to take into account irrigation scheduling and crop response. An example is the work of Yaron et al.[16] Unfortunately, the data base available is not yet sufficient to make such models very useful. The concept of increasing irrigation efficiency by reduced leaching is being applied effectively in various areas. Examples are the Wellton-Mohawk area of Arizona and the Grand Valley of Colorado cited above. To put the matter in perspective, however, a number of reservations must be addressed. For example, though it is expected that reducing the water applied in the 4,000hectare Palo Verde Subarea (cited above) would reduce the salinity at Imperial Dam, "improving" the currently very low water application efficiency in the remainder of the 36,000-hectare District is not expected to affect downstream water quality because there is no evidence of salt stored underground in that area and salt should not precipitate from the applied water in this case.[17] Presumably, the economic efficiency of water management at present is quite high there. Reduced leaching implies a lower margin for error in providing adequate salinity control. Thus it calls for a more uniform, better managed system of irrigation and, especially when pushed to the limit, requires some system of monitoring to avoid crop yield reductions or adverse salt buildup in the soil. Precise and innovative irrigation management is aided by recent developments in
― 164 ― irrigation technology, such as linear-move sprinklers, more reliable trickle systems, and laser-graded level border systems. Regular monitoring of salinity status is made feasible by developments in instrumentation and
techniques originating at the U.S. Salinity Laboratory in Riverside.[18] Reduced leaching and controlled seepage will reduce the drainage requirement and, in the absence of adequate drainage, postpone the day of reckoning. As an example of the first situation, it is likely that the alleged need for increased drainage intensity in Imperial Valley now compared to 20 years ago is due to excess canal seepage; the second is illustrated by the concerns in Fresno and Kern counties, California, with rising water tables.[19]
Use or Reuse of Salty Water In the western U.S., water supplies have been relatively plentiful and generally of excellent quality. As the pressure on water resources increases, there is increasing reason to consider use of more saline water in agriculture. Rhoades[20] pointed out that most of the typical drainage waters in the U.S. have potential value for irrigation, and presented results of detailed calculations to illustrate this observation. Our interest, however, is not so much in drainage waters per se, but in water with increasing levels of salinity. The number of documented reports on the successful use of brackish water for irrigation is relatively limited. Claims that seawater can be used for crop production[21] are far from convincing. Some other claims, such as 10 tons per hectare–1 yield of alfalfa with 12,500 mg L–1 water in the USSR[22] may well be tainted by poor translation or misunderstanding. Data on cotton irrigation (p. 166) are more consistent with U.S. experience; comparing long-term irrigation in Uzbekistan with drainage water (5-6,000 mg L–1 TDS), mixed water (2-3,000 mg L–1 ) and canal water (<1,000 mg L–1 ), yields were as shown in Table 6.1. Paliwal[23] gives a number of examples of irrigation in India with waters of relatively high salinity. Shalhevet and Kamburov[24] in their worldwide survey of irrigation and salinity cited earlier, suggested that waters up to 6,000 mg L–1 were often classed as acceptable and indeed used. Dhir[25] reported the use of water ranging from 5 to 15 dS m–1 for wheat production in India, but these areas receive annual monsoons. Hardan[26] irrigated pear trees with water ranging up to 4,000 mg L–1 without yield reduction. Frenkel and Shainberg[27] and Keren and Shainberg[28]
― 165 ―
Table 6.1
Yield of Cotton under Irrigation in Uzbekistan, 1957-68 (100 kg ha-1 ) Source of Year Irrigation Water 1957 1958 1959 1960 1961 1962 1963 1964 1965 1966 1967 1968 Canal
20.5 26.9 36.9 29.4 30.6 31.8 36.2 29.3 46.1 47.8 41.8 37.9
Drainage 20.6 24.9 38.3 30.4 28.8 28.0 26.6 31.4 40.6 42.9 34.0 33.5 Mixed
19.5 28.6 35.6 31.5 29.1 28.7 31.6 28.0 41.9 46.1 36.3 33.2
― 166 ― reported that cotton is grown commercially in Israel with water having an electrical conductivity of 4.6 dS m–1 . In the U.S., extensive areas are irrigated in the Arkansas Valley of Colorado with water containing more than 1,500 mg L–1 and up to 5,000 mg L–1 .[29] Alfalfa, grain sorghum, and wheat are grown with these waters. In the Pecos Valley, water averaging 2,500 mg L–1 but ranging far higher, has been used for years.[30] Jury et al.[31] grew wheat in lysimeters with water up to 7.1 dS m–1 without effect on yield. Ayers et al.[32] were able to grow barley without yield reduction with 20,000 mg L–1 in the irrigation water, as long as a better quality water was used for stand establishment. Most of these data and observations can easily be misinterpreted, since very often the crops were grown in climates where rainfall made a significant contribution; also, the absolute yields may not always be as high as desired. Just the same, it is evident that water containing substantial levels of salt still has agronomic value. Rhoades, with colleagues, has established two elaborate field experiments to more explicitly assess the potential of using brackish water for crop production in California. The first, in Kern County, concerns the use of drainage water (8 dS m–1 and 5.5 mg L–1 boron) to grow cotton.[33] Comparison treatments use "aqueduct" water (0.6 dS m–1 ) and a 50-50 mix. Results to date have been encouraging. Notwithstanding a series of difficulties encountered during the experiments, it has been shown that highly respectable yields can be obtained, with good management, even on the extremely difficult soils of the site, with 8 dS m–1 water, especially when
the stand is established using aqueduct water. The second experiment, started at the beginning of 1982, has somewhat different (and probably more ambitious) objectives. This experiment is located in Imperial Valley and is intended to investigate the potential of using, one after the other, saline water (3,000 mg L–1 from the Alamo River) and normal water (860 mg L–1 from the Colorado River) to grow a rotation of crops including both tolerant and sensitive species. If indeed one can grow a crop of sugarbeet or cotton with "poor" water for all but stand establishment, and follow it immediately with lettuce using "good" water, then serious concerns of farmers—namely, that recovery after use of brackish water will be slow or impossible, and that use of such water on the land will thereafter restrict its use to only a few tolerant crops without foregoing cropping during a long period of reclamation—will have been resolved.
― 167 ― Both of these experiments are based on the premise that water not now used because it is deemed too salty can in fact be used effectively for irrigation if properly adapted management practices are applied; and that such use would benefit the landowners and the general public. In Imperial Valley, much of the drainage water now discharged to the Salton Sea could become available for irrigation either as an additional supply or as a substitute supply. In the Lower San Joaquin Valley, use of drainage water for irrigation would convert a waste product into an asset, reducing the volume of drainage water needing export. Another source of water, in lieu of current supplies or in addition thereto, is sewage effluent. Secondary sewage waters are typically increased in total dissolved salts, carbonate, boron, nitrogen, and in the proportion of sodium relative to calcium and magnesium.[34] However, the degree of increase is such that, in general, if the initial quality of domestic water is suitable for irrigation, then so is its secondary sewage effluent, as assessed using conventional criteria and standards.[35] Secondary sewage waters are enriched in some plant nutrients, especially nitrogen, and have value as a source of plant nutrients. In fact, reclaimed sewage water has been advocated as a satisfactory hydroponic growth medium for plants.[36] Much research on the effect of sewage effluent on plants and environment has been conducted at sewage disposal sites where high-rate effluent application has been used primarily for purposes of disposal, purification, and groundwater recharge.[37] Lower rate applications for irrigation should pose less hazard of groundwater pollution and make more effective use of the effluent as a source of water and nutrients for growing crops. Results of research and practice using low-rate applications are promising, though such use is not without its problems and potential hazards. Numerous crops have been produced over long periods of time using secondary sewage waters for irrigation.[38] Secondary sewage effluents typically contain nitrogen in the concentration range 20-40 mg L–1
of N.[39] According to Ayers and Tanji,[40] cropping problems due to excess nitrogen concentration occur in the range 5-30 mg N L–1 , and severe problems can occur when the level of N exceeds 30 mg N L–1 . Reduction in sugar content in sugarbeets, reduction of starch in potatoes, increased crop lodging and reduced milling and baking quality of small grains, reduction in yield and lodging of cotton, and reductions in yield and quality of citrus, avocados, and various other fruit crops have been reported to occur from
― 168 ― irrigating with sewage waters.[41] To cope with a high N supply in sewage waters, the farmer may have to substitute other water supplies at times.[42] The high organic matter loads of secondary sewage effluent also may reduce soil permeability through plugging of pores.[43] Thus, though one must impose some limitations, there appears to be good potential for reusing secondary sewage waters for irrigation. Such use would add to the immediate water supply, reduce or delay need for developing new supplies, decrease need for synthetic fertilizers, and reduce need for disposal facilities. However, potential health and environmental hazards associated with use of sewage waters prevent us from advocating their widespread general use for irrigation. Even though sewage waters have been used for irrigation in California for more than forty years and elsewhere for similar long periods without any confirmed case of disease resulting from their use, there still exists the potential for contamination of crops, soils, and groundwaters with viruses, bacteria, parasites, trace organic compounds, nitrate, and heavy metals.[44] These health and environmental issues do not relate to salinity—our area of expertise—and hence we will not expand on them. Suffice it to say that the reuse of sewage effluents on croplands will not generally cause serious salinity problems, but the potential of health and environmental problems must be recognized. In any case, the use of sewage waters on croplands should always be evaluated on the basis of sitespecific soil, crop, hydrologic, climatic, and management conditions, and the benefits weighed against the potential long-term consequences. Aside from reuse of drainage or sewage water, learning to use brackish water effectively opens up new supplies of hitherto untapped groundwater. For example, Bahr estimated that New Mexico has in storage about 18 x 1012 m3 of brackish groundwater.[45] If techniques were developed to use only 10 percent of that amount, this would supply the state for 500 years at current rates of use.
Changing the Cropping Pattern Another approach towards "learning to live with salinity" is to make changes in agronomic management that overcome some of the problems. To some
extent, it may be feasible to change management within an existing cropping pattern as salinity increases, as by increasing planting density of cotton to compensate for smaller plants.[46] More likely, one will need to substitute
― 169 ― more tolerant species. This, of course, involves a cost in terms of loss of flexibility—an opportunity cost. Alternatively, one may attempt to breed more salt-tolerant varieties of desired species. Though not a new idea, it has only been in recent years that much activity has taken place in this area. Because of the nature of the selection process, the degree of intraspecific variation in salt tolerance tends to be small. Nevertheless, such variation has been observed in a number of species.[47] Without attempting to document recent progress, we suggest that breeding for improved salt tolerance deserves high priority in research, but one should be prepared for a relatively long gestation period. While it is reasonable to expect success in terms of 10 or 15 percent increases in tolerance for a given species, it appears unrealistic to anticipate increases that will permit the use of seawater for conventional crops. A third alternative is the selection for cultivation of species not currently used in agriculture. Numerous halophytic species are known that, by definition, tolerate high salinity stresses. Some exhibit reasonable growth rates, but they tend to produce biomass at a rate that is low compared to that of typical agronomic crops.[48] Yet to the extent a market can be identified for these crops or their derivatives, they may offer the potential of a new agricultural industry that does not depend on fresh water supplies. It is also possible that disposal of brackish water by evaporation can be profitably coupled, under certain circumstances, with the production of halophytes that enhance or establish wildlife habitat. Unfortunately, some of the recent advocates for new plants for new uses have overlooked some fundamental difficulties. For example, the introduction of guayule as a substitute source of rubber may well be highly desirable. However, guayule appears to be fairly sensitive to salt and, although it may well survive under droughty conditions, it appears to require substantial amounts of water for maximum production. Thus guayule could become an important new crop; one may be able to grow it with limited irrigation in, say, the Texas High Plains; but it will not produce much salable product without adequate water. Far more extreme have been claims about euphorbia as a source of petroleum. Aside from the question whether the energy balance in producing petroleum from euphorbia is sufficiently favorable to warrant further investigation, it is clear that euphorbia can only be grown, at reasonable production rates, with adequate irrigation. Thus many of the claims for potential new crops overlook
― 170 ― some fundamental relations between water use and dry matter production.
Options in Perspective The objective of this paper is to explore means to sustain agricultural production in the face of deteriorating water supplies. We briefly considered, then dismissed as either impractical or outside the purview of agriculture, the interception of brackish water and its disposal or desalination. We explored, in a bit more detail, the consequences of changes in irrigation efficiency, stressing the potential reduction in salt returned to receiving water bodies by reducing subsurface flows or by inducing salt precipitation in the rootzone. In the right circumstances, these reductions can be very substantial. It would be wrong, however, to deduce that minimal leaching is likely to affect total water use significantly. As long as biomass production is not reduced, the amount of water evapotranspired by the crop will remain approximately the same; any water saving would have to be associated with reductions in phreatophyte use or in unrecoverable deep seepage losses. Increased use of brackish water for irrigation, our third option, presents technical challenges with obvious socioeconomic and institutional consequences. Whether one accepts the estimates of the Interagency Drainage Project[49] or the much higher ones by Dudek and Horner,[50] all parties agree that the existing drainage problems in the San Joaquin Valley will become more extensive and more serious. IDP estimates that, in 1990, 153,000 hectares will require artificial drainage; Dudek and Horner's estimate is 690,000 hectares. Use of drainage water for irrigation would reduce the volume needing export out of the San Joaquin Valley and, presumably, open up new disposal options. It would also raise questions of equity, and require establishment of dual pricing policies and resolution of water rights questions. In view of the high marginal cost of developing new water supplies for Los Angeles—whatever the exact figure—the potential for reducing the total diversions to Imperial Valley without reducing the area irrigated opens up interesting questions for speculation: what if the Metropolitan Water District were to purchase some of the Colorado River water currently allocated to Imperial Valley? Since the drainage into Salton Sea exceeds 1.2 x 109 m3 per year, the amount of water potentially available is
― 171 ―
far from inconsequential. The complications, legal and otherwise, also could be substantial. Our fourth option, the introduction of new crops and the breeding for higher salt tolerance, we see as important and deserving of far greater attention than it has received. However, we counsel against extreme optimism. We do not anticipate practical use of seawater for irrigation nor high levels of production per unit area of halophytes. We do anticipate, over time, substantial but modest increases in salt tolerance of several crops.
Conclusions As the pressures on water supplies mount, water quality—especially salinity —will develop into an increasingly more severe constraint. Several options do exist to reduce the adverse effects of salinity on agricultural and other water uses. There are ways to reduce the amount of salt returned to the rivers and ways to make more effective use of waters with relatively high levels of salinity. None of these options is without cost. Nor does one substitute for the other. For each set of circumstances, a specially tailored set of management practices can be developed. However, whatever the technical merit of such a plan in any given set of circumstances, the degree to which it will be implemented will often depend greatly on other technical considerations. Without adjustments in institutions, without acceptance by the water user, without government participation, we do not foresee extensive reuse of drainage water, or reductions in leaching volumes. We may hope that socioeconomic adjustments will occur in step with technical developments.
Discussion: James W. O'Leary Whenever the issue of water and agriculture is discussed, a couple of important points must be kept in mind. First, crop productivity, or dry matter production, per unit of irrigated land in the western United States is much greater than crop productivity per unit of nonirrigated land. The difference is so great that it recently has been claimed that irrigated agriculture has considerable land-conserving implications.[1] It has been calculated, that if the 18.5 million irrigated acres of corn, sorghum, wheat, and cotton were dryland-farmed, it would take an additional seven million acres of land to make up the loss in yield. The second important point to keep in mind, however, is that the high productivity is accomplished at the cost of high water consumption by the crops. Even though some plants are more efficient than others in their use of water, it is impossible for plants to assimilate carbon dioxide from the air and produce dry matter without losing water in the process.
The great concern for conserving water in agriculture has led to the increasing promotion of new crops that use less water. Some of these potential new crops are well known drought-resistant plants, such as guayule and euphorbia. As van Schilfgaarde and Rhoades have pointed out, some fundamental relations between water use and dry matter production often are overlooked in these cases. This point is too important to let it become lost. Even though these plants, and many others, have the ability to survive and even grow with extremely small quantities of water, quantities of water so small that contemporary crops could not even begin to survive, they do not have higher productivity than conventional crops when moderate or greater amounts of water are applied. The most efficient use of water by many of these plants occurs at growth rates that are far less than maximal. At growth rates that give high dry matter
― 176 ― production, they are no more efficient in their use of water, and in fact, often are less efficient than conventional crops. Thus, the important question that emerges from this brief analysis is: if forced to choose, which is more important, high productivity per unit of water used, or high productivity per unit of land used? I think it is the latter. With the increasing loss of good farmland to urbanization, the demand for high productivity per unit of land area is increased. The only solution to this dilemma is an increased use of lower quality water in agriculture. Van Schilfgaarde and Rhoades have discussed several very appropriate ways in which this could be accomplished, such as multiple use of irrigation water. We should be prepared to see use of drainage water from irrigated fields to irrigate additional fields in the near future. The use of blended drainage water and fresh water, or even undiluted drainage water, for irrigation in places like the Imperial Valley in California and the WelltonMohawk area in Arizona should be feasible. It already is being done on a limited basis. Similarly, we should be able to use treated sewage effluent, as has been suggested. Blending with other water sources, such as brackish water, may be an effective way to dilute the high nitrogen content of the sewage water and dilute the high salt content of the brackish water. It will be necessary to continue breeding efforts toward increasing salt tolerance in contemporary crops, but it must be pointed out that progress will be slow and there is an inevitable upper limit to tolerance, far below seawater concentration. I agree with the authors that it is unrealistic to anticipate increases in salt tolerance in conventional crop plants that will permit the use of seawater; however, I think I can be more optimistic than they are about the potential for obtaining high productivity from halophytes irrigated with seawater. The conclusion one arrives at when comparing productivities often depends on the figures selected to represent the crops or
crop types being compared. We have grown several species of halophytes irrigated with seawater, and the most productive ones yielded from 895 to 1,365 g DW m–2 yr–1 .[2] This compares very favorably with yields from such conventional freshwater crops as alfalfa (760 g DW m–2 yr–1 —U.S. average 1977).[3] This is an area of research that has been active for only a short time and in relatively few places, so there is not an abundance of good data yet. Nevertheless, I am extremely optimistic about the prospects of developing valuable crop plants from halophytes that could be
― 177 ― used in either seawater or brackish water based agriculture. With brackish water, the productivity should be even higher, due to the energy subsidy given to the plants. It is important to emphasize that this is a site-specific solution. Brackish or saline water can be used without detrimental effects on the site if the proper soil type is present and if proper management techniques are used. In general, I am in strong agreement with van Schilfgaarde and Rhoades regarding the options they have discussed and the emphasis they have placed on the need for other than technical considerations in order to see them implemented.
Discussion: J. Eleonora Sabadell Van Schilfgaarde and Rhoades give a clear description of causes affecting salinity and main management strategies to cope with the problem. I would like to point out other management options and some causes and effects of salination that may affect agriculture directly as well as indirectly. As has been said, salinity is due to salt loading and/or salt concentration. Any proposed remedial or preventive measure will have to deal with either or both phenomena. The increase in salt loading is due not only to saline springs and farming, but also to other land uses by which salts, natural or man-made, are added to the hydrological system. Some examples of these activities are strip-mining, livestock grazing, urbanization, processing fuel and nonfuel minerals, recreation (off-road vehicles), disposal of industrial waste, etc. These activities that disturb the soil, releasing salts into the system or adding to the total chemical load, in turn affect every land use in a feedback mode. The point is that to control salinity, it is necessary to adopt measures not only on the farm but also outside the farm.
― 178 ― Agriculture today is highly mechanized and statistics show that the number of farm workers has declined steadily, even if acreage in crops has not changed substantially; and farmers derive income from other activities besides farming. This fact, coupled with strong growth in the population of the western states and with adopted policies on energy development, indicates that the economic base in the West has diversified significantly, and that the number of land users and intensity of use has increased. Even with existing environmental legislation and regulations, the control of the synergistic and cumulative impacts on water resources of intense and multiple use of drylands has not yet been successful. Agriculture is nevertheless the number one industry in the country and in the western states. California, for example, produces more than 250 agricultural commodities and is the largest net exporter of food, grossing over $15 billion in 1980. Any change in the productive capacity of the region caused by declining water quality will be felt by the whole economic system. Along these lines, the Bureau of Reclamation has estimated that the direct damage to an area is roughly $400,300 (in 1982 dollars) per mg/L of increased salinity, and $534,000 (in 1982 dollars) of direct-plus-indirect damage per mg/L increase. If these costs continue to rise, they will impact the farming community and its financial ability to cope with its own salinity problems, to say nothing about the rest of the community and all other activities. Hence, a holistic approach to development and a recognition of the relationships among land uses and consequences seem to be in order. The "do-nothing" and the "yield to competition" options have already been adopted in some parts of the West, resulting in a shift from irrigated agriculture to some other more profitable land use. The impact on remaining agricultural activities and on the natural system involved is not yet known. The Supreme Court decision in the Sporhase v. Nebraska case will probably bring about more of these changes. The consequences and costs of such shifts should be determined and appraised before they occur. Another relationship not often considered, but significant for the solution of the salinity problem, is between water quantity and water quality. This is especially true for irrigated agriculture, as the authors have mentioned in describing the physical aspects of and the technological solutions to salination. Unfortunately, legal, political, and institutional entities view water
― 179 ― resources from two separate perspectives, quantity or quality. The result has been separate bodies of law and institutional arrangements, and responsible agencies, scientific communities, technical staff and managers that seldom communicate with each other.
On-farm practices to control salinity, specifically schemes three and four cited by the authors, are based on the natural or bred tolerance of plants for salt. The idea is to use as commercial crops plants that can be irrigated with saline water. The concern to be stressed is that input into the farming operation of higher loads of salt can eventually reach the point where the tolerance threshold of the new plants can be overwhelmed. The cost of rehabilitating soil and water resources from this more constrained situation would be higher than at present, and the possibility of developing increasingly tolerant plants is questionable. Available options for on-farm salinity control are: building underground drains and drainable wells; adopting leaching irrigation, sprinkler irrigation, special planting and bedding practices, and using soil additives; increasing irrigation frequency, etc. Not all of these measures are applicable in all instances, nor is there a single solution for a given salinity problem. In practice there are constraints on the adoption of some of these control techniques, e.g., financial limitations on the building of structures, limited water supplies for leaching or for more frequent applications, bedding practices limited to specific crops, or lack of local cooperation. Salinity control schemes are in general a combination of procedures that complement each other and are appropriate for the selected cultivation practices used. Nevertheless, there is still room to develop more efficient methods. Some of the characteristics to be considered in devising the best control options are: local physical and economic conditions; the time frame in which each procedure works; available local capabilities; interaction among individual farms, irrigation districts, and other users; technical compatibility; and the cumulative impact of practices, if any. The economic benefit of the optimal use of resources is self-evident.
― 180 ―
Chapter 7— Improving Crop Management by Ronald D. Lacewell and Glenn S. Collins
Abstract Agricultural adjustments to the rising cost and increasing scarcity of water may be expected. One adjustment is to shift production from field crops to high value crops. However, high value crops usually require (1) more water, (2) more risk, (3) new machinery, (4) more labor, (5) more management, and often (6) several years of heavy investment before the first returns. A second adjustment is to plant new drought-resistant crops such as guayule, jojoba, or crambe. Serious marketing, production, and processing issues
exist for each of these new crops. Yet another option is to continue producing field crops but alter production systems to improve yields and decrease costs by crop rotation, no-till, residue management, and new technology. The expected impact of doubling irrigation costs in the United States, as estimated by a national econometric model, was only a slight adjustment in cropping patterns. The major effect was a reduction in net farm income in the West, exceeding 20 percent for many western states. This has serious implications for the future structure of irrigated agriculture relative to consolidation and vertical integration. Thus, it is likely that most farmers will attempt to maximize profits from the more familiar field crops by adopting more efficient production systems. A number of new systems, such as optimal crop rotation, no-till practices, beneficial residue management, and better irrigation systems are reviewed in this paper.
Irrigation is a most important factor in western water use and is important to total U.S. crop production. However, water is becoming increasingly scarce and costly. Over 15 million acres of U.S. groundwater-irrigated lands are incurring declining water levels in excess of one-half foot per year.[1] A declining groundwater supply increases lifts (cost of pumping), reduces well yield, and may have a negative effect on water quality.
― 181 ― Surface water in many cases is allocated by legal and administrative institutions which may have traditionally favored agriculture. However, currently nonagricultural users are demanding transfers of surface water rights from agriculture, since typically the value of water is considerably less in agriculture.[2] It is suggested that the development of property right rules and organizational facilities to allow water transfers in a market framework is a part of the evolution of water as an economic resource.[3] This suggests water for agriculture will cost more, and some reduction in quantity of available water may be expected. The purpose of this chapter[4] is to explore the economic implications and management alternatives for irrigated agriculture in the West. First, discussion focuses on the expected impacts of significantly higher costs for ground and surface water. This leads to management options for producers and expected economic implications.
Impact of Increased Water Costs The impacts on U.S. agriculture, both regional and national, of increasing water costs may be examined using an econometric model (TECHSIM) developed at Texas A&M.[5] TECHSIM is a regional field crop and national livestock model designed to evaluate yield and/or production cost changes. Within TECHSIM, extraneous information is used as a basis to reflect changes in supply and/or demand. Then, economic impacts of a yield and/or cost change can be estimated. TECHSIM is represented by 13 field crop producing regions, shown in Figure 7.1, and four national livestock categories. The field crops included in the model are: corn, small grains (wheat, barley, and oats), grain sorghum, cotton lint, cottonseed, and soybeans. The model also contains the forward meal and oil products of cottonseed and soybeans. The national livestock products included in the model are fed beef, nonfed beef, pork, and sheep. TECHSIM is a recursive model which centers on three types of estimates: planted acreage, yield, and demand. The model assumes that producers within a region make planting decisions based on expected net returns of various field crops within the region. The recursiveness of TECHSIM is based upon the expected net returns which are equivalent to the previous year's net returns. The yield equations reflect productivity changes of the model's base period, 1961-1977.
― 182 ―
Figure 7.1 Thirteen Field Crop Producing Regions of the U.S.
― 183 ― The demand equations, with the exception of final consumer demands of the livestock sector, are intermediate demands. This implies that additional processing of these commodities is required before they reach the final consumer. Shifts resulting from increasing ground and surface water costs are introduced into the model by changing each crop's variable per-acre production cost for each region. Once these costs are changed, the model traces the impacts and provides estimates of regional and national planted acres, yields, production and supplies of each field crop. The results also give estimates of national demands (domestic, export, private and government stocks) of all commodities in the model. To examine the social implications of increased ground and surface water costs, TECHSIM estimates the short-run net returns or profits of all industries in the model plus the agricultural sector of the U.S. economy. These results are obtained by simultaneously solving all markets for prices such that each commodity's total supplies are equal to total demands. The model is based on 1979 costs and returns. Average costs of groundwater were about $17 per acre-foot and surface water about $7 in 1979 across the West.[6] Two national water alternatives are examined with TECHSIM in this paper. The first is doubling the per-acre costs of both ground and surface water. The second is doubling the cost of groundwater but letting surface water increase to $40 per acre-foot.
Planted Acreage Shifts Regional changes in planted acres due to the two increased water cost alternatives are shown in Table 7.1. All results reflect the final impact of increasing ground and surface water costs to U.S. agriculture. Total U.S. planted acres decreased under both alternatives for all crops except small grains and grain sorghum. However, the percentage change of these acreage shifts is less than 1.5 percent for each crop for both alternatives. The largest percentage shifts occurred in the western regions where irrigation is predominant in agricultural production. The greatest regional percentage shift by crop was for corn in the Mountain States (MS) region. In this region corn acreage decreased by 27.1 percent when ground and surface water costs were doubled, and decreased by 26 percent when groundwater was doubled and surface water was increased to $40 per acrefoot.
― 184 ―
Table 7.1 Regional Shifts in Planted Acres and Net Returns Policy
Regionsa US
NW
CA
MS
SW
CP
NP
TX
LS
CB
DS
S
Corn
–44
1
1
–162
1
–419 10
–40
45
75
0
8
% change from base
–.7
.2
.4
–27.2 1.2
–5.6 2.2 –4.3
.4
.2
.0
.
Small Grains 4
–23
25
142
22
–44
0
1
–37
9
1
1
% change from base
.0
–.5
1.1
1.1
2.7
–.1
.0
.1
–.4
.1
.1
.
Grain Sorghum
18
0
–32
0
86
100
0
17
0
7
3
–
% change from base
1.2
.0
–10.3 .0
22.1
1.5
.0
.3
.0
1.0
.9
–
Cotton
–4
0
–26
0
–89
15
0
32
0
0
14
1
% change from base
–.3
.0
–2.2
.0
–16.4 2.8
.0
.6
.0
.0
.4
1
Soybeans
–7
0
0
0
0
9
2
–1
50
–118 –38 6
% change from base
–.1
.0
.0
.0
.0
.3
.4
–.2
11.3 –4.0 –.4
.
Net Returns
–318 –24
–139
–129
–144
–233 13
–200
81
3
Double Ground & Surface Water Costs Planted Acres (1000)
303
68
(m. $) % change from base
–1.4 –18.0 –23.9 –29.9 –39.7 –7.7 2.4 –13.2 3.6
2.7
3.9
7
― 185 ―
Policy
Regionsa US
NW
CA
MS
SW
CP
Corn
–44
1
–4
–155
1
% change from base
–.7
1.8
–1.5
Small Grains 10
–31
% change from base
.1
Grain Sorghum
NP
TX
LS
CB
DS
S
–389 10
–38
41
70
0
8
–26.0 1.2
–5.2 .5
–4.1
.4
.2
.0
.
0
101
13
–37
0
2
–33 16
2
1
–.6
.0
.8
1.6
–.1
.0
.0
–.4
.2
.3
.
18
0
–31
0
85
104
0
14
0
7
3
–
% change from base
1.2
.0
–9.9
.0
21.9
1.6
.0
.2
.0
1.0
.9
–
Cotton
–5
0
–38
0
–80
5
0
33
0
0
15
1
Double Ground Water & Increase Surface Water to $40/acrefeet Planted Acres (1000)
% change from base
–.4
.0
–3.2
.0
–14.8 .9
.0
.6
.0
.0
Soybeans
–7
0
0
0
0
7
2
–2
49
–111 –42 5
% change from base
–.1
.0
.0
.0
.0
.3
.4
–.3
1.1
–.4
-.4
.
Net Returns (m. $)
–547 –34
–297
–162
–160
–233 17
–211
81
297
70
3
% change from base
–2.4 –24.8 –51.1 –37.6 –44.2 –7.6 3.0 –13.9 3.6
2.6
4.0
7
a
Regional delineations are illustrated in Figure 1.
― 186 ―
Net-Return Shifts The total regional and national short-run net returns or farmer profits in 1982 dollars are also shown in Table 7.1. For each region these net returns represent the sum of the changes in net returns for all field crops in a region. The national net return figures represent the summation of all regions' net returns. Nationally, total net returns decrease for field crops. Regional net return decreases are observed for Northwest (NW), California (CA), Mountain States (MS), Southwest (SW), Central Plains (CP), and Texas (TX) regions. The largest decrease in net returns when both ground and surface water costs are doubled occurs for the Southwest (SW) region. However, when groundwater cost is doubled and surface water costs are increased to $40 per acre-foot, California (CA) becomes the largest loser on an absolute and percentage basis. The Corn Belt (CB) region gains the largest dollar amount from increased water costs. Its gain amounts to approximately $300 million for both water alternatives. From a percentage standpoint, however, the Corn Belt (CB) region ranks sixth and seventh out of the seven regions which show positive increases in regional net returns. Nationally, total net returns decrease by 1.4 and 2.4 percent in the two water scenarios.
.4
1
Price Shifts The price shifts associated with increased water costs are modest. Price increases occur for corn, cotton lint, cottonseed, and soybeans. The largest price increase is for corn and soybeans. However, these prices increased by less than $.12 per bushel. Small grains and grain sorghum have slight price decreases. These small price changes are to be expected, given the small change in planted acreage of the field crops. The impact of increased water costs to the livestock sector are also small. Increases in livestock prices are observed for fed beef, pork and sheep and lambs, while only nonfed beef decreased in farm price. This is because feed prices of corn, soybean meal, and cottonseed meal increase proportionately more than small grains and grain sorghum decrease. Hence, livestock producers would shift into nonfed animal units, which tend to increase fed animal prices and decrease nonfed animal prices.
Social Implications When ground and surface water costs are increased, annual national income would decrease over $.9 billion when both water
― 187 ― cost sources are doubled, and over $1.2 billion when groundwater is doubled and surface water is increased to $40 per acre-foot. Very few agricultural industries gain as a result of these water alternatives. Consumers of field crops lose the most, but U.S. field crop producers and soybean and cottonseed meal and oil industries also lose. The livestock sector of the U.S. economy would gain; however, final consumers of livestock products lose. The major implication of this analysis is that if water costs increase, western regions which are heavily dependent upon irrigated crop production will have the greatest decrease in net returns. Furthermore, additional losses will result in areas such as California if average surface water costs increase to $40 per acre-foot. Nationally, these water cost increases will result in only modest decreases in planted acres and small changes in prices of farm products. However, other industries besides field crop producers stand to lose with increasing water costs, so that the total annual loss will approach $1 billion.
Crop Management Strategies As water costs increase and less water is available to agriculture, there are
some crop management techniques which may maintain agricultural productivity. This section considers the producer options of shifting to high value crops, practicing residue management and crop rotations, and introducing new crops. Opportunities and limitations are discussed. Often crop management alternatives will be simultaneously adopted with technical adjustments such as sprinkler system modification or irrigation well rehabilitation. They are considered separately in this paper.
High Value Crops Agricultural regions with very expensive water typically produce high value crops such as vegetables, citrus, grapes, or nuts. This is because the value of field crops is not sufficient to justify $100 per acre-foot for water. Of course, high value crops are also produced in regions with relatively low cost water. The value of irrigation water in field crops varies significantly from region to region. However, a range of from $10 to about $60 per acre-foot is typical.[7], [8], [9] The value of water in high value crops ranges from a negative value to several hundred dollars per acre-foot.[10] On the average over several years, the value of water in high value crops exceeds that of field crops. Thus, some producers may choose to shift from field crops to high value crops as
― 188 ― water costs rise and water becomes increasingly scarce. This is nevertheless a limited alternative for increasing the value of irrigation water. Table 7.2 shows water application rates and production costs per acre for some selected field crops and high value crops in California.[11] In many cases, per-acre application rates of water are higher for the higher value crops such as almonds, peaches, grapes, and tomatoes as compared to sorghum, corn, or wheat. Furthermore, yield and quality of the high value crops are much more sensitive to irrigation. This suggests skillful management of irrigation is required. Of greater importance is the cost of production for high value crops. In very general terms, the costs are greater than $1000 per acre for high value crops and less than $400 per acre for field crops. This creates a serious strain on a farmer's cash flow, particularly if he is borrowing some or all of his operating expenses. Furthermore, for citrus, fruits, nuts, and grapes, a large initial investment is required for several years before any income is returned.
In addition, these crops often require different production techniques, purchase of new equipment and machinery, and intensive labor. Machinery investment can be substantial. For example, a precision vegetable planter costs $15,000, a cultivator, $10,000, a vegetable bed-shaper, $5,000, and harvesting equipment from $40,000 to $100,000.[12] Lastly, high value crops are generally specialized within a limited market. Once the market is saturated, the price of the product (e.g., vegetables, citrus, or nuts) declines dramatically. This represents a very high level of market risk to the high value crop producer. A study of farming in El Paso County, Texas, found risk to be a major factor affecting a farmer's cropping pattern. Because of high production costs and variability, vegetable production was not observed on small and medium sized farms.[13] When the price of a product changes one percent, the responding change in quantity demanded is termed "price elasticity of demand", i.e., the percentage change in quantity for a one percent change in price. An elasticity of –.5 means if price increases one percent, quantity demanded will decline 1/2 of a percent. "Price flexibility" is the response of product price to changes in supply. An approximation of price flexibility is the inverse of price elasticity of demand. This estimate of price flexibility is a simplification and requires some simplifying assumptions. For a price elasticity of demand of – .5, price flexibility is approximately
― 189 ― –2. That is, a one percent increase in supply will cause a two percent reduction in price. Here the price effect is greater than the supply change. The smaller the price elasticity of demand, the greater is the price flexibility or the price response to changes in supply.
Table 7.2 Irrigation Application Rates and Production Costs Per Acre for Selected Crops in the San Joaquin Basin, California 1975
Crop
Irrigation Application Rate (acre-feet)
Total Production Costs ($ per acre)
Sorghum
2.3
375
Alfalfa
4.5
581
Cotton
3.3
627
Corn
2.8
368
Wheat
2.2
320
Almonds
3.1
1,154
Peaches
3.5
2,268
Grapes
3.6
1,331
Oranges
2.4
696
Lettuce
2.1
660
Carrots
2.8
2,387
Celery
2.8
3,543
Onions
2.5
874
Tomatoes
3.5
1,149
Source: Allan Highstreet, Carole Frank Nuckton and Gerald L. Horner, "Agricultural Water Use and Costs in California," Giannini Foundation of Agricultural Economics Information Series 80-2, Division of Agricultural Sciences Bulletin 1896, University of California, July 1980.
― 190 ― The price elasticity of demand for some selected products is –.31 for potatoes, –.72 for apples, –.66 for oranges, –.14 for lettuce, –.38 for tomatoes, –.26 for beans, –.25 for onions, –.49 for carrots, and –.32 generally for fresh vegetables.[14] Since only nine percent of the 50.2 million irrigated acres in the West are in high value crops and the price is very responsive to supply, there is little opportunity to shift to high value crops. If more crops are produced, prices will go down, but cost of
production will remain high. Other regions producing high value crops maintain competition. This means some acreages can shift to high value crops, but our subjective estimate is that likely less than 10 percent of current high value crop acres, or less than one-half million acres, may do so profitably. This leaves 45 million irrigated acres in field crops or pasture. Thus, other irrigation management alternatives must be considered for most irrigated cropland.
New Crops With increasing water costs and a more scarce water supply, producers are encouraged to look at new field crops which are less water intensive. In recent years, several new field crops have gained popular attention. Included among these are guayule, jojoba, buffalo gourd, crambe, kenaf, and pigeon peas. This discussion is based on a number of studies of commercial feasibility of new crops.[15], [ 16]
Guayule Guayule is a rubber-producing perennial plant native to the semiarid regions of the southwest U.S. and north central Mexico. The growth of guayule is highly dependent upon temperature and water. The plant requires little water, and in fact if rainfall and/or irrigation exceeds 25 or more inches, little rubber production occurs. Guayule withstands temperatures between 0° F and 120° F. However, freezing temperatures can kill young plants and also limit rubber production. While guayule appears to be well-suited to production in the Southwest, the requirement of a major processing facility is a significant limitation to development of commercial guayule production.
Jojoba Jojoba is a perennial shrub that produces oil seeds. Each seed is approximately the size of an olive and contains about 50 percent oil by weight. Jojoba grows in marginally arable areas. It is natively found in Mexico, along the coast of Southern
― 191 ― California, and in Arizona. Jojoba requires very little water, approximately 5 to 18 inches per year. Jojoba, like guayule, is suited to commercial agricultural practices. Both irrigation and fertilization promote faster growth and more vigorous plants. The seed of jojoba produces the only known source of unsaturated liquid
wax that is a replacement for sperm whale oil. The seed is also used in the manufacturing of detergents. Although available oil seed crushing facilities can be used for jojoba, serious production questions remain.
Crambe Crambe is an annual plant that grows to a height of approximately 3 feet. Crambe's seeds are a source of plant oil which has a high erucic acid content. About one-third of the seed weight is oil which contains about 55 percent erucic acid. This acid is used in the manufacturing of rubber additives. Crambe is a cool season crop and does not do well in extremely dry regions. The commercial production practices for crambe are similar to those for small grains. However, a major limitation of this new crop is the shattering of mature seeds during harvest. In addition, crambe faces stiff market competition and may not sell in sufficient quantities to make production profitable.
Buffalo Gourd Buffalo gourd is a perennial plant that produces fruit on a spreading vine. The plant grows naturally in the semiarid and arid regions of the West, and needs annual rainfall of only 10 to 12 inches. The seeds of buffalo gourd can be harvested yearly and contain protein and an oil which is similar to corn oil. The meal product of buffalo gourd may also be used as an animal feed. Many other so-called "new" crops have been discussed, but there are several major limitations to commercialization of any of these. For most, there is no infrastructure for marketing and processing. On the production side, there are questions about weed, insect and disease control, appropriate tillage, fertilization and irrigation practices, use of pesticides, harvesting equipment, yield, and per acre net returns. Lastly, uncertainty over general economic conditions and the risks to grower, buyer, and processor make these only possible alternatives for the future.
Crop Rotation and Residue Management Crop rotation, residue management, and tillage practices for maintaining agricultural productivity with less irrigation water
― 192 ― may be discussed simultaneously. The many alternatives include each of the options separately or in combination with each other, besides an array of other practices. Crop residues can control wind and water erosion, increase organic material in the soil, and capture rainfall.[17] However, impacts of residue management on profit and yield must be considered as well as integration with crop rotations. For example, minimal tillage is designed to leave crop residues on the surface and leave the surface rough. This increases water infiltration and reduces evaporation. For some cases, significant water savings have been shown for cotton with no yield loss and sometimes a yield increase.[18] Similarly, use of tillage systems to increase water conservation in wheat has been reported and is shown in Table 7.3.[19] Wheat yields in the Great Plains have risen from 15.9 bushels in 1916-30 under maximum tillage, to 32.2 with stubble mulch and minimum tillage. Yield is projected to average 40 bushels per acre with an effective no-till system over the next 10 years. Residues are also important in crop rotations that maximize value of limited irrigation and rainfall. For example, major
Table 7.3 Evolution of Tillage Practices on Efficient Use of Natural Rainfall
Year
Tillage Practice
Wheat Yield (bu. per acre)
1916-30 Maximum tillage
15.9
1931-45 Conventional tillage
17.3
1946-60 Improved conventional tillage and stubble mulch
25.7
1961-75 Stubble mulch and minimum tillage
32.2
1976-90 Projected improved minimum tillage and no-till
40.0
Source: B.W. Greb, "Reducing Drought Effects on Croplands in the West Central Great Plains," United States Department of Agriculture, Information Bulletin 420, 1979.
― 193 ― increases in yields of dryland grain sorghum have been obtained where residues from irrigated wheat have been undisturbed by no-till methods by using herbicides for weed control during summer fallow.[20] Lower costs and higher average grain yields indicate a major economic advantage for notill sorghum in an irrigated wheat-fallow-dryland grain sorghum system. Grain sorghum produced under the no-till system averaged 3,150 pounds per acre compared to 2,190 with conventional tillage. This system is also effective with crops other than sorghum, such as cotton. Unlimited crop rotations may be devised using the no-till system. Multicropping options include double-cropping, three crops in two years, and five crops in four years. Yet, no-till is only part of a cropping system and not the system.[21] Optimal crop rotation and tillage systems will be area- and regional-specific. Based on results to date, however, the outlook is promising. As irrigation water becomes more scarce, relatively drought-tolerant crops should be selected. These include cotton, wheat, sunflower, and grain sorghum. Crops to be avoided, since yield and quality are very sensitive to water shortage or irrigation delays, include corn, soybeans, and vegetables.[22] Also, with limited irrigation it is desirable to grow multiple crops in rotation within an area, so that peak demand periods most sensitive to water stress do not coincide. Shortcomings and limitations of no-till systems and different crop rotations need to be discussed along with advantages. For example, no-till wheat at Bushland, Texas, showed a higher average yield than conventionally tilled wheat, being much higher in the best year, but much lower in the worst year. This suggests an increase in risk.[23] Also, direct seeding into heavy stubble is difficult. There have been examples of crop yield reductions of 10 to 30 percent where crops were seeded into heavy stubble, as compared to conventional tillage.[24] In addition to poor stands in stubble, there is often increased weed infestation. In finetextured soils in some regions under chemical fallow (weed control with herbicides), the soils become too hard for seeding. Some agronomic constraints limit cropping pattern adjustments. For example, in the Pacific Northwest nematode buildup limits the extent of
potato acreage increase.[25] Disease, weeds, insects, erosion, and other concerns will certainly influence crop selection, rotations, and tillage systems.
― 194 ―
Improved Technology This section examines some economic implications of the many new technologies that often are integrated into an overall management system. The discussion covers equipment as well as more management-oriented options.
Low-Energy Precision Application (LEPA) This is a sprinkler system which has been modified with drop tubes. It operates at less than 10 pounds per square inch of pressure, applying irrigation water uniformly across the field with little evaporation. The LEPA system in combination with row dams is both water- and energy-efficient. This system on 1.7 million sprinkler-irrigated acres on the Texas High Plains was estimated to increase the value of groundwater by $1 billion over 20 years. Cost to modify current sprinkler systems would be about one-tenth of this. This economic benefit comes from using less energy and reducing the rate of depletion of groundwater.[26]
Furrow Dikes The LEPA system's effectiveness is very dependent upon row damming or furrow dikes in tight soils. The furrow dikes conserve both irrigation water and natural rainfall. Results indicate that furrow diking on nonirrigated land in Texas and Oklahoma increases cotton yield from 11 to 25 percent, and grain sorghum yields from 25 to 40 percent. The value of furrow diking on nonirrigated land for the Texas High Plains and Oklahoma Panhandle is an estimated increase in farmers' annual net income of $87.6 million.[27]
Limited Irrigation-Dryland System (LIDS) This system was developed and is being tested by Stewart et al.[28] This system uses a limited water supply to irrigate an area larger than could be fully irrigated. A field is divided into three sections. The upper half is managed as fully irrigated. The next fourth is a tailwater runoff section that uses furrow runoff from the fully irrigated section. The last fourth of the field is managed as dryland, using both irrigation runoff and natural rainfall. This system also uses furrow dikes placed about every 10 feet. These dikes are
washed out by irrigation water to the distance that the water advances down the furrows.
― 195 ― This system has increased grain sorghum output per acre-inch of irrigation water from about 302 pounds per acre to 450 pounds. This is about a onethird increase in grain production as compared to conventional irrigation with limited water. With grain sorghum at $5 per hundred-weight, this is an increase in the value of water of $7.50 per acre-inch.[29]
Other Several other strategies or techniques are available, such as irrigation scheduling, alternate furrow irrigation, row spacing and directional effects, land shaping, distribution systems, skiprow planting, and staggered planting dates. Details of their use appear in numerous published studies. The appropriateness and economic implications of each are influenced by costs of water, quantity of water available, price of products, labor availability, credit, and managerial ability of the operator.
Conclusions The national effect on cropping patterns of more expensive water is not expected to be dramatic. The effect on producers' net returns is of much more concern, particularly in the West. Reduced net farm income has implications for the structure of agriculture in the West. High value crops are not likely to be the salvation of irrigated agriculture. The price of high value crops is very sensitive to supply, hence a small increase in production dramatically reduces price. Further, compared to typical field crops, often high value crops use more water, their per-acre costs are several times greater, their risk is significant, and managerial ability is critical for their success. There are some methods available for farmers, however, that can be economically attractive. These include improved crop rotations and residue management, improved irrigation distribution systems, new tillage practices, better irrigation scheduling, and new crop production systems including a number of improved techniques. Irrigation will continue in the West, and make a significant contribution to agriculture and the nation. The crop production system, however, can be expected to change significantly in response to high water costs and reduced
availability of water.
― 196 ―
Discussion: Donald J. Brosz As water costs increase and less water is available to agriculture, certain crop management techniques may maintain agricultural productivity. Irrigators in the West today are experiencing limited water supplies in many areas every year. Under the prior appropriation water law system, waters are regulated according to water availability during the irrigation season, particularly surface water supplies during the late season on streams with no storage. Junior water right holders have managed limited water supplies for many years. I believe they serve as a good example of how others may manage a limited supply in the future. It doesn't take an irrigator with a limited water supply long to determine on which lands and what crops he can obtain the highest income with the water supply he has available. As stated in this chapter, 22 percent of the irrigated land in the West is hay and 10 percent pasture. Much of this is located in high elevation country, ranging from 5000 to 9000 feet. Many of these lands produce only 3/4 to 11/4 tons of hay per acre. Herein lies a great alternative for western agriculture. Many of the irrigated hay acres are native hay. Research conducted in several states shows that yields of 4 to 5 tons per acre can be achieved on mountain meadows using improved grass varieties.[1] Studies also indicated that consumptive use of water is essentially the same for growing the low tonnage native hay and growing the improved varieties.[2] By improving water management and planting improved grass varieties on the better lands, production can be maintained at possibly lower costs and water made available from the poorer lands for other uses. Part of crop management includes the study and proper management of phreatophytes or hydrophytes. Not many studies have been done to date on water consumption by noncrop vegetation. Not all such vegetation is needed for habitat, and a substantial quantity of water might be made available by managing phreatophytes and hydrophytes. The authors have touched on technical and economic efficiency. As cost goes up and water becomes less available, more emphasis will be placed on increasing efficiency of use. Research shows that often less irrigation water is required than presently used. Using less often results in crop yield increases, less fertilizer lost due to leaching, and less lands "seeped." The end result is that the irrigator will realize a higher net return using less water. More water also becomes available for other
― 199 ― users when irrigation efficiencies are increased. Here we must be careful how we define both technical efficiency and economic efficiency. There is no question that we can demonstrate to the individual irrigator that it often is beneficial for him to become more efficient with his water. But what are the impacts upon the area and basin? Much information is still needed on the variability of soils in fields, and irrigation practices related to such soil variabilities. Does an irrigator strive to achieve maximum yields in all parts of the field? Where surface waters are used for irrigation, increases in delivery system and on-farm efficiencies may require additional water storage to provide water supplies to downstream water users. If not, the shortage of water in an area and basin may be accelerated. Present irrigation methods in many cases serve as a water storage system. Excess application of irrigation water in many areas sustains late season streamflows, may be a source of groundwater to present users, and may have created fish and wildlife streamflow habitat. The cost of water may increase, and quantity availability decrease, to all users unless careful planning is done basin by basin. Limiting water to irrigated agriculture in the West may have a substantial impact involving not only agriculture but all water users in a community, area, basin, and/or region. A method for evaluating irrigation efficiencies and economic results comparing alternative delivery systems and on-farm improvements has been tried in Idaho. A cooperative study by United States Department of Agriculture, Soil Conservation Service, Economic Research Service, and the Forest Service was published in 1977,[3] comparing annual net benefits for various irrigation project improvements in the Upper Snake River Basin. Similar studies are being made elsewhere. In western Wyoming, in the area known as Star Valley, flood method irrigation systems on over 10,000 acres of land have been converted to gravity pressure sprinkler systems. With the high cost of power and the availability of low pressure systems today, many areas in the West may find that enough pressure can be obtained by utilizing elevation and pipelines. These sprinkler systems have substantially increased water application efficiencies and crop yields. However, since sprinkler systems have been installed, more flooding along streams often occurs during early spring runoff, and much lower streamflows result in late summer. Habitat, fisheries, water supplies, etc., have been
― 200 ― impacted by increased irrigation efficiency practices. Some studies have been initiated to evaluate the technical-economic efficiency of the area as influenced by a change in on-farm systems. Costs for pumping irrigation water today are causing great concern. Many acres may be taken out of irrigation in the near future. Cost of pumping needs to be further addressed. An interagency task force study on irrigation water use and management (report published in June 1979)[4] recommends that the governors representing irrigated agriculture initiate and maintain a cooperative program through federal, state, and local agencies and the private sector to study and coordinate water efficiency programs. Agriculturalists have the opportunity to take leadership in wise water development, use, and management. They have been in the water business a long time. Their influence might bring water users together to cooperatively develop methods and techniques to assure water supplies for all uses for many years to come.
Discussion: Zach Willey Methods of quantitative assessment of the impacts of water scarcity within agricultural regions require integrated physical and economic components. This integration can be pursued with mathematical models which link physical and economic variables and allow "what if" scenarios to be evaluated. The state-of-the-
― 201 ― art in the development of such integrated models is at a rudimentary stage, when judged by the test of predictive accuracy. Nevertheless, their development and improvement is of great importance in efforts to resolve the dilemma of water scarcity facing agriculture in the future. Lacewell and Collins have made a significant contribution to this process in this chapter. In their attempt to quantitatively evaluate the impacts of water cost increases on western irrigated agriculture, the linking of factors underlying the demand for irrigation water, and the ensuing market supply for various commodities with their market demand, is central. This is done with a recursive econometric model which can illustrate relative intraand
inter-regional shifts in commodity supply functions and their resulting impacts on prices, crop acreage allocations, and net revenues to producers. The authors' piece is timely, since there has been, during recent years, a primary emphasis in resource/agricultural policy modeling efforts on large linear programming models which do not allow the kind of intertemporal market equilibrium scenario work possible with this approach. Great strides in the use of L-P models have been made, most notably in the work of the Iowa State team led by Earl Heady, which played a central role, for example, in implementation of the 1976 Resource Conservation Act. The appeal of the Iowa State approach has been that changes in production conditions can enter directly through the "technical coefficients" and resource constraints of the L-P, rather than indirectly through the derived demand for the natural resource and ensuing entry as a cost element in the commodity supply function. The other side of the coin is that the LP approach must impose commodity demand exogenously, instead of incorporating the more realistic dynamic interplay of supply and demand as pursued by Lacewell and Collins. This interplay allows estimates of changes in regional acreage shifts, prices, and producer revenues which will likely be much more realistic. A key problem in either approach is in the translation of water scarcities into economic decisions where technical change and input substitution are possible. Having provided this perspective on Lacewell and Collins' work, there is clearly not adequate opportunity in this very cursory review to provide a detailed and constructive critique of their approach. A brief discussion of what in my view is the major area in need of work in the future will have to suffice. This concern is primarily that the TECHSIM model has not been
― 202 ― developed to incorporate the "high value" crops which are a major focus in the paper. The question, "How much can shifts into high value crops mitigate the economic impact of water cost increases on producers?" cannot be answered through a quantitative simulation of TECHSIM as it currently exists. TECHSIM focuses only on field crops and livestock, and omits "high value crops," such as vegetables, fruits, and nuts, as well as such forage crops as alfalfa hay and irrigated pasture. Consequently, it cannot address relative adjustments in production of field crops and these other crops as a result of water cost increases. While the authors' conclusion that rising water costs would increase prices and/or decrease acreage of many crops makes sense, other results do not. That water cost increases would decrease net returns nationally in field crop production, the demand for which is "price-inelastic," is counter to the expected higher prices, lower acreage, and higher revenues. The authors even note that this would be the case in the Corn Belt region for corn and
soybeans, where prices and net regional return would rise from increased water costs. But the same scenario would not occur in California, which TECHSIM says would be a big loser in field crops. Presumably this reflects the phasing-out of cotton production in California, which might constitute a net revenue loss if no substitution of acreage of other nonfield crops resulted. Again, TECHSIM doesn't allow this substitution. TECHSIM also tells us that the livestock sector of the U.S. economy would gain from water cost increases. Yet alfalfa hay and irrigated pasture are not included in TECHSIM. In California, for example, these two feed and forage crops are major water users. Since the demand for livestock products tends to be price-elastic and feed crops such as corn price-inelastic, one would expect livestock production to be among the biggest losers, not winners, with respect to net revenue changes associated with water cost increases. The authors reason that the demands for "high value" crops are priceinelastic and, therefore, that increases in supply would result in drastic declines in price. When this is combined with the high production costs of such crops, the risks of producing them are substantial, and would act as a damper to their increased production. However, when relative elasticities are considered, the validity of this argument becomes unclear. The demands for fruits and vegetables do tend to be inelastic (estimates in the –.10 to –.40 range at the farm level), but less so than grain crops (estimates of less –.10 for wheat, corn, and barley),
― 203 ― and the demands for many livestock products tend to be more elastic (from around –.50 for cheese to –.70 for chicken and beef to nearly –2.00 for lamb and mutton). It appears that water cost increases would influence dairy and cattle production and revenues relatively more adversely than revenues for fruits, vegetables, and some grain crops. The upshot is that water cost increase could actually increase the ratio of acreage in high value crops considerably, since their relative economic attractiveness has been enhanced compared to many feed and livestock commodities. This enhancement would mitigate the risk of dramatic price declines from increased production of these crops. In conclusion, Lacewell and Collins have begun an important new effort at simulating the effects of water scarcity on agricultural production in the U.S. I hope that they continue to expand and improve the TECHSIM model. If they do, an important new tool in agricultural and environmental policymaking will be available in the years to come.
― 204 ―
Chapter 8— Improving Land and Water Use Practices by Norman J. Rosenberg
Abstract As water supplies diminish, land will necessarily be removed from irrigation or water will be applied more sparingly. Further, much of the agriculture of the semiarid to subhumid regions will continue to be practiced on "dryland". Science in support of agricultural production must concentrate on increasing water supplies and diminishing water consumption. Increasing the water use efficiency in crop production by increasing photosynthesis, by decreasing transpiration, or both, is another way to make limited water supplies go further. An analysis of technological options to further the objectives described above was made for the Great Plains region in a workshop sponsored by the National Science Foundation. Ways to increase supply include water harvesting, minimum tillage, snow management, improved cultural practices, soil evaporation reduction, phreatophyte control, and use of small water impoundments. Findings with respect to these methods are briefly summarized in this chapter. Ways to decrease demand include the use of alternative crops, microclimate modification, selection for efficient water use, and irrigation scheduling. Microclimate modification and selection for efficient water use are illustrated through description of an integrative scientific approach involving manipulation of plant reflectance. Mathematical models, chamber studies, and field studies with artificial reflectants and with specially bred pubescent isolines of soybeans, have led to the development of plants better adapted to limited water supply.
Much of the land in semiarid and subhumid areas is already being used for food production. If we can save and use more of the uncertain and sometimes inadequate water supply, if we can beneficially alter the water supply and the microclimatic conditions in which these plants grow, and if we can develop plants
― 205 ― that use water more efficiently, we can produce more and better crops. In my view, this is one of the major challenges facing agronomic scientists, agronomists, engineers and meteorologists in the years to come. Others in this volume emphasize ways of getting more water to sustain agriculture in the semiarid West. My emphasis will be on ways to decrease demand by crops grown on dryland. Of course, many of the same principles I review can apply to irrigation agriculture, and reductions in water demand mean an increase in water supply. Sustained agricultural production on the lands that have remained dry in the semiarid West will be given primary emphasis. However, realism tells us that some lands that are now in irrigation will, when their water supplies are depleted or cannot be economically brought to the surface, revert to dryland agriculture. Perhaps some intermediate type of cultivation such as strategic or critical-stage irrigation will be used in such regions to extend the useful life of the aquifer. We may also foresee that some lands that have not yet been introduced to irrigation may be irrigated for only a short time. Evidence of satelliteprovided imagery shows that in Nebraska in 1980, 18,785 center pivot systems were operational and 1,348 were inactive or had been abandoned.[1] Economic factors such as commodity prices and input costs (e.g., fertility, erodibility) may necessitate the abandonment of lands now under irrigation or their reconversion to dryland culture. We should be prepared for that development. The problem is to increase water supply and to demand less. To accomplish the former in dryland agriculture is not so easy as it is (conceptually, at least) in irrigation. You do not open the tap more widely. The task is to capture and hold in soil storage as much of the precipitation as possible. There are ways in which plants can be made to demand less water: the microclimate in which they grow can be modified, the plant can be treated, or the plant can be altered in certain ways. In the discussion which follows, these concepts will be further explained and examples will be given. The issues of water supply and demand, especially as it applies to Great Plains agriculture, was reviewed in a workshop that addressed the task of developing drought management strategies for the Great Plains.[2] In March 1979 a group of knowledgeable individuals—climatologists, agronomic scientists, farmers, and persons in other sectors of the economy and government—were invited to assemble a tabulation of strategies, technological,
― 206 ― political, economic and social, in anticipation of future droughts in the region. The report of the Panel on Technology, chaired by Dr. Harold E. Dregne of Texas Tech University, provides a comprehensive list of emergency, short-term, and long-term tactics worthy of further study and development as a means of minimizing the impacts of drought and in improving agricultural stability.[3] Eleven technologies were identified. These can be ordered according to their primary purpose—increasing water supply or decreasing water demand. Increasing supply: 1) Water harvesting 2) Minimum tillage 3) Snow management 4) Improved cultural practices 5) Soil evaporation reduction 6) Phreatophyte control 7) Use of small impoundments Decreasing demand: 8) Use of alternate crops 9) Microclimate modifications 10) Selection for efficient water use 11) Irrigation scheduling Of these, items 6, 7 and 11 do not fall within the scope of this paper. The brief review of items 1-5 and 8 draws heavily on the report of the Panel on Technology.
Increasing Supply Water Harvesting "Water harvesting" is the capture of runoff water which spreads over depressional areas in fields or the floodplains of streams. The practice has ancient roots. Evenari et al.[4] have described reconstruction of ancient Nabateaen settlements in Israel's Negev desert where water harvesting provided the basis for all food production. On this continent, water spreading has been limited to mostly a few high-value crops grown in the Southern Plains region, but the potential exists for greater use of microcatchments in low rainfall areas. Microcatchments (microwatersheds) within fields can cause severe flooding of planted areas when precipitation is heavy, so that, except in the very arid regions, this technique may be of limited use.
― 207 ―
Minimum Tillage Methods have been developed to reduce the number of tillage operations needed in crop production. Certain plowing, harrowing, and cultivation operations can be eliminated for many crops, particularly where chemical herbicides are effective in weed control. The benefits of minimum tillage in reducing soil erosion by wind and water have been demonstrated,[5] as has the increased soil moisture availability in times of drought.[6] About 20 percent of U.S. crop production was on minimum or no-tilled land in 1979. Much greater adoption is predicted in the future. Some unsolved problems of minimum tillage include uneven seed germination, low soil temperature in spring, possible disease and insect outbreaks, and possible undesirable environmental effects due to reliance on chemical herbicides. Nonetheless, the potential of minimum-tillage methods for improving soil moisture conditions, minimizing losses of topsoil, and reducing the energy and labor costs in crop production indicates that adoption should increase in coming years.
Snow Management In the Canadian Prairie provinces, the northern Great Plains, and into Nebraska and Kansas, a significant portion of the annual precipitation occurs in the form of snow. Unless controlled, snow either blows off or runs off over frozen ground as it thaws. Thus, snow often contributes little to the reservoir of soil moisture available to the crop in the spring. Snow is best controlled by reducing windspeed near the surface. This can be accomplished with constructed barriers, tree windbreaks, sown windbreaks, or annual or perennial crops,[7] or by leaving stubble of the previous crop standing in
the field. Barriers cause some problems. Efficiency of tillage operations is decreased to a degree where barriers such as trees create traffic obstacles. Windbreaks may harbor insects that attack the sheltered crop, but they may also, of course, harbor beneficial creatures. The incidence of fungal diseases is thought to increase where the windbreak creates a more humid environment that can favor such disease. Nonetheless, the benefits of wind barriers, particularly in snow management, are important.[8] In the semiarid regions where grains are grown, even small increments of water lead to very significant yield increases.[9] Windbreaks are discussed in greater detail below.
― 208 ―
Improved Cultural Practices Cultural practices of benefit in moisture conservation and yield improvement are many and varied. They include tillage, fertilization, strip cropping, crop (plant) selection, skip-row planting, and crop rotation. The objective is to maximize crop production while achieving water and soil conservation. Many highly efficient management practices have been developed in the past 30 years. The development of minimum tillage and no-tillage practices are recent examples. One of the major needs in dryland agriculture is to find better ways to supply nitrogen to crops without running the risk of injuring the plant or of prolonging the vegetative period. Plant and row spacing to meet varied climatic conditions is also a tactic in need of further research.
Soil Evaporation Reduction Systems of reduced tillage which maintain crop residues, promote aggregation, increase infiltration, reduce evaporation and erosion, and control weeds are key factors in increasing stored soil moisture. Crop residues and other mulches on the soil surface reduce evaporation for one or more of the following reasons: a vapor barrier is created; soil temperature is lowered; wind speed at the soil surface is diminished. Weed control by mechanical means depletes soil moisture by exposing moist soil to the elements. Rational use of chemical weed control for moisture conservation is indicated. Winter moisture is stored more efficiently than is summer rainfall, so that in the northern plains windbreaks of perennial grasses can be used to increase snow catch and soil moisture storage.[8] Fallowing systems are widely used over the Great Plains, and further
research to integrate chemical and mechanical weed control will be needed to adapt such methods to areas of varying rainfall and soil texture, organic matter content and pH, so that soil water storage can be maximized and evaporation minimized without injury to the crop. Where limited water is available for supplemental irrigation, evaporation can be reduced and water use efficiency increased by applying the water at critical stages of crop growth like tasseling and silking, head emergence, or pod and bean development. Tests of strategic (limited) irrigation of sugarbeets in the High Plains of Texas have shown a considerable overall saving of water with little loss of yield. Irrigation water was used most efficiently when application was adequate to maintain a nearly full canopy,
― 209 ― with no periods of major water stress or excessive water. One irrigation prior to the onset of major water stress in July promoted high water use efficiency in sugarbeets.[10] A considerable body of work has also been done on limited irrigation and conjunctive use of rainfall for sorghum and wheat in the High Plains of Texas.[11] Similar strategies of limited irrigation and conjunctive water use need to be worked out under a variety of cropping, environmental, and stress conditions.
Decreasing Demand Alternative Crops One way to face a problem may be to avoid it. Thought is being given to introduction to the semiarid and subhumid regions of new crops which are less sensitive to moisture stress than those currently grown.[12] Possible new food crops for use in dryland farming systems or with limited irrigation include pearl millet, amaranth, and guar. Specialty crops considered for introduction include guayule as a source of latex and forage sorghum for biomass conversion. Kochia and fourwing saltbrush (Atriplex canascens ) are potentially useful new plants for Great Plains rangeland. Breeding, cropping systems development, and marketing research will be needed before these crops can be introduced.
Microclimate Modification A number of microclimate modification methods have proven effective in reducing demand for water and/or increasing water use efficiency in crop production. A few of these are described in detail here:
Windbreaks and Shelterbelts Strong and damaging winds often reduce agricultural productivity. Cold winds in spring and fall may cause mechanical damage to the whole plant, as well as freezing damage to certain tissues. Winds blowing from arid into semiarid and subhumid areas can also cause mechanical damage. But these winds, because of their high temperature and low humidity, also impose severe moisture stress on the growing crops and cause wilting, desiccation, and loss of potential productivity. In regions where the land is not well protected by vegetation, wind erosion may occur and initiate a decline in productivity. Young, tender vegetation may be damaged or destroyed by "sand blasting" when soil is
― 210 ― eroded by wind. For a detailed review of the direct effects of wind on plant growth, see Sturrock,[13] and Grace.[14] Properly designed windbreaks can aid greatly in stabilizing agriculture in regions where strong winds are common. The windbreak aids in uniformly distributing snow over the fields, thereby increasing the supply of soil moisture in spring.[7], [8] Windbreaks have a considerable impact on the crops they shelter during the growing season as well.
Considerable experimentation with tree windbreaks and with windbreaks constructed of such materials as snow fencing, plastic screens, and reed mats has shown that the climate that prevails in the sheltered area is more moderate than that in adjacent unsheltered fields. [15] ,[16] The air is slightly warmer by day and slightly cooler by night, but absolute humidity is greater by day and by night. The overall effect on the microclimate is to moderate evaporative demand and moisture stress on the sheltered plants. Since moisture stress leads to wilting, closure of the plant stomates, and cessation of photosynthetic activity, the windbreak should permit the achievement of improved crop yields. Evidence from around the world showing this to be true is given in reviews of "shelter-effect" by Van Eimern et al.,[17] Marshall,[18] Rosenberg,[19] and Grace.[14] Despite the proven beneficial effects of windbreaks planted in the Great Plains during the drought years of the 1930s, many of them are now being removed. Changes in agricultural land use that involve larger fields and expensive irrigation systems have increased the value of the land to the point where farmers begrudge its occupation by tree windbreaks. Windbreaks may interfere with the mechanical operation of the large centerpivot sprinkling systems that are revolutionizing irrigation in the Great Plains region.[20] There is urgent need for windbreak designs compatible with current and foreseeable agricultural systems in windswept regions.
What do we know of the actual mechanisms of windbreak effects on the sheltered plants? From the reviews cited above and particularly from our work in Nebraska with annual windbreaks, constructed windbreaks, and tree windbreaks, the following synthesis is made: · Shelter is normally beneficial to plant growth. Moisture conservation for later use by the plant is probably the major direct benefit of shelter in dryland agriculture. Even under liberal irrigation, however,
― 211 ― shelter effect is beneficial to plant growth and yield; turbulent exchange is reduced in shelter; the amplitude of the temperature wave is increased; the air becomes more humid. CO2 concentration is affected very little. · If the shelter-affected microclimate did not induce physiological differences in plant stomatal resistance to diffusion, evapotranspiration would be consistently reduced in shelter. Sometimes, however, unsheltered plants exposed to strong evaporative demand exhibit incipient wilting with large increases in the stomatal resistance. Then it is possible for the sheltered plants to transpire more water. At such times, of course, the opportunity for photosynthesis remains greater for the plants in shelter. In an attempt to better understand the problem of shelter effect on water use, Brown and Rosenberg[21] developed a resistance model to predict actual evapotranspiration. The model is derived from the Daltonian concept of evaporation from a free water surface, and requires knowledge of the following meteorological inputs: net radiation and soil heat flux (Rn + S), air temperature (Ta ), vapor pressure of the air (ea ), and aerial diffusion
resistance (ra ). The stomatal diffusion resistance to vapor, rs , must also be known. To apply the model to a crop canopy rather than to a single leaf, rc , a measure of the canopy resistance may be substituted for rs . Using data developed in an experiment conducted in western Nebraska where double rows of corn sheltered irrigated sugarbeets, the model closely predicted measured windbreak influence on evapotranspiration.[15] The model predicted major water savings, particularly under conditions of strong sensible heat advection (strong winds, high temperature, low humidity). Miller et al.[22] demonstrated, with precision weighing lysimeters, that soybeans in shelter also transpire significantly less water when such conditions prevail. We see no convincing evidence to suggest that photosynthesis rate is decreased in shelter, either because of reduced turbulence or lowered CO2
concentration. In fact, the physiological responses of the sheltered crop under the conditions of reduced evaporative demand in shelter are all conducive to greater photosynthetic activity. The sensitivity of stomatal resistance to the interacting influences of soil water potential and shelter climate
― 212 ― strongly suggests that windbreaks, valuable as they are in most climates, can be particularly important in the development and stability of agriculture in semiarid lands. Shelter effect and its influence on crop growth now seems fairly well understood. There is great need for engineers, foresters, and agronomists to develop and/or adapt windbreak designs which will be most effective in each region. Tall annual crops such as corn, sorghum, or ryegrass can be planted in fields of shorter crops in order to provide shelter or to augment shelter provided by widely-spaced tree windbreaks.[7] This idea is not new, but considerable adaptive research will be needed to develop appropriate management systems.
Reflectants Speculations by Seginer[23] and Aboukhaled et al.[24] suggested that, by increasing the albedo of plants, the net energy load upon them could be reduced, and this should result in diminished evaporation and transpiration. Rosenberg and Brown[25] modeled the effects of reflectants on evapotranspiration. For their calculations, they assumed a 20 percent reduction in net radiation. No more than 15 percent has actually been achieved in our subsequent field studies, however. Whatever the weather condition, lower Rn (higher reflectance) leads to reduced evapotranspiration. The influence of reflectance is of least consequence under high temperature and low humidity since, then, advection of sensible heat is a major source of energy. Savings of water are significant at high temperature and high humidity, and even greater if the reflectant increases canopy resistance to a degree by plugging the stomates. That reflectants actually do reduce evapotranspiration has been demonstrated with artificial coatings applied to rubber plants by Aboukhaled et al.[24] in growth chambers, and by Doraiswamy and Rosenberg,[26] Lemeur and Rosenberg,[27] and Baradas et al.[28], [29] for soybeans grown in the field.
We do not yet fully comprehend the reasons for the reflectant effect on water use, although Baradas et al.[29] consider that increased stomatal
resistance, reduced net radiation, reduced longwave emissivity, and other factors are involved. Reflectants may indeed reduce evapotranspiration, but water use efficiency can increase only if photosynthesis is not reduced concomitantly. With soybeans we anticipated no major decrease in photosynthesis since, under field conditions, that crop is light-saturated by a global radiation flux density of about 700 W m–2 .
― 213 ― In experiments conducted in the early 1970s at Mead, Nebraska (cited above), we found that photosynthesis and yield were not reduced at all, apparently because the materials with which the plants were coated increased multiple reflection of light deep into the canopy where the plant is usually light-un saturated. One would expect that reflectorizing a C4 plant such as sorghum which is light-saturated might diminish photosynthesis in that crop. Moreshet et al.[30] found, indeed, that net photosynthesis in sorghum was reduced by 23 percent (solar radiation by 26 percent) immediately after application of a kaolinite coating. But grain yield was consistently increased by the treatment. They attribute this result to specific beneficial physiological effects at the time of panicle initiation and to early senescence in the treated plants that hastened translocation to the developing grain. The application of reflectant materials may be impractical on a large scale. The practice may prove useful as an emergency technique in times of drought or severe water shortage, especially where labor to apply the material is available. However, from the studies described above, another different approach to increasing water use efficiency has developed. This is described in the following section.
Natural Reflectants—Plant Architecture As shown above, there is theoretical support for the ideal that increased reflectance should reduce evapotranspiration. There is experimental evidence that, by artificially increasing reflectance, evapotranspiration may be reduced. There are ways by which reflectance can be naturally modified. Albedo varies from species to species and within species according to age of the leaf, turgidity, presence of waxes or other materials on the surface, and concentration of chlorophyll. For example, Fergus et al.[31] have reported on barley plants bred isogenically for greater albedo through a reduction in
chlorophyll concentration. Wooley,[32] Ghorashy et al.,[33] and Gausman and Cardenas[34] have found in the case of soybeans that leaf pubescence increases reflectivity slightly in the visible waveband, more significantly in the near infra-red. Wooley,[32] and Ghorashy et al.[33] also found, for single leaves, that pubescence decreased transpiration, both because of reduced radiation absorption and because of an increased boundary layer resistance. Ehleringer and Bjorkman[35] and Ehleringer and Mooney[36] have observed a
― 214 ― greater visible reflectance, a reduced transpiration, and a slightly reduced photosynthetic rate in Encelia farinosa due to increased pubescence. However, Ghorashy et al.[33] found no reduction in photosynthetic rate in soybeans, and Hartung et al.[37] found increased yield rate associated with leaf pubescence in that crop. Drs. James Specht and James Williams of the University of Nebraska Agronomy Department have developed a range of paired soybeans bred isogenically to differ in a single gene only. In their work pairs differ only in the gene that controls a certain expression of the plant's architecture. For example, they have provided us with seed of isogenically paired Harosoy cv. soybeans which differs only in the degree of pubescence on the leaves and stems. These isolines were grown in plots of about 1.5 hectares in experiments conducted during 1980 at our Agricultural Meteorology Station near Mead, Nebraska. Detailed measurements of radiation balance, energy balance, photosynthesis, and evapotranspiration were made in the field during the course of the summer. Results of the study are being reported in a number of papers now in press (Baldocchi et al.[38], [39], [40] ). For our purpose, however, it is sufficient to cite the following findings: ET was reduced overall by approximately 7 percent in the densely pubescent isoline of Harosoy cv. Photosynthesis and yield were unaffected by pubescence over the season. But on single days, especially days of strong regional sensible heat advection, the CO2 /H2 O flux ratios were increased by 30 percent. The pubescence greatly altered the partioning of Rn with deeper penetration into the canopy of the pubescent isoline. In practical terms, the research on pubescence described above provides an important opportunity for strengthening and stabilizing agriculture at the edge of the semiarid and subhumid zones. Soybeans are currently grown about as far west as Lincoln, Nebraska. To the west, corn, especially irrigated corn, predominates. Corn is strongly sensitive to dry and hot weather, especially as it enters the reproductive stage. Soybeans are less
so, since indeterminate cultivars predominate. The agronomic trials of Hartung et al.[37] and the microclimate-physiology studies of Baldocchi et al.[38], [39], [40] support the plan to introduce pubescent soybean lines into the drier areas to the west. Pubescent isolines are now being increased so that by the end of this decade they may be introduced to commercial use.
― 215 ―
Conclusions In order to sustain dryland agriculture in the semiarid and subhumid West, proven techniques for increasing the supply of available water and decreasing demand must be applied. Snow management, limited irrigation, minimum tillage, evaporation suppression, and other such techniques are mentioned in the foregoing pages. These and other techniques need improvement, but a considerable body of research work indicates that there is significant potential for their adaptation. Microclimates can be beneficially modified with well designed windbreak systems. The energy balance of the crop may also be artificially altered by the application of special materials such as reflectants. Perhaps most logical and economical, plants may be bred for improved adaptation to the moisture stresses that typify the arid, semiarid, and subhumid environments. Increased reflectance and/or increased pubescence has been shown to improve water use efficiency in the soybean crop.
Chapter 9— Improving Irrigation Systems[*] by Marvin E. Jensen
Abstract The volumes of water diverted and consumed by irrigation are summarized. The effects of changes in conveyance and on-farm distribution systems on water supplies made available to the primary water users are easy to estimate. The net effects of system changes on water supplies are more difficult to ascertain. Two hypothetical projects and various system changes are used to illustrate the net effects of these changes on water availability to agriculture within a river basin. Suggested changes in irrigation efficiency terminology are provided to minimize misuse of irrigation data and misconceptions about the effects of system changes.
In an upstream project, major changes in the conveyance and on-farm systems may have little effect on net water available to agriculture if a high proportion of the excess water returns to the river system. If more land is irrigated with increased water supplies, water consumption is essentially transferred upstream from downstream areas. In a downstream project, near the ocean or a salt sink, large increases in water supply for agriculture can be obtained if return flow systems are made part of the on-farm surface irrigation systems and the irrigated area is enlarged or diversions are reduced. Estimates of increased water supplies for agriculture for the western states indicate that less than four percent more water may be available to agriculture as a result of massive changes in the systems. [*] Developed cooperatively with Agricultural Research Service employees: A.R. Dedrick, D.F. Heermann, T.A. Howell, E.G. Kruse, J.T. Musick and J.A. Replogle.
― 219 ― Water consumption by row crops is not significantly affected by the irrigation method. Simulations of evaporation and transpiration by cotton under various irrigation systems are used to illustrate system effects.
All water diverted from a natural source such as a river or a groundwater aquifer is either consumed (evaporated), stored in a nonrecoverable strata, or returned to the river or groundwater system. Water consumption includes water evaporated from reservoirs, conveyance and return flow channels, during application, and consumptive use by irrigated crops, riparian and phreatophyte vegetation (evapotranspiration). The source of water consumed by phreatophyte vegetation in arid areas may be from distribution system seepage, surface runoff and deep percolation from irrigated lands, and periodic flooding of flood plains. Water retained below the maximum crop rooting depth in previously dry sedimentary materials is not consumed, but is essentially permanently nonrecoverable for later reuse and can be considered as water consumed. An assessment of future water supplies for irrigated agriculture and the ultimate effects on U.S. agricultural production must consider water supplies now being consumed by agriculture. In 1975, the U.S. Water Resources Council estimated total U.S. water withdrawals to be 463 km3 , of which 76 percent came from surface supplies and 24 percent came from groundwater
sources.[1] About 217 km3 were withdrawn for irrigation and 118 km3 (54 percent) were consumed.[*] About 93 percent of the water consumed was by irrigation in the western water resources regions. Wolman estimated that 1,250 km3 of water are consumed by farm crops and pasture, 870 km3 by forest lands and browse vegetation, and 1680 km3 by noneconomic vegetation.[2] I estimated that about 840 km3 of water are consumed on nonirrigated cropland and fallow. Briefly, water consumption by nonirrigated U.S. agriculture is about 10 times that on irrigated land. Assessment of water supplies to sustain or increase U.S. agricultural production must include the effects of potential improvements in water use efficiency on nonirrigated croplands. [*] One cubic kilometer (km ) = 10 m = 810,710 acre-feet.
― 220 ― Improving water conveyance and on-farm water distribution systems can increase our ability to irrigate efficiently and to avoid adverse plant water stresses. Improvements can assure maximum delivery of the water supply available to users, reduce or eliminate consumptive waste along canals and on farms, and reduce energy costs for pumping. Improving farm irrigation systems to provide better and more timely water control can result in direct benefits to individual water users, such as reduced energy costs, higher or better quality crop yields with improved water management, and often less labor. Changes in water conveyance and on-farm distribution may increase the proportion of water diverted or pumped that is made available to the primary users in a project, but these increases may reduce by a like amount the potential amount of water available to downstream users from return flow. Similarly, changes in farm irrigation systems that minimize surface runoff and deep percolation may reduce the potential return flow or storage in nonrecoverable sites. Changes that increase the water supply available to primary users will reduce the water supply available as return flow if the increased water supply is used to irrigate more land within the project. If the seepage or deep percolation water is accumulating in nonrecoverable sites, changes that reduce these losses represent a true net water savings.
Irrigation Efficiency Terminology There are three major common misconceptions about U.S. irrigated agriculture that relate to the engineering aspects of water use: (1) irrigated agriculture wastes 50 percent of the water it uses; (2) by increasing "irrigation efficiency," proportionally more water will be available for
agriculture and other users; and (3) the irrigation method can greatly influence the amount of water consumed in crop production. The first two of these can be clarified by the following two definitions, and a schematic illustration that summarizes the average irrigated agriculture water budget.[3]
Irrigation Efficiency Irrigation efficiency is the ratio of the volume of irrigation water required for beneficial use in the specified irrigated area to the volume of water delivered to this area.
― 221 ―
Net Irrigation Efficiency Net farm or project irrigation efficiency is the ratio of irrigation water consumed by crops on a farm or project to the net depletion of usable water in a river basin or groundwater system. Net depletion is diversion minus return flow.
Use of Irrigation Efficiency Terminology Irrigation efficiency is a term that has a specific meaning to engineers, but it alone cannot be used to evaluate the impacts of changes in irrigation systems and practices on agricultural water supplies. Irrigation efficiency considers only part of the water budget, i.e., crop water consumption as compared with farm delivery or gross diversions. Return flow is not part of this term. Net irrigation efficiency compares crop water consumption with net water depletion. An increase in efficiency means either greater crop water consumption with the same depletion, or a reduction in net depletion, or both. The following efficiency values are obtained when using the data in Figure 9.1:
Project irrigation efficiency
= 90.6/219 = 0.41 or 41 percent.
Farm irrigation efficiency
= 90.6/171 = 0.53 or 53 percent.
Net project irrigation efficiency
= 90.6/(219 – 100) = 0.76 or 76 percent.
In this example, the return flow is 78 percent of the excess diversion (100/(81 + 48) = 0.78). If the project irrigation efficiency was increased from 41 to 82 percent and the same crops were grown, the gross diversion could be reduced to 110.5 km3 . If the return flow percentage remained the same (78 percent), the net depletion would be 90.6 + (1 – 0.78) (19.9) = 95 instead of 119 km3 . Doubling the irrigation efficiency in this example would decrease net depletion by only 20 percent. The major ways to increase "net irrigation efficiency" and available water supplies are: (1) to reduce evaporation from soil and surface reservoirs; (2) to reduce evapotranspiration by lowor nonbeneficial vegetation of farms and flood plains; and (3) to reduce all system losses and reduce waste of usable drainage and operationally spilled water. Greater production per unit of water consumed can be achieved by increasing water use efficiency.
― 222 ―
Figure 9.1 U.S. Irrigation Water Budget in Percent and in km3 /year Source: SCS, 1980.
― 223 ―
Other Effects of System Changes Direct and Indirect Costs and Benefits Major changes in conveyance or on-farm irrigation systems to conserve water will require large capital investments and probably increased annual operating costs. In some cases, lower operation and maintenance costs will offset part of the increased annual capital costs. If the primary water users cannot expand the irrigated land area as a result of system changes, their benefits from improvements may be limited to indirect benefits resulting from better water control. If the purpose of major conveyance and on-farm system changes is to reduce net depletion or salt loading, the primary beneficiaries will be the downstream or secondary water users. Improvements may result in a loss of wet wildlife habitat and benefits, if any, attributable to excess water diversions.
Water Quality All water consumption increases the concentration of salts in the remaining downstream flow. In addition, mineralization occurs as excess water percolates through the soil, and there may be salt loading from saline subsoils. The reduction in salinity damages to downstream water users by upstream system improvements often is used to justify expenditures of public funds.
Increasing Water Supplies to Primary Users Use of on-farm irrigation systems like sprinkler and trickle systems reduces the opportunity for excess water application, or mismanagement. Projectwide conversion to these systems can increase the potential water supply to irrigated agriculture in those cases where the fraction of surface runoff and deep percolation that returns to a reusable supply is small.
Potential Increases in Water Supplies for Agriculture Water flow to and through irrigation projects is a complex process involving many interacting variables. The effect of changes in the water conveyance system on the water supply that can be delivered to the primary water users is easy to measure or
― 224 ― predict. The overall effect of system changes on water available to agriculture is more difficult to determine or predict. Two hypothetical case examples are presented to illustrate the complexity of irrigation projects and systems, and the difficulty of estimating the probable impacts of proposed system changes on available water to agriculture. These cases involve: (1) an upstream project along a major river; and (2) a project near the downstream end of a river basin. Several examples of on-farm system changes and their effects on water use are presented in the next section.
Case A—Upstream Irrigation Project Data for a hypothetical upstream project before and after changes in the system are presented in Table 9.1. The recommended metric volume unit for large volumes of irrigation water is 1000 cubic meters (1000 m3 ) which is one cubic decameter (dam3 ). However, the megaliter unit (ML) is more
convenient for frequent use.[*] The effects of various changes in the system described under cases A1 to A4 are presented in columns 2-5 of Table 9.1.
Case A1 Line the main conveyance canal and install improved water control and delivery structures. ET is assumed to increase five percent per unit area as a result of more timely and uniform irrigations. Water diversion remains constant and the land area irrigated is increased with the additional water delivered to the water users. Surface runoff is reduced from 25 to 20 percent due to better water control.
Case A2 Same as Case A1, except the volume of water diverted is decreased because of reduced conveyance losses and the land area irrigated is held constant. ET is assumed to be five percent greater per unit area as in Case A1.
Case A3 Pump-back return flow (tailwater) systems are installed on each farm. Return flows do not re-enter the distribution system, [*] 1000 cubic meters = 1 dam = 1 ML = 0.8107 acre-foot.
― 225 ―
Table 9.1 Effects of Conveyance and On-Farm System Changes in a Hypothetical Upstream Project Case A
Case A1
Case A2
Case A3
Case A4
Item
Original Project
Line Canal & & Improve Structures
Same as A1, but Reduce Diversion
Add Return Flow Systems
A2 & A3 A2 & A3 Combined
Project Data:
(1)
(2)
(3)
(4)
(5)
Irrigated area, hectares
10,000
12,535
10,000
10,000
10,000
Evapotranspiration, mm
700
735
735
735
735
Effective precipitation, mm
100
100
100
100
100
Net irrig. requirement, mm
600
635
635
635
635
Irrigation method
B/F
B/F
B/F
B/F
B/F
Surface runoff, fraction
0.25
0.20
0.20
0.05
0.05
Deep percolation, fraction
.15
.15
.15
.15
.15
Main canal
Unlined
Lined
Lined
Unlined
Lined
Project Water Volumes, ML: Diversion
125,000
125,000
99,700
99,250
81,000
Canal seepage (20% & 2%)
25,000
2,500
2,000
19,850
1,600
Farm delivery
100,000
122,500
97,700
79,400
79,400
79,600
63,500
63,500
63,500
Irrigation ET (A x Inet 60,000 ) Surface runoff (25, 20 & 5%)
25,000
24,500
19,500
4,000
4,000
Deep percolation (15%)
15,000
18,400
14,700
11,900
11,900
― 226 ―
Case A
Case A1
Case A2
Case A3
Case A4
From canal seepage (90%)
22,500
2,250
1,800
17,900
1,400
From surface runoff (80%)
20,000
19,600
15,600
3,200
3,200
From deep percolation (95%)
14,250
17,500
14,000
11,300
11,300
Total
56,750
39,350
31,400
32,400
15,900
Volume, ML
68,250
85,650
68,300
66,850
65,100
Percent of Case A
100
125
100
98
95
Conveyance efficiency
0.80
0.98
0.98
0.80
0.98
Unit (farm)efficiency
.60
.65
.65
.80
.80
Return flow recovery1
.87
.87
.87
.91
.91
Project irrigation efficiency2
.48
.64
.64
.64
.78
Net project irrig. efficiency3
.88
.93
.93
.95
.98
116,200
118,740
122,200
Return Flows, ML:
Net Water Depletion:
Calculated Values, Fractions:
Water Available for Agriculture: Volume, ML4
109,940
116,200
Percent of Case A
100
106
106
108
111
1
Ratio of total return flow to the sum of canal seepage, surface runoff, and deep percolation. 2
Ratio of irrigation ET to diversion.
3
Ratio of irrigation ET to net water depletion.
4
Irrigation ET plus (return flow plus Case A minus Ax diversion) x net project irrigation efficiency.
― 227 ― reducing farm surface runoff to five percent. ET is increased five percent as in Case A1, the land area irrigated is held constant as in Case A2, and the diversion is reduced as needed, but the canal is not lined.
Case A4 Case A2 and A3 combined. Assumptions Assumptions required are that the project-wide return flow fractions for canal seepage, surface runoff, and deep percolation are 0.9, 0.8, and 0.95, respectively. If smaller values were used, the net effects would be different, but the general results would be similar. Results The calculated relative changes in water available for agriculture were based on the following ratio expressed in percent.
In the above ratio, Enet in the numerator is the value for case Ax, while in the denominator, it is the value for Case A. For Case A1, six percent more water would be available for ET mainly because ET was increased five percent. The upstream net water depletion would be 25 percent greater. Thus, lining the canal to reduce seepage, and expanding the irrigated area using the increased water supply, would essentially shift agricultural production from downstream areas to upstream areas. In Case A2, net depletion of water would remain about the same as in Case A, and water available to agriculture would be six percent greater than in Case A. In Case A4, water available to agriculture in this project would be 11 percent greater than in Case A, and net depletion in the upstream project would decrease five percent. Basically, major changes would have little effect on water supplies for agriculture, but could shift the area of water use. If the return flow fractions were much smaller, i.e., 0.8, 0.6, and 0.8, for canal seepage, surface runoff, and deep percolation, respectively, then the increases in water available to agriculture by system improvements would be larger. Net depletion for Case A would be 78,000 ML instead of 68,250 ML, and water available to agriculture would be 96,200 instead of 109,940 ML. For Case A4 (lining the canal and decreasing surface runoff), net depletion would decrease to 67,800 ML from 96,200 ML, and the water available to agriculture would be 117,300 ML or 22 percent greater than for Case A.
― 228 ―
Case B—Downstream Irrigation Project Data for a hypothetical irrigation project near the mouth of a river or inland sink are presented to illustrate important differences in options available to increase available water to agriculture between upstream and downstream projects (Table 9.2). Basically, it is more difficult and may be more expensive to capture and reuse return flow from a downstream project, i.e., surface return flow from the project enters the ocean or a salt sink instead of the river system or groundwater. Return flow must be reduced by expanding the irrigated area, or reducing diversions to increase upstream water supplies to agriculture, or both. Data from a recent study of the Imperial Irrigation District in California were used to approximate the current status and the effects of various changes in the conveyance and irrigation system.[4]
Case B1 Line more lateral canals and expand seepage recovery lines under the main canal. Estimated recovery is about 38 percent of 96,000 ML seepage from main canals and a 90 percent reduction in the 151,000 ML of seepage from lateral canals. The resulting seepage loss is 74,000 ML instead of 247,000
ML. Farm deliveries remain constant. Water salvaged from main canal seepage and lining was assumed to be used to irrigate more land in the district at the same unit efficiency.
Case B2 Tailwater recovery systems installed on farms where surface runoff cannot be recovered in the lateral systems, to reduce project surface runoff from 22 to 5 percent. Farm deliveries are reduced to offset reduction in surface runoff. Water salvaged is used to irrigate more land in the district at the new unit efficiency.
Case B3 Changes in B1 and B2 combined. Water salvaged is used to irrigate more land in the district at the new unit farm efficiency.
Case B4 Case B2 and B3 combined and diversion reduced. Reclaimed seepage returned to the canal-lateral system. Reduction in diversion would be available to irrigate more new land outside the district.
― 229 ―
Table 9.2 Effects of Conveyance and On-Farm System Changes on a Hypothetical Downstream Project Similar to the Imperial Irrigation District
Item
Case B
Case B1
Case B2
Case B3
C
Current Status
Line More Laterals & Recover Seepage
Tailwater Reuse Systems Installed
B1 & B2 Combined Same Diversion
B C D R
(1)
(2)
(3)
(4)
(
185,000
195,000
227,000
240,000
1
Project Data:
Irrigated area, hectares
Crop evapotranspiration, mm
1,145
1,145
1,145
1,145
1
Effective precipitation, mm 35
35
35
35
3
Net ET irrig. requirement, mm
1,110
1,110
1,110
1,110
1
Leaching requirement (15% of ET), mm
170
170
170
170
1
Surface runoff, fraction
0.22
0.22
0.05
0.05
0
Deep percolation, fraction
.10
.10
.12
.12
.1
End of farm lateral spills, fraction
0.024
.024
.024
.024
.0
Main canals and laterals
42% lined 71% lined
42% lined
71% lined
7
(2830 km)
(1180 km)
(2012 km)
(1180 km)
(2012 km)
(
Diversion (at Pilot Knob)
3,376,000 3,376,000
3,376,000
3,376,000
2
Canal and lateral seepage
247,000
247,000
74,000
7
Farm delivery
3,129,000 3,302,000
3,129,000
3,302,000
2
Irrigation ET
2,052,000 2,165,000
2,522,000
2,661,000
2
Spills (2.4% of farm delivery)
75,000
79,000
75,000
79,000
6
Surface runoff (22 & 5%)
688,000
726,000
156,000
165,000
1
Deep percolation (10% or 12%)
313,000
330,000
375,000
396,000
3
Project Water Volumes, ML:
74,000
Return Flow to Salton Sea, ML:
From canal seepage (50%) 124,000
37,000
123,000
37,000
3
From farms (spills, R.O. & D.P.)
1,076,000 1,135,000
606,000
640,000
4
Total
1,200,000 1,172,000
729,000
677,000
5
― 230 ―
Case B
Case B1
Case B2
Case B3
C
Item
Current Status
Line More Laterals & Recover Seepage
Tailwater Reuse Systems Installed
B1 & B2 Combined Same Diversion
B C D R
Project Data:
(1)
(2)
(3)
(4)
(5
0
37,000
0
37,000
37
From surface runoff from 0 project
0
0
0
0
Deep percolation from project1
0
0
0
0
0
Total
0
37,000
0
37,000
37
Return Flow Used for Agri., ML:
From canal & lateral seepage
Net Water Depletion:
Volume, ML2
3,376,000 3,376,000
3,376,000
3,376,000
2,
Percent of Case B
100
100
100
100
78
Net conveyance efficiency 0.93
0.98
0.93
0.98
0.
Unit (farm) efficiency3
.66
.66
.81
.81
.8
Unit (district) effic. (ET & LR)4 .75
.75
.93
.93
.9
0
.03
0
.05
.0
District irrigation efficiency5
.61
.64
.75
.79
.7
Net district irrigation efficiency6
.61
.64
.75
.79
.7
Calculated Values, Fractions:
Return flow recovery (RF/(Div.-ET))
Water Available to Agriculture:
Volume, ML
2,052,000 2,165,000
2,522,000
2,661,000
2,
Percent of Case B
100
123
130
12
106
1
Deep percolation assumed to be unsuitable for reuse for agriculture because of salin
2
Since flow to Salton Sea is no longer usable for agriculture, total diversion is deplet
3
Ratio of irrigation ET to water delivered to farms.
4
Ratio of ET and leaching requirement of 15% of ET to water delivered to farms.
5
Ratio of irigation ET to water diversion.
6
Ratio of irrigation ET to net water depletion.
― 231 ― Assumptions Deep percolation was kept at approximately 15 percent of ET to control salinity (leaching fraction). As the surface runoff fraction was reduced, new land was assumed to be irrigated at the same new unit efficiency without increasing total main canal seepage. If the diversion was reduced, new land was assumed to be available elsewhere in the region for agriculture to use the water. Results If more laterals were lined and seepage under main canals was recovered, then six percent more land could be irrigated, increasing the net irrigation efficiency from 61 to 64 percent. The present cost (July 1981) of water delivered to the farmer is $6.08/ML ($7.50/acre-foot). The estimated cost of lining the canals was $25/ML of reduced seepage ($31/acre-foot). The estimated cost of the seepage recovery system was $11/ML of water recovered ($14/acre-foot). The largest increase in water that could be made available to agriculture would be by installing on-farm tailwater recovery systems to reduce surface runoff from about 22 to 5 percent. The cost of tailwater recovery systems was estimated to range from $6.50 to $20/ML of water recovered ($8 to $25/acre-foot). The above example shows that if water supplies are limited, about 600,000 ML (490,000 acre-feet) of water could be made available for expanded irrigated agriculture in the region. The California Department of Water Resources estimated 541,000 ML could be saved.[5] I did not attempt to include reductions in water spills. The estimated cost of project reservoirs to accomplish reductions in water spills was $28/ML ($34/acre-foot) of water saved. The important difference between a downstream project like this and an upstream project is that additional land must be irrigated within the project or upstream from the diversion to use additional water that would become available to agriculture as a result of changes in the project system.
Potential Increases in Water Available to Agriculture Estimates of potential reduced diversions and the resulting increases in water supplies in the 17 western states made by an Interagency Task Force showed that if all of the measures identified in a USDA Soil Conservation Service study were implemented under a 25-year accelerated program, average conveyance efficiency could be increased 10 percent and average on-farm efficiency 13 percent.[6] With no increase in irrigated area and
― 232 ― providing water to water-short areas, return flows could be reduced by 43.5 km3 (35.3 million acre-feet) and net depletion reduced by 4.1 km3 (3.3 million acre-feet). Diversions would be reduced by 47.6 km3 (38.6 million acre-feet), but only the 4.1 km3 (3.3 million acre-feet) would be available for additional agricultural or other consumptive uses. The estimated onetime capital cost of the entire program in 1977 dollars was $14.6 billion or $3.56/m3 of additional water made available. The cost of parts of the program would be less per unit of water than the total cost for all projects.
Effects of Changes in On-Farm Irrigation Systems Basically, the irrigation system has little effect on water consumption by most farm crops that are fully irrigated. An exception is the use of trickle irrigation systems to establish orchards, citrus groves, and vineyards, because of reduced evaporation when the trees or vines are small. The major water conserving benefits from system changes occur when most or all of the surface runoff or deep percolation does not return to the river or groundwater aquifer. Changes in irrigation systems can reduce surface runoff and deep percolation (Table 9.3). In the Texas High Plains, an evaluation of the volume of water pumped from the groundwater and from return flow systems on several farms showed that 14 to 23 percent of the water pumped from the aquifer was repumped with the return flow system.[7] This water would have been lost by evaporation without the return flow system. There essentially is no deep percolation on the Pullman soil. Runoff from furrow irrigation on this soil ranges from 25 to 35 percent. About 20 percent of the water applied on the Olton soil was estimated to be deep percolation that probably would not reach the groundwater because subsoils are dry. When farmers convert from furrow irrigation to center pivot
irrigation, they generally pump about 20 percent less water with little difference in yields. However, during a dry year like 1980, sprinkler-irrigated crop yields were lower because well yields were limited. In 1981, surface runoff averaged 32 percent and deep percolation averaged 13.5 percent, resulting in a water application efficiency of 54.5 percent on a surface-irrigated demonstration farm near Greeley, Colorado.[8] The recently leveled fields were 425 to 540 m in length and had a slope of 0.6 percent. The soils were in a SCS intake family of 7.6 to 13 mm/h (0.3 to 0.5 in/h). In 1974, prior to leveling and with 185-m long furrows, the average
― 233 ―
Table 9.3 Return Flows used on Sample Texas High Plains Farms Volume Pumped, ML From Wells
Reuse Systems
Percent Reused
Farm/Soil Type
Year
Pullman clay loam
1980
296
41
14
1981
318
58
18
Olton clay loam
1980
358
72
20
Acuff loam
1980
1037
239
23
Source: J.T. Musick, ARS-USDA, Bushland, Texas, personal communication.
application efficiency was 46 percent with surface runoff being 40 percent.
With level basin surface irrigation, there is no runoff and the amount of deep percolation is dependent on the control of the volume of water applied and on the timing of irrigations. Dedrick[9] observed the data in Table 9.4 in a level basin study in Arizona. With most irrigation systems, management can have a major effect on water application or irrigation efficiencies. For example, Heermann[10] showed that the average depth of water applied on a 405-hectare nonscheduled, farmer-managed area was one-third more than on an adjacent 648-hectare area of corn on which irrigations were scheduled with a computer program. Both areas were on sandy soils and irrigated with center pivot sprinkler systems. One of the scheduled center pivot fields had the highest corn yield for the state. In this case, because of the sandy soil near the South Platte River, most of the excess water applied returns to the river system. T.A. Howell[11] evaluated water consumption by simulating cotton water use when irrigated with trickle, sprinkler, and furrow irrigation methods near Fresno, California. Using experimental data, he used a calibrated water balance model and 1981 weather data to evaluate the potential reduction in ET by simulating the use of different irrigation methods. All cases were assumed to be
― 234 ―
Table 9.4 Irrigation Management and Efficiency, Level Basin Surface Irrigation
Crop
Field No. of Size, ha Irrig.
Cotton
15.3
Alfalfa
72.0
Winter wheat
56.9
a
9a 15
Depth Applied, mm
Est. Cu, mm
1220
1050
86
1790
1890
100b
955
660
69
7a
Includes a preplant irrigation.
Irrigation Efficiency, %
b
Some extraction of stored soil water by alfalfa may have occurred, or the ET estimate may be too low. Source: A.R. Dedrick, ARS-USDA, Phoenix, Arizona, personal communication.
irrigated and would produce about the same yields of cotton on a clay loam soil. The six cases simulated were: (A) sprinkler irrigated, 100 mm applied at 10-day intervals; (B) furrow irrigated, 150 mm at 20-day intervals; (C) trickle irrigated, 30 mm at 3-day intervals and medium soil evaporation; (D) trickle irrigated, 10 mm daily applications and medium soil evaporation; (E) trickle irrigated, 10 mm daily applications and low soil evaporation (buried lines or irrigating alternate rows); and (F) trickle irrigated, 10 mm daily application and high soil evaporation (closely spaced lines). The water application efficiency was 80 percent for sprinkler irrigation, 85 percent for furrow irrigation, and 92 percent for trickle irrigation. Irrigations began when 150 mm had been depleted on all treatments. Irrigations were terminated 125 days after starting to irrigate in all cases except for the furrow case in which irrigation was terminated 110 days after starting. All simulations ended 150 days after starting to irrigate. The soil was assumed to hold 450 mm of available water. All treatments received a 300-mm preplant irrigation. The simulation results, expressed in mm, and the relative total ET compared with Case A are shown in Table 9.5. The average ET for the sprinkler and furrow cases is 772 mm (30.4 inches). The ET for the trickle irrigated cases ranged from 2 to 9 percent
― 235 ―
Table 9.5 Evapotranspiration with Various Irrigation Methods Water Applied
Evapotranspiration
Case
Seasonal
Total
Evaporation
Transpiration
Total
Relative ET
A
625
925
156
629
785
100
B
529
829
145
614
759
97
C
457
757
94
621
715
91
D
446
746
96
616
712
91
E
391
691
43
616
659
84
F
500
800
159
612
771
98
less, except for the low evaporation case (E) which was 16 percent less than the ET for the sprinkler case. The reductions ranged from 6 to 13 percent when compared with the furrow irrigated case. Howell indicated that lysimeter measurements of total ET by tomatoes which were trickle irrigated (daily) and furrow irrigated (each 10 days) made at Davis, California, by W.O. Pruitt were nearly the same (560 mm), which supports these simulated values. These results clearly show that water consumption by trickle irrigated row crops is not much different from row crops irrigated with furrow or sprinkler methods. A five-year study of trickle irrigated cotton in New Mexico using water of medium salinity (1200 ppm) showed that trickle irrigated plots yielded six percent more lint cotton of comparable lint quality with 25 percent less water applied than that applied on the surface irrigated plots. However, the soil salinity increased from 25 to 100 percent in the 30- to 130-cm depth on the trickle irrigated plots.[12]
Discussion of Chapters 8 and 9: Marshall J. English The technological possibilities for maintaining agriculture with less water have been summarized well in these two chapters. It is left to me to provide emphasis and additional perspective where I can, and to raise one additional topic. As Dr. Jensen has pointed out, irrigation diversions could be reduced substantially in some areas by increasing conveyance and application efficiencies, but most of the water wasted by inefficiencies would eventually be returned to a river or aquifer anyway as percolation or runoff. So the ultimate water savings associated with improved irrigation practices would be the result of: · reduced transpiration by wild plants, such as vegetation along canals and drainage ditches, and evaporation from ponded water; · reduced evaporation from soil surfaces during the early stages of crop development by improved management or drip irrigation;
· prevention of runoff or percolation into the ocean, saline sinks, or other bodies of water where the water is rendered unusable.
― 237 ― Dr. Jensen indicated that these savings could amount to a modest fraction of total diversions in the western states. The capital costs to accomplish these savings might be high for the amount of water saved, but these costs could be offset to some extent by reduced energy costs, reduced capital costs for pumps and wells, and by the opportunity costs associated with the water saved. I would like to add additional perspective concerning the third item of the list. The third item, in its broadest sense, may include return flows that are partially degraded by salts leached from soils or subsoils. These saline return flows can adversely affect downstream crop production. Structural or irrigation system improvements which reduce percolation may reduce downstream salinity. While this may not increase the water supply per se it can enhance the productivity of the water, which amounts to the same thing. Reducing percolation is a significant conservation technique in a few locales where the salinity derived from percolating water, leaking canals, etc., is substantial. Examples include the Roaring Fork and Grand Valleys of Colorado where project irrigation efficiencies are low and the subsoils are highly soluble marine evaporites. I would also like to add one item to the list of possibilities for saving water. This fourth item would be reduced transpiration by crops. Most of the water consumed by irrigated agriculture is lost to the atmosphere through transpiration. Unfortunately, if crop transpiration is reduced, yields will also be reduced; the two are inextricably linked. Nevertheless, a reduction in transpiration might be economically feasible under some circumstances. This idea is based on the relationships shown in Figure 9.2. The dashed line represents the relationship between transpiration and yield. The solid line shows the relationship between total water use and yield. The horizontal distance between the two curves is the water wasted as runoff, percolation, or unproductive evapotranspiration. A combination of high irrigation uniformity and careful irrigation management can narrow the gap between the two curves, though some gap will always remain. The highest levels of transpiration (and crop yields) are achieved when soil moisture levels are kept uniformly high throughout the field. But maintaining uniformly high soil moisture levels requires frequent irrigation. It also requires that excess water be applied to compensate for the nonuniformity of applications and the inhomogeneity of the soil. Excess applications insure that those parts of the field receiving the least water
― 238 ―
Figure 9.2 Relationship between Water Use and Crop Yield will be fully irrigated. Because of these practices, irrigation tends to become less efficient as higher levels of transpiration are reached, which is why the water-use line diverges from the transpiration line. As efficiency decreases, irrigation becomes more costly and more energy intensive, and so the marginal costs of production tend to increase as we approach maximum yield. Now consider the consequences of under-irrigating the crop by a small amount. If we arbitrarily decide to reduce transpiration by, say 10 percent, we will sacrifice perhaps 10% of potential yields. But it then becomes possible to irrigate less frequently and to reduce the excess applications. The consequent reductions in energy, capital, labor, maintenance, and other production costs may be greater than the reduction in gross income, in which case net income will increase. This is a straightforward application of a fundamental principle of economics; we want to reduce the
― 239 ― level of production until the marginal cost of production just equals the value of the marginal product. Profit is maximized at that point. English and Nuss (1982) did a hypothetical case study of this concept by designing an irrigation system explicitly to under-irrigate a wheat field in eastern
Oregon.[1] For the particular circumstances which they considered, a 24 percent reduction in evapotranspiration was possible without any reduction in net income. The yield reduction associated with deficit irrigation would be offset by increased production if the water saved were used to irrigate additional land. Furthermore, if the newly irrigated land includes land that is not already being farmed, more natural precipitation will be captured, which will increase the effective water supply. This approach to irrigation offers a way to compensate for reduced water supplies, but it involves theoretical and practical questions that have not yet been fully explored. Researchers have been actively examining these questions, and Rosenberg was referring to one aspect of that research when he talked about irrigating at critical stages of growth. However, it should be noted that deficit irrigation is not fundamentally a radical departure from normal irrigation practice. In fact most fields are under-irrigated to some extent. SCS guidelines are commonly used in specifying irrigation system performance. These guidelines are based on an 87.5 percent adequacy, meaning that 87.5 percent of the field will be fully irrigated. Thus ordinary irrigation practices following SCS guidelines allow a degree of deficit irrigation already. To my knowledge, the possible economic benefits of this approach to irrigation have not been systematically analyzed for working farms, although various theoretical analyses have been carried out. It is difficult therefore to estimate the returns that might be realized by this approach. My impressions at this point are: · Where irrigation costs are moderate, irrigation systems are already in place, and water supplies are not limiting, this approach to irrigation offers only slight economic advantage. · Where total irrigation operations costs are high or where a new irrigation system is to be built, profits may be moderately increased by this approach.
― 240 ― · Where water supplies are limiting and the water saved by this technique can be used to put additional land into production, profits may be increased significantly. Note that this situation may also result in an actual increase in water supply, as discussed earlier. The discussion up to this point has introduced an economic perspective. We have been asked to discuss the technical aspects of maintaining agricultural
productivity with less water, but we are implicitly concerned with maintaining the profitability of the agricultural industry. The techniques that have been described in this volume can add to the usable water supply. But some of them will also reduce production costs and by doing so will further compensate for limited water supplies. For example, water harvesting and snow management were discussed in terms of their potential for conserving water, but these techniques can also reduce irrigation costs, and thereby increase profitability. Finally, there are one or two points that I would like to raise concerning Rosenberg's discussion of water harvesting and snow management. We should keep in mind that when water is trapped on an upstream farm by these techniques, it may mean less water available for downstream users. It makes economic sense to trap the water where it falls rather than to pump it for use somewhere else. Nevertheless, this technique may only shift a portion of the water supply from one region to another, rather than increase the supply. It should also be kept in mind that water harvesting will not be effective unless the soil is sufficiently deep to store the water. There are areas where precipitation exceeds the storage capacity of the soil, and erosion is continuing to reduce soil depths in much of the country; the Palouse region of the Northwest is a good example. In the long run, this continuing soil loss may limit the effectiveness of water harvesting and force us to use irrigation as a substitute for dryland agriculture. Erosion control is therefore relevant to the problem of dealing with reduced water supplies. Water harvesting can contribute significantly to erosion control by reducing surface runoff.
Discussion of Chapters 8 and 9: Wilford R. Gardner In their respective chapters, Rosenberg and Jensen have given excellent reviews of the prospects for maintaining present crop yields with less water through improved engineering practices and through crop adaptation. What I should like to consider in these brief comments are a few factors which will determine which agronomic and engineering practices will actually be adopted, and the information that must yet be developed if dramatic water savings are to be realized. First, it must be accepted that plant transpiration is a mandatory cost which the plant must pay as a consequence of the physical pathway which permits CO2 to be taken up for photosynthesis. Rosenberg described a number of approaches to reduction of water loss during CO2 uptake, but thus far most of these are only interesting concepts which have not resulted in encouraging reductions in water use. Except for very modest differences between plant species, the amount of dry matter produced per unit water transpired depends upon the saturation deficit of the atmosphere and the metabolic pathway (C3 , C4 or CAM). Improvements in water use efficiency
in the near term will come mainly from increasing the harvest index, i.e., increasing the fraction of the plant that is of economic value to the farmer. This will be achieved through a combination of plant breeding and better management of plant population. Plants which are less sensitive to brief periods of water stress can be more readily managed under water-limiting conditions than sensitive plants, even though their inherent water use efficiencies may be virtually identical. Plant breeders have already made tremendous progress in developing plants that produce more grain with less vegetation, though the limit to this process does not yet seem to have been reached. However, producing more dry matter with the same amount of transpired water, or the same dry matter with less water, does not offer immediate prospects for large savings in water. Even the so-called lowwater-using plants must transpire, and offer advantages over sensitive plants mainly in that they are more forgiving of water stress, whether planned or inadvertent. The major gains in water use efficiency will come through reduction in evaporation from the soil surface and from reduction in runoff and percolation losses. Reduction of losses from the delivery system itself is a matter of straightforward engineering and economics. Jensen gives a good discussion of this aspect.
― 242 ― Tailwater recovery systems are also quite straightforward and readily evaluated. Reduction of percolation and evaporation losses is more difficult. Only two approaches give any real promise for reducing evaporation losses. If the fraction of the soil surface wetted can be reduced, or the number of times that it is wetted reduced, savings can be affected. Drip irrigation and alternate furrow irrigation both achieve some reduction in evaporation, though these measures are of value only under irrigated conditions and are of no assistance under rainfall conditions. A second solution is a surface mulch of some sort. Dust mulches and mulches of crop residue have proven to be of very limited value in reducing surface evaporation. An impervious mulch, such as a plastic covering, offers significant savings. Only in a very limited number of cases has this proved economically attractive. The cost/benefit ratio must change significantly before this measure will be adopted for other than very high value crops. Narrower row spacing, resulting in earlier closure of the crop canopy, tends to reduce surface evaporation, though this practice must be considered in the context of the other consequences of high plant population. The greatest opportunity for reduction in crop water use on the farm is in the reduction of deep percolation. This will be achieved simply by applying less water during an irrigation. How much reduction in yield will accompany that reduction in water application is a matter of how uniformly the water is
applied. Existing techniques for water application often result in very nonuniform distribution of water, with parts of many fields getting as much as twice the needed water. This is especially true of furrow irrigation. Even when the land is laser-leveled, it is virtually impossible to achieve a uniform distribution of water from one end of the field to the other. Variable soil properties combine with the variations inherent in the irrigation technique to ensure this result. Greater uniformity can be achieved by a number of techniques. Space does not permit a review of them here, but the most dramatic results are achieved through drip irrigation systems, which, when designed properly, assure almost negligible variability. The problem facing the farmer in achieving uniformly efficient irrigation is not so much a technical problem as an economic problem. We know that sprinkler irrigation, laser-leveling, drip irrigation, and other engineering measures increase water application efficiency. We know the value of any water saved by these
― 243 ― practices. What we lack, unfortunately, is adequate information on the potential reductions in water use and potential increases in yields for a particular situation. Because of the variability of soils and other site-specific factors, it is very difficult to make a cost/benefit analysis for any given farm. The cost of laser-leveling is sufficiently modest that a farmer can undertake it on speculation. Sprinkler irrigation systems are costly, and drip irrigation systems even more so, and the benefits are difficult to quantify. Small scale irrigation experiments on research farms are of some help, but the results cannot be reliably scaled up to field-size operations, nor can the results from one soil necessarily be transferred to another soil. It has been estimated that it takes at least 1800 individual measurements to obtain a good quantitative assessment of the permeability of a field. Few farmers have even a single permeability measurement upon which to base a design, let alone an understanding of the variability of each field. Future improvements in water use efficiency on the farm will come largely from irrigation management practices more closely tailored to the local situation. No longer will maximum yield per unit of land be the major criterion of merit. The yield per unit of water will also be important. This means that instead of managing a farm or a field according to its average properties, smaller units will have to be irrigated according to their properties. While we have measuring techniques which permit us to obtain the necessary information in the field, they are not now sufficiently simple and inexpensive that they lend themselves to routine application. There is a serious gap between what is known about irrigation efficiency and common irrigation practices. A final point seems worth making. Much present irrigation practice is
predicated upon the assumption that "beneficial use" of water justifies the amount applied. If using more water results in more yield, more water is used. As water becomes limited, the law of diminishing returns should be reinstated and optimum water use rather than maximum yields should become the goal. While there are many who now espouse this philosophy, it has not been so widely adopted as economic and social forces will come to dictate.
― 244 ―
PART III— IMPACTS OF LESS WATER FOR IRRIGATED AGRICULTURE Chapter 10— Local and Regional Economic Impacts by Robert A. Young [*]
Abstract The water economy of the western U.S. is moving from the "expansionary phase" (where new supplies are readily available) to the "mature phase" (where costs of new supplies are rapidly escalating and water users are increasingly interdependent). At some point, the incremental cost of new water exceeds the economic value foregone in some of the existing uses. Irrigation accounts for 85-90 percent of water used in each of the western states, and competition for irrigation water from growth in both off-stream and instream uses is increasingly evident. However, a reasonable scenario for urban water demand growth will bring about only a 10 or 20 percent reduction of agricultural supplies in the next two decades. The task of this chapter is to assess the direct and indirect economic impacts of potential transfers of water from agriculture to alternative uses. The conventional wisdom regarding the role of irrigation in the West holds that irrigation has been an important source of regional growth and, conversely, that removing water from agriculture would have significant negative economic effects. This chapter argues the case for the contrary hypothesis. The general approach is to compare the potential reductions in net farm income and regional farm-related income and employment with the gains in those sectors which receive reallocated water supplies.
Direct economic impacts to the agricultural sector, measured by net economic value foregone, will, in the final analysis, be registered on the products in which value productivity is lowest. In those sectors (generally in forage, and food and feed grain production), the net economic value foregone for a 10 to 20 percent supply reduction will mostly fall in the range of $5-$30 per acre-foot. The gain in net value of product or in willingness to pay in households and industries are seen to be five to ten or more times as high. [*] Support for research underlying this paper was provided by the Natural Resource Economics Division, Economic Research Service, U.S. Department of Agriculture, and by the Colorado State University Experiment Station. Richard Gardner and Marie Livingston provided helpful comments on an earlier draft.
― 245 ― Indirect impacts are measured by income from primary regional resources ("value added") and by employment per unit of water, including multiplier effects. The evidence indicates that the indirect losses associated with transferring water from agriculture, while not insignificant in terms of either income flows or employment, will also be dwarfed by the gains in nonagricultural sectors. In particular, the sectors most likely to be affected (forage, and food and feed grains) yield relatively small indirect employment and income effects when compared to those for emerging urban sectors. The economic interests of farmers whose water is transferred to urban uses are generally protected by state water and property rights laws. It is anticipated that the rate of loss of irrigation water will be relatively slow (a few percent per year), so that indirectly affected workers and businessmen have time to anticipate and adjust. These problems are the natural consequences of the process of economic growth and change, and are similar to those felt in other sectors of the changing economy. Little need is seen for special public policies to deal with these changes.
A premise of this volume is that the water economy of the western United States is passing from the "expansionary" phase to the "mature" phase. In the expansionary era, the incremental cost of water remained relatively constant over time (in real terms), as water development project sites were available to meet growing demands. The mature phase, brought on by change in the economy at large, is characterized by rapidly rising incremental costs and greatly increased interdependencies among water uses and users.[1]
In a maturing water economy, the high cost of new water brings about a search for supplies from existing uses whose economic productivity is less than the cost of acquiring new supplies. The largest use of water in the western U.S. is for crop irrigation. Thus, competition for irrigation water is arising from industrial, energy, and household water diversions, and from instream uses such as power generation, recreation, fish and wildlife habitat, and navigation. This chapter assesses the economic impacts of increased competition for irrigation water on farmers and other direct water users, and on the local and regional economies intertwined with the water using sectors. A second task is to consider the policy changes needed to deal with anticipated impacts.
― 246 ―
Economic Impacts: Alternative Perspectives Two competing hypotheses or viewpoints can be identified regarding the economic impacts of reduced water supplies for irrigation.
The "Significant Impact" Hypothesis One viewpoint, which appears to reflect the conventional wisdom in political and media discussions of the "western water problem", contends that irrigation has been a significant source of regional growth in the West. Supporters of this perspective point to the sharply increased crop sales brought about by irrigation, and claim substantial multiplier effects in jobs and spending in the related communities and regional economies. From the "significant impact" hypothesis follows its converse: removing water from the agricultural sector will have major, even intolerable, negative effects on the regional economy. The significant impact hypothesis draws its evidence from several sources. One is our historic sense of the role of irrigation in developing the West. Another is the obvious fact that irrigated lands yield enormously more product than semidesert, or wheat-fallow rotations. Also supporting this view is the relatively high income and employment associated with fresh vegetable and fruit crops in areas with milder climates.
The "Limited Impact" Hypothesis The alternative hypothesis conceptualizes the problem in what economists
would call "marginalist" terms. This viewpoint, invoking the law of diminishing marginal returns, posits that the productivity of irrigation water ranges from highly productive down to marginally productive uses. Similarly, the indirect regional employment and income impacts range from significant in some sectors to minimal in others. The marginalist position contends that water removed from irrigation will, in the long run, be the least valuable portion. Even if the first-round impact is at the expense of high-valued irrigation uses, subsequent economic adjustments will find the low productivity uses giving way. The limited impact hypothesis finds evidence for its viewpoint in the large proportion of water diversions in the West which are devoted to irrigation (80-90 percent), and the high proportion of irrigation water use which is in relatively low-valued uses
― 247 ― (forages, and food and feed grains). Proponents focus on the low absolute amounts of indirect income and employment in the processing and input supply sectors associated with most agricultural water use. This approach asks how much water from agriculture will be needed to fuel expected nonagricultural growth and tries to measure the incremental costs of such reallocations, compared with the costs of new water supplies.[2] The evidence, I believe, strongly supports the "limited impact" hypothesis. This chapter presents the case for that viewpoint.
Procedures and Scenario for Impact Assessment The general approach taken here is to compare the economic impacts of potential reallocation of water from irrigation to other direct uses of water. Indirect impacts of removal of irrigation water are similarly compared to indirect effects in growing sectors which might acquire water. The net value foregone (or gained) is taken to be the most suitable measure of direct economic impact. Payments to primary factors of production (value added) and employment are the chosen measures of indirect impacts. The assumptions of the analysis are as follows. The planning horizon is taken to be the remainder of the century. The economic impacts presented below will be expressed in 1982 price levels. As the economic background, there will be no general wars or political upheavals which disrupt world production and trade in agricultural commodities, and agricultural commodity prices will continue the trend which has been observed through most of this century, with technology holding food prices down relative to the cost of production inputs and to real consumer incomes. Hence, current price and production relationships will be used in predicting future agricultural net income.
It seems unlikely that water diversion requirements in nonagricultural sectors will grow so rapidly as to require any enormous reduction in water supplies to agriculture. (For example, a 2.5 percent compounded rate of growth in nonagricultural water demands in California would absorb only another 4 million acre-feet after twenty years, or about 10 percent of current agricultural water use in that state.) The analysis below posits at most a 20 percent reduction in irrigation water supply, which I regard as an extreme outside limit of impact in the next two decades.
― 248 ―
Direct Impact Measurement Economic value has been a principal indicator of general value in our society. In a market economy, economic values are measured by market prices. When the market is working well, the price system measures the value that goods or services provide to people and the value of resources used in production. Direct economic impacts of water reallocation should be measured by the price of the commodity (or by a surrogate price when markets are not operative), since the price measures the net value foregone or gained in the respective use categories. For various reasons, market prices are not generally available for water. The physical barriers to markets for water stem from its flowing, mobile characteristics, which make it difficult to establish and enforce the property rights which are the essential foundation for any market system. Also, in certain uses, water is a public rather than a private good, in that one individual's consumption does not preclude use by others. Finally, water plays a special role in human society. Boulding[3] has pointed out that "the sacredness of water as a symbol of ritual purity exempts it in some degree from the dirty rationality of the market." However, it is possible to estimate the net benefits conferred by water even in the absence of markets. This process is sometimes termed "shadow pricing." Shadow pricing can be understood as an attempt to establish an exchange ratio in monetary terms which would be equivalent to that which would emerge from a properly functioning market process. The basic concept is willingness to pay as the indicator of economic value. Willingness to pay (WTP) reflects the amount which a rational, fully informed consumer would be willing to forego rather than do without the commodity in question. In accordance with the principles of diminishing marginal utility or diminishing marginal productivity, willingness to pay falls as quantities increase.
Special Problems in Valuing the Water Resource The hydrologic system must be considered in terms of its interactions with climate, land, ecosystems, and the human social and economic systems. This intricacy is further complicated by the highly variable nature of moisture supplies, the importance of sequential uses as water flows from upper watersheds to its eventual destinations in sea or sump, and the importance of transportation costs in establishing water value. Concepts of the
― 249 ― economic value of water can be relevant only when explicit recognition is given to quantity, location, quality, and time of supply. Put another way, the value of water is highly site-specific, and varies directly with local conditions of supply and demand for the resource. Broadly speaking, there are three ways of determining net willingness to pay for water.[4] One is to determine WTP by statistical analysis of actual or hypothetical water use decisions by consumers. A second, called the "change in net income" approach (applicable to agricultural or business users), imputes the value of water as the increment to profits arising from an increment in water supply. Finally, the "alternative cost" approach values water in terms of the resource savings which would be achieved by waterintensive as opposed to alternative production technologies.
Marginal versus Total Value The correct concept is the incremental worth (value of the last unit) rather than total value or revenue associated with all units of water and other resources. The total value of product can be attributed to water only if all other factors of production (i.e., labor, land, capital) have no known alternative beneficial use (an extremely unlikely event).
Long-Run versus Short-Run Value Short-run values apply to farmer decisions in the growing season (with fixed resources not charged for), while long-run values reflect the net returns after all resource input costs are deducted. Short-run values tend to be higher; as willingness to pay rises, the fewer the fixed resources which need to be accounted for. Long-run values are the most appropriate in the present context.
Comparability in Place, Form, and Time As noted above, water is a bulky commodity, for which transportation costs are often large relative to value at the place of use. Hence, value of water declines rapidly with distances from site of use, and may even be negative at a potential source. Quality (perhaps reflected in treatment costs) and timing are important specifics as well.
Measuring Quantity: Diversion versus Consumption For off-stream uses, the usual choice of a measure of quantity is between the amount diverted and the consumptive use (that
― 250 ― portion of diversion not returned to the stream or aquifer, and not available for reuse). Although there are no firmly agreed upon conventions, most economists prefer to deal with withdrawals. The discussion below follows that approach.
Annual Value versus Capitalized Value Does the value estimate represent an annual rental equivalent (the price of one acre-foot in a typical year), or the right to a certain flow each year into the indefinite future? Clearly, these values are related, but not identical. The value of the latter (property right) is conceptually equal to the discounted present value of the stream of annual values. Hence, time horizon, interest rate, and expectations regarding inflation, in addition to annual value, must be specified in order to reconcile the two. The capitalized value will normally be in the range of twelve to twenty times as large as the annual value. In the subsequent discussion, "net benefits" will refer to the willingness to pay for one acre-foot of raw water diverted in a particular year, unless otherwise specified. Diversionary uses are treated first, followed by the nonwithdrawal or instream categories.
Net Economic Benefits Foregone from Irrigation The direct value of water from foregone irrigation is usually measured in terms of the decrement of profit to the producer without irrigation (or with a decrement of water supply) as compared to profits with irrigation. At the margin, the value of a decrement is the same as that of an increment, so
either formulation is applicable. One additional distinction is useful. The marginal net benefit measured can be for the marginal crop or for the average net benefit for the marginal farm. I favor the former measure as most generally applicable. But there may be some instances, where entire farms (or even areas) are removed from irrigation, where the average benefit is appropriate. What are the net benefits of irrigation water? The previous discussion implies that the value at the margin will reflect water scarcity and marginal cost of supply. Local production conditions (i.e., rainfall, temperature, and growing season length) and market situations will have an impact, so we would expect considerable variation across the West. A recent set of estimates has been developed by Beattie and Frank,[5] which involved statistical analysis of 1974 census data on agricultural output, as influenced by resource inputs, including
― 251 ― land, labor, machinery, and chemicals, as well as irrigation water. The results yielded values (converted to current 1982 dollars) of $10-$15 per acre-foot in the intermountain valleys (Upper Colorado, Snake River Basin), $20-$25 in the desert Southwest and central California, and $40-$45 per acre-foot in the Ogallala groundwater region of the High Plains. Howitt et al. recently reported rather similar results, using a much different technique. Their interregional supply-demand model for California yielded shadow prices at the margin of $23-$35 per acre-foot in the Central Valley and southern California and $7 in the Imperial Valley.[6] Gollehon et al. show shadow prices for irrigation water for eleven Rocky Mountain subregions. With a 20 percent reduction in irrigation water supply, two regions were identified with water valued at the margin in excess of $20 per acre-foot, while four were between $10 and $20 per acre-foot and six were below $10.[7] Estimates based on conversions of water rights sales to annual equivalent values in New Mexico[8] yield similar results. Irrigation water is seen to be most valuable when it helps to confer a special comparative advantage on crop production in a particular locale. This advantage is most likely to occur in the desert valleys of the Southwest which are adapted to perishable fruit and vegetable production. Forage, feed grain, and food grains are storable and readily produced with natural moisture elsewhere in the nation, so that net value productivity of water use in these categories is relatively limited. Net benefit estimates obtained for certain specialty crops may therefore be somewhat higher than the figures cited above. However, such uses will probably account for no more than 10
to 20 percent of total irrigation water use in the West in the period under discussion, and are not relevant for the present analysis. Eighty percent of irrigation demand probably lies below $40 per acre-foot, and the last 10-20 percent subject to transfer would be valued below that level.
Net Economic Benefits in Nonagricultural Uses The Value of Water in Industry While water is used throughout the industrial sector, the major consumer, particularly in the arid West, is in the energy sector, particularly for cooling steam-electric power plants.
― 252 ― Several processes can be used for cooling, depending on water scarcity and price. Young and Gray[9] show with an alternative cost approach that it is economical to convert from a passthrough system to evaporative cooling towers when water costs rise above about $5 per acre-foot (1982 price levels). Methods which conserve more water are much more expensive. Gold et al.,[10] in a study for EPA, report that breakeven points for a combination wet-dry system run around $600 per acre-foot, while the shift to a completely dry cooling system would be economical only if water was priced above about $1400 per acre-foot. Abbey's analysis of the water/energy problems in the Colorado River Basin provides similar estimates.[11] Leigh has estimated the net benefits to water for coal slurry pipelines, using the cost saving from the alternative of rail transportation as the measure.[12] The value of water in a Colorado to Texas system is estimated to exceed $1600 per acre-foot. Hence, the large-scale energy projects proposed for several areas of the West could, if necessary, be willing to pay an amount many times the price of water in neighboring agricultural uses. Other manufacturing processes, i.e., electronics, would likely be willing to pay even higher amounts for the relatively small amounts required.
Value of Water in Households While willingness to pay for water delivered to households is readily observed and much studied, deriving a marginal value of water to households which is comparable and commensurate with estimates of raw water values in streams is relatively difficult. Household water, which is treated (filtered, chlorinated), stored, and delivered to the user on demand, is a much different economic commodity than the raw river water used in irrigation or in many industries. Hence, a deduction for treatment, storage, and delivery costs must be made to achieve comparability. A method
suggested by Young and Gray using data developed by Howe and Lineaweaver[13] estimates that lawn sprinkling is valued at about $150 per acre-foot and in-house uses as $250 per acre-foot (in 1982 dollars). A weighted average would be about $220 per acre-foot. Howitt et al.[14] do not distinguish between industrial and household demand. Their municipal and household sector estimates for 1980 (in 1982 prices) are about $160$200 per acre-foot. Gardner and Miller report the price of water rights in the Colorado-Big Thompson project (in northeastern Colorado) transferable to urban uses to have averaged $2450 per acre-foot
― 253 ― in 1981.[15] Converting this figure to an annual acre-foot value requires assumptions regarding the appropriate capitalization rate and expectations about future inflation. However, at an interest rate of 8 to 9 percent (which seems plausible), and a long planning horizon, the figure is practically equivalent to the figures given above.
Hydroelectric Power Generation Evaluation of hydroelectric projects has usually proceeded on the assumption that water is a free good, so that recorded efforts to value water in this use are rare. The procedure which has been developed is to value electricity in terms of cost of production by the alternative process of a steam-powered plant (alternative cost method). The value of water is then derived by deducting capital and operating costs of the generation and transmission system. The residual, if any, is attributed to the water resource (change in net income method). Specific value estimates vary according to the differences in head (the distance the water falls before turning turbines) but also with distance to load centers, energy costs of the stream alternative, and the cost of dam and storage reservoir construction relative to power output. Values also may be expressed for one site only or for several sites on a given river reach. Young and Gray report single site values ranging from $3.30 to $10 per acre-foot in 1982 prices in the western states, the higher values associated with sites with relatively large head on the Colorado River.[16] Whittlesey and Gibbs report values in the Columbia Basin of over $30 per acre-foot (1982 prices) for water going through all dams below Franklin Reservoir, including Grand Coulee.[17]
Valuing Water in Waste Load Dilution Most analysts have adopted the concept that the value of a unit of dilution water is equivalent to the cost of treating effluent to achieve an
improvement in water quality equivalent to the specified quantity and quality of dilution water. The results of these studies generally imply that dilution benefits, for the most part, are not large. Merritt and Mar[18] showed dilution water in the Willamette Basin (Oregon) to be about $1.30 per acrefoot (1982 price levels). Gray and Young[19] applied this technique for several regions, deriving estimates for diluting urban effluents ranging from $0.08 per acre-foot (Colorado Basin) to $3.25 in the lower Missouri. However, they derived a value of high quality water in the Colorado Basin for dilution of salinity at about $15 per acre-foot.
― 254 ―
The Value of Water in Water-Based Recreation Water-based recreational services, by tradition and policy, are not often priced by market processes. Hence, the normal problems of valuing water are compounded, since in this case, the value of water for recreation must be derived from a prior synthetic imputation of the value of the recreational services themselves. Moreover, recreational uses of water are often complementary to other uses, rather than competing with them. Thus, water stored for irrigation or flood control can often by enjoyed without diminishing its usefulness in alternative uses. However, growing recreation demand is creating situations in which these uses are competitive with other classes of instream and offstream use, but economic analysts have only recently begun work on measuring values which are suitable for comparing allocations among alternative uses. Daubert, Young, and Gray[20] formulated a direct interview procedure which elicits bids from recreationists on the value of water in flowing streams. Applied to a sample of visitors to the Poudre Canyon in northeastern Colorado, this approach yielded estimates of economic value related to flow in fishing, whitewater kayaking, and noncontact streamside recreation (i.e., picnicking). The resulting marginal values were (at a typical summer flow rate of 200 cfs) converted to dollars per acre-foot: $9 per acrefoot for fishing, $5 for whitewater sports, and $7 for the noncontact group. Walsh et al. performed similar analyses on western Colorado streams, reporting $13 per acre-foot for fishing, $4 for kayaking, and $2 for rafting, when flows were maintained at 35 percent of maximum.[21] These findings lend support to the notion that nonconsumptive uses, even though they are nonmarketed, have economic value to users. While many are skeptical of the validity of benefit estimates based on responses to questions regarding hypothetical consumption situations, the values cited seem plausible, and a preferable alternative technique to generate quantitative estimates of instream flow values has not been developed.
Summary of Direct Impact Analysis Up to this point, it has been shown that: 1) The direct net economic value foregone from partially reduced irrigation water supplies will mostly fall in the range of $5-$30 per acre-foot, depending on location and type of use.
― 255 ― 2) The gain in net value of product or willingness to pay in industries and households absorbing water previously in agricultural use is five to ten times or more as high as the losses in the agricultural sector. Important direct economic values also are found in instream uses, particularly in power generation and recreation. (These latter uses are less often in direct conflict with irrigation, since they are largely nonconsumptive.) These findings are summarized graphically in Figure 10.1. The horizontal axis represents the fixed supply of developed water in a representative river basin. Agricultural water values are shown in the left vertical scale, and urban-industrial values on the right. The step-function Da represents the demand (value-quantity) relationship for agriculture. Maximum WTP would be in the $50-$100/AF range, but most of the demand is below that range. The step-function Du , drawn in reverse from the right-hand axis, represents demand in nonagricultural uses. Maximum WTP is much higher than in agriculture. Du intercepts Da at a point such that 10 percent (more or less) of the water is most profitably used in nonagricultural pursuits, while the balance is profitably employed in irrigation. The function D'u represents a
hypothetical future nonagricultural demand, reflecting growth in those sectors. The gross gains to the regional economy from the shift from Du to D'u is shown by the area between the curves, MNOP, while the losses
foregone in agriculture were MNQR. The net gain to the economy from the shift is then RQOP, and is likely to be quite large.
Indirect Impacts from Reduced Irrigation Indirect income effects, often called secondary impacts, are the impacts on related economic sectors which are associated with changes in the level of irrigation. They are conventionally divided into forward-linked activities ("stemming from" effects), those which involve processing, marketing, and transportation of the farm products, and backward-linked activities ("induced" effects) which include supply of inputs (seed, fertilizer, machinery, etc.) to the farm sector.
― 256 ―
Figure 10.1 Marginal Willingness to Pay for Water as Related to Percent of Average Annual Supply: Agriculture and Municipal and Industrial Combined (for a Representative Western River Basin) Indirect impact measures must not be confused with direct impact measures. Indirect income measures usually refer to either gross revenue charges or payments to all primary resources, rather than the net revenue shifts measured in direct impact analysis above. Therefore, direct economic impact measures and indirect economic impact measures, even though both are expressed in dollars, are not strictly commensurate.
The Limited Indirect Impact Hypothesis For purposes of this chapter, the main question regarding indirect impacts is the relative magnitudes in losing sectors versus gaining sectors. Concern over the magnitude of potential indirect effects in irrigation-based subregions is the basis for public action to avoid loss of irrigation in areas where supply depletion is imminent. My conclusion regarding the importance of irrigation to regional economies has, in some circles, proven to be
― 257 ― controversial. Stated simply, my belief is that irrigation developments have had a relatively minor impact on regional economies in the post-industrial era. The converse proposition is that loss of 10 to 20 percent of the irrigation supply in the West would not have an appreciable effect on regional income or employment. Evidence for this proposition can be put forward in three classes: casual observation, statistical analysis of growth impacts on water development, and detailed studies of the structure of regional economies.
Casual Observation Consider any of a number of irrigated areas with no other industry or governmental installation to bolster the economy, beyond the suppliers and processors linked to agriculture. Many tens of thousands of acres of irrigation, particularly when the products are forages, grains, or cotton, are required to support even a small town. The numerous small communities dotting the Ogallala-High Plains region provide one example; Yuma and Pinal Counties in Arizona, another.
Econometric Growth Analyses More systematic statistical analysis of growth impacts also have not been able to identify significant regional growth impacts from irrigation. Only a few detailed ex post analyses of regional growth impacts associated with irrigation projects have been published. Cicchetti et al., under contract to the Bureau of Reclamation, employed regression analysis to study the effect on various indices of regional economic growth of a number of variables representing Bureau of Reclamation investments.[22] Census data were obtained for numerous economic subregions in five arid western states, for 1950, 1960, and 1970. Variables representing USBR investments in irrigation facilities were not found to have any significant impact on subregion income, and only a small and not convincingly significant impact (t-value = 1.62) on the value of farm output. In a similar study, Fullerton et al. used econometric techniques to estimate the quantitative impacts of federal water resource development on economic growth in 246 counties in 7 western states.[23] The authors summed up (p. 22): The null hypothesis that regional economic growth is caused by investment in water resources of various types is given virtually no support from these empirical results.
― 258 ―
Studies of Regional Economic Structure Other detailed regional studies, such as Kelso et al.,[24] yield similar inferences. The recent investigation of the Colorado Ogallala-High Plains region found that the 600,000 acres irrigated in the area directly employed about 1200 workers (one man-year = 2000 hours), while withdrawing 1.1 million acre-feet of water annually. Indirect employment in the region associated with irrigation from the Colorado Ogallala accounted for another 1800 workers.[25] Our conclusion was that the 40 percent reduction in irrigated crop production, employment, and income anticipated over the next four decades would have an imperceptible effect on the state economy, since the impact would amount to less than one-tenth of one percent of the state's work force. Gollehon et al. studied the effects of reduced irrigation due to energy development on regional employment and income in eleven Rocky Mountain region subareas, in Montana, Wyoming, Colorado, and New Mexico.[26] The area studied encompassed nearly one million irrigated acres, producing mainly forages, and is supplied by 3.1 million acre-feet of water. A 20 percent reduction in water supply to this group of subregions would cost the area about 450 jobs directly in farming and about 900 jobs in the region as a whole. Indirect effects are often measured by reference to "multipliers" derived from a regional input-output (interindustry) model which indicates the monetary value of income generated elsewhere in the economy in relation to a dollar's worth of increased income in the sector of interest (i.e., irrigated crop production). Applying the multiplier to estimates of increased (or reduced) crop sales yields an estimate of increased (reduced) economic activity in the region represented by the model. The income multipliers for the irrigated agriculture sector are among the highest of all economic sectors, since each added dollar's worth of crop output generates economic activity in processing sectors, such as feedlots, dairies, and packing plants. To project what would be the net regional effect of reallocation of the water resource, however, the analysis must be carried further. I have computed the predicted income effects in California of an additional unit of water in several selected irrigated agriculture sectors and in four of the rapidly growing sectors in the state's economy (Table 10.1). California was selected because of the size and importance of its irrigated sector, and because the changes being examined are likely to be registered early in that state. The income projections would probably not differ much in other western states.
― 259 ―
Table 10.1 Direct, Indirect, and Induced Income and Employment Impacts from Water Reallocation, Selected Agricultural and Industrial Sectors, California, 1977 Part A: Income Impacts Sector Name (Number)
Water Use (1,000 AF)
Total Total a Income Income ($ million) per 1,000 AF ($ million per 1,000 AF)
Direct Plus Indirect Income per 1,000 AF ($ million per 1,000 AF)
Direct, Indirect, Plus Induced Income per 1,000 AF
Hay and pasture (14) 11,440
319
.03
.06
.09
Cotton (9)
4,714
253
.05
.13
.21
Noncitrus fruits (22)
3,478
710
.20
.33
.52
Vegetables (25)
1,988
767
.39
.63
.93
All agricultural sectors
34,460
5,000
Printing, publishing (70)
4
1,404
351
611
1,130
Aircraft (114)
15
3,247
216
492
957
Communication equip. (110)
5
2,578
516
836
1,579
Computers, office
6
1,029
172
396
734
Selected Agricultural Sectors
Selected Industrial Sectors
equip. (103)
― 260 ―
Part B: Employment Impacts
Labor Use (person years)
Direct Workers per 1,000 AF
Direct Plus Indirect Workers per 1,000 AF
Direct, Indirect, Plus Induced Workers per 1,000 AF
Hay and pasture (14) 11,440
7,891
0.7
1.9
3.0
Cotton (9)
4,714
10,187
2.2
7.9
11.7
Noncitrus fruits (22)
3,478
114,408
32.9
43.8
52.6
Vegetables (25)
1,988
59,183
29.8
48.0
62.0
All agricultural sectors
34,460
451,000
Printing, publishing (70)
4
68,540
18,037
29,941
56,095
Aircraft (114)
15
119,930
8,156
20,064
42,091
Communication equip. (110)
5
101,492
20,298
33,635
69,420
Sector Name (Number)
Water Use (1,000 AF)
Selected Agricultural Sectors
Selected Industrial Sectors
Computers, office equip. (103)
6
63,224
All nonagricultural sectors
5,604
8,831,000
11,290
22,128
39,515
Source: Computed from California Department of Water Resources, Measuring Economic Impacts: The Application of Input-Output Analysis to California Water Resource Problems, Bulletin 210, Sacramento (reprinted 1981), (Tables 3, 15, 16, 17).
a
Income = payments to primary factors of production ("value added").
― 261 ― The income measured here refers to payments to primary resources. An acre-foot of water used in hay and pasture production yielded in 1977 about $30 of direct income, $60 of direct-plus-indirect income, and $90 of direct, indirect, and induced incomes. Other agricultural sectors are considerably larger. Comparing the industrial sectors, it is seen that total annual income per acre-foot is several hundred to several thousand times as large as in irrigation. Job creation is another aspect of regional growth policy. The water requirements per worker for the same sectors are shown in Part B of the table. Less than one worker per year was directly employed in association with 1,000 acre-feet of water in hay and pasture production in California. This compares with 8,000 to 20,000 workers per 1,000 acre-feet in the selected industrial sectors. Considering indirect and induced as well as direct employment shows similar relationships.
Indirect Impacts: Summing Up The analysis of indirect regional economic impacts yields similar inferences to those reached concerning on-farm impacts. 1) The indirect losses to a region giving up irrigation water, while not insignificant in terms of either monetary flows or employment, will be dwarfed by the gains in nonagricultural sectors.
2) As in direct impact analysis, there are stair-steps of impacts, when analyzed on the basis of returns per acre-foot. These steps parallel the steps in the direct analysis, in that forages and food and feed grains, which account for over half of water use in western states, yield relatively small indirect employment and income effects, while the emerging manufacturing and service sectors yield relatively large increases per unit water of employed.
Caveats Space and time limitations preclude discussion of several important aspects of the subject. Specific localities are likely to feel large proportional impacts of increased urban demands for water. The use of state data may mask the seriousness of these effects of water reallocation. Where the water is transferred to distant uses, rather than in the locale of agricultural application,
― 262 ― the community left behind may suffer significant proportional losses of income and employment; the Owens Valley is an example. Also, the question of indirect impacts on public sector activities and investments (schools, roads, health care, public safety) is not considered here. Finally, little information is available on indirect impacts from instream uses, and that topic has not been touched on in this paper.
Policy Implications The preceding analysis has shown that as the western states have been transformed from an agriculturally-based economy toward more manufacturing and eventually to a primarily service-based economy, the proportion of the irrigation-agriculture sector to total income and employment has declined. In particular, the proportion of direct and indirect employment and income generated by the last 10-20 percent of water in irrigation represents an imperceptible portion of the economy of any of the western states. We should recognize that changes between sectors are the natural consequence of an evolving economy.
Policy Implications Regarding Farmers Facing Losses of Agricultural Water Supplies In the case of farmers who have a renewable source of supply (usually
surface water or aquifers interrelated with streams), the existence of a problem turns on the degree to which property rights in water and land are protected by state and federal law, and hence, whether or not due compensation will be received by the farmers losing the water. I perceive a relatively limited threat in this instance. Most farmers who have sold water rights (either directly or with associated lands) have not only been amply repaid for foregone productivity of their water, but have shared liberally in the benefits of alternative uses. Land and water values have been greatly bid up in the face of anticipated urban, industrial, and energy demands. The fact is that large acreages with associated water rights in regions of urban growth are held speculatively (by farmers and others) in anticipation of further asset appreciation. Those who are forced out of farming are "crying all the way to the bank," and to a subsequent reentry to farming where land and water is cheaper, or, if desired, to a comfortable retirement
― 263 ― in Sun City, Honolulu, or Acapulco. Chapter 18 in this volume reports on trends in formalizing property rights in water throughout the West. This trend to firmer property rights in agricultural water should be encouraged, both to aid in reallocation to higher valued uses and to assure adequate recompense to resource owners.
Policy Implications Regarding Losses to Indirect Beneficiaries of Irrigation The protections afforded by property rights to primary users of water against the loss of assets is not available to the indirect beneficiaries, who are linked to irrigated agriculture as input suppliers or processors of products. Even so, at the risk of appearing insensitive, I can see only a limited basis for concern, and not much need for formal public action in response. Most individual transfers of irrigation water supply are neither large nor unexpected, enabling those indirectly impacted to adapt to new conditions. As seen above, a small amount of water from agriculture can fuel a large change in a region's population and industrial base. Even in rapidly growing metropolitan areas, such as near Denver, Phoenix, or Los Angeles, irrigation continues, and the associated indirect economic activity and employment decline only slowly. In the face of slowly declining demand, workers generally have time to plan for career change, and business and public sectors have time to depreciate their investments without suffering severe economic losses.
Finally, it might be observed that relatively few instances outside of irrigated agriculture can be identified where secondary impactees are the subject of formal public policy concern. Risks are inherent in a changing market economy, as testified by the changes affecting millions of workers in the industrial Midwest. We need to think carefully about the justification for public intervention in this case, unless it is a part of a more general response to the structural changes throughout the economy.
Conclusions The evidence regarding the role of irrigation in regional economies in the semiarid West suggests that under modern conditions of production, irrigation accounts for a relatively minor portion of employment and income. This is particularly true for the half or more of the irrigation water diversions used for forage, and food and feed grain production. Second, significant
― 264 ― growth in the nonagricultural sector can be accommodated with relatively minor shifts from irrigation. Thus, we can expect only a relatively small impact on local economies by the anticipated limited reduction in irrigation water use. The general perception that irrigation has been an engine of economic growth, and conversely that loss of irrigation would have major economic consequences, is not supported by a close examination of the structure of the economy. This misperception probably arises from what Boulding terms the mythical role of water in human society, abetted by the public relations activities of the "iron triangle" of bureaucracy, construction firms, and legislators who have a stake in "business as usual" rather than adjusting to the imperatives of a maturing water economy. I see a limited need for special public policy to solve problems which are similar to, but less severe than, those in other sectors of the changing economy.
Discussion: Charles V. Moore Professor Young has presented a succinct overview of the impacts of shifting water supplies between agriculture and other uses. I find very little with which to disagree, although a couple of important points were made that may have been missed by the noneconomist in the rush of jargon that we economists tend to use in communicating with each other. I would like to amplify and expand on three points made or alluded to in the chapter. First is the possible regional benefits from a transfer of water between agriculture and municipal and industrial users. Young clearly shows that water transferred from agriculture to the printing and publishing, aircraft,
communications, or computer and office equipment manufacturing industries will generate increase in regional income and employment. Significant benefits can also accrue to the region if water is transferred within agriculture. The institutional arrangements under which water was originally allocated in the western states (appropriative water rights, riparian rights, or long-term contract) did not take into account the productivity of this water as a criterion. "First in time" only meant that lands closest to a water source received the largest and most reliable water supplies. Riparian lands may in fact contain some of the poorest soils in a river basin. Service areas for governmental water projects are more closely related to the political power of the local elected representative than to the productivity of the soils to which the water is to be applied. Thus the probability that lands with the highest productivity also have the largest and most secure water supply is very small indeed. The probability that existing institutions have allocated water in the exact same manner as a free market, where all potential water users have an equal opportunity to bid for the supply of water, is almost nil. When one irrigation district has rights to seven acre-feet per acre and another district not too many miles away has rights to only one acre-foot, this seems prima facie evidence to prove my point. If a generously endowed district is applying the last acre-foot to a field of grain sorghum with a return of $5 per acre-foot and next door a "Johnnycome-lately" district with very junior water rights has highly productive cotton or perennial crop land left idle with a potential return of $40 to $50 per acre-foot, both the region and the nation would benefit from a transfer.
― 267 ― Howitt, Mann, and Vaux developed an interregional programming model of California to analyze the potential for water transfers between subregions of the state and between agricultural and urban users.[1] Assuming that water laws were allowed to evolve so that a competitive market for water rights was established, these authors found that, compared to maintaining existing water laws and allowing new water supplies to be developed only when users are willing to pay their full costs, the quasi water market saved up to 2 million acre-feet of water annually, with net benefits to buyers and sellers of over $70 million. Annual benefits would increase with time and population growth to $83 million by the year 2020. I would like to comment on another point alluded to by both Young and Whittlesey: how price will be determined in water sales. Both provide estimates of the incremental value in use for irrigation and industrial water. The range of these values is quite wide, varying from zero to over $40 per acre-foot at the margin for agriculture, and up to $1,600 per acre-foot for
municipal and industrial users. To make their models workable, economists make some assumptions with respect to supply and demand functions. For one thing, we assume that demand and supply functions are continuous, and that both buyers and sellers know and understand these relations (our assumption of perfect knowledge). However, in the big, cruel world things don't always work that way. The incremental values in agriculture provided by Young and Whittlesey become the lower bounds or reservation prices those growers would be willing to accept. The incremental values for municipal and industrial water then become the upper limits to price offers by municipalities. The final market clearing price will be somewhere in between, after allowances are made for transportation costs. Given that in most states there are many landowners and only a relatively few large metropolitan areas interested in purchasing water rights, the water market would be one characterized by an economist as ologopolistic. In other words, the bargaining power or market power will be in the hands of the urban areas. A market structure with most of the bargaining power on the side of the buyer will tend to reduce prices paid to sellers, and shift many of the benefits to urban areas and away from irrigated agriculture. One suggestion for equalizing the bargaining power in the marketplace and thus making the market more competitive
― 268 ― would be for landowners to create a water broker or bargaining agent to represent their interests. This broker or agent could also serve an important function by consolidating small lots, or to coin a word, "dribbles," into units large enough to be attractive to municipal buyers. This function would be especially important in California, where the legislature has recently passed a bill allowing landowners to sell water saved through water conservation efforts. Adjustment costs to limited regional water supplies will be minimized through water transfers away from marginal soils or marginal farms, rather than wholesale shifts of entire districts out of agriculture. Every time the subject of water transfers out of agriculture comes up in California, the question of the Owens Valley is raised. The Owens Valley is located on the east side of the southern Sierras; in the 1920s, the City of Los Angeles purchased land and water rights in the valley and subsequently exported water, with farming in the valley reverting to dryland agriculture. Although books and movies have described the "rape of Owens Valley," it is my opinion that the expressed anger stems from the feeling that valley landowners sold out too cheap, rather than that water rights were sold per se. The crux of the matter is that the sale price was based on the agricultural value of the water, not on its value to the buyer. If Owens water
rights had been sold at something in the neighborhood of the 1980 equivalent of $150 per acre-foot per year, a much smaller fuss might have ensued. One final point is related to the secondary impacts of water transfers. Young is correct in saying that, from the national point of view, secondary impacts "wash out". I would suspect that in a state as large as California this relation would also hold. In states with a smaller economic base than California, however, I would expect to find measurable impacts. The question I would like to raise also, without appearing crass, is "Why all the fuss?" What is the difference between the water transfer case and the state building a freeway which bypasses a small town and leaves its commercial section to wither on the vine, or the federal government opening or closing a military facility? Did anyone in the southwestern states offer compensation to the thousands of sharecroppers growing cotton in the southeastern U.S., when subsidized irrigation water favored the shift of the location of cotton production westward? Traditionally in this country, people injured by these types of structural changes (what economists call "pecuniary
― 269 ― externalities" or damages) have not been compensated, nor has government felt it necessary to intervene to prevent adjustments from occurring. When a movie theater shuts down due to lack of business, government is not expected to move in to prevent the closing just because the person operating the popcorn stand next door will be faced with a significantly reduced income.
Discussion: Norman K. Whittlesey I agree with Young's findings that reallocation of water from agriculture to competing uses is unlikely to cause serious problems for the agricultural community or for other regional and national economies. Both the farmer and the nation's economy will profit from reallocations of water to higher valued uses. The total amount of water exchanged in any given area will usually be relatively small, providing ample room for adjustment by all affected parties. Though water is a "mobile resource" leading to problems of capture for private property management, it is difficult and expensive to move far from present locations. Hence, the values given to water are likely to be site-
specific and highly influenced by other resources, competing water uses, the assumptions of the analyst, plus many other factors. Young acknowledges that different assumptions can lead to different estimates of agricultural water value. However, he implies that the differences between agricultural and nonagricultural water values are so great as to render the correct value unimportant. This may not always be true. I have developed an example in Table 10.2 to show how assumptions can affect the estimated value of irrigation water. These values are based on consumptive use, so that an appropriate adjustment would be required to obtain values for total water diversions. The first value is a very short run measure called "returns above variable costs." It could be the rental price for water in an
― 270 ―
Table 10.2 Estimation of Alternative Agricultural Water Values for an Average Crop Rotation Consumptive Water Requirement (AF/A)
2.50
Gross Revenue ($/A)
397
Costs ($/A) Variable production (VC) Fixed excluding land and water (FC) Irrigated land (IL)
137 64
115
Nonirrigated land (DL)
20
Water delivery and application (WC)
80
Net Returns to Water Above ($/AF): VC
104
VC + FC + DL
70
VC+FC +DL +W
38
VC + FL +IL +W
1
emergency drought situation, where it could go even higher for the rescue of perennial crops like orchards or vineyards. This value of water is sometimes called "value added" to indicate the economic impact of agriculture in a regional or state economy as estimated by an input-output model. In this context, it is a measure of payments for fixed resources used in the production process. This value would not likely be used to determine a market price for permanent exchange of water rights, nor would it provide any indication of the profitability of agriculture. For water exchanges that leave land and undepreciated irrigation facilities idle, we move close to the average value of water to determine its market price and measure the social impact of exchange. This value is probably best reflected by the returns above costs including dryland rent ($70/acre-foot). But if the irrigation facilities are allowed to depreciate normally (or salvaged) before the water is exchanged, we should probably move to the next water value ($38) which deducts the current payment for the irrigation facility. If the land and irrigation facility usefulness are not reduced, the value of both resources must be deducted from the value of water sold. At this point the marginal value of water will be
― 271 ― near zero, as reflected by the last line of the table. No rational farmer is going to sell water at this price, even though it probably reflects the social impact of small quantities of water diversions to alternative uses. This is Young's conclusion. This exercise illustrates that alternative agricultural water values can be used to compare with values in competitive uses. The result is site-specific, crop-specific, and operator-specific and, to a large extent, depends upon which side hires the "best" economists and lawyers in the bargaining
process. Even after deciding which is the proper agricultural value of water to capitalize, we are left with questions about discount rates and planning horizons in establishing market exchange values. I believe that it would be possible to argue for lower discount rates and longer planning periods in agriculture than for industry. Such assumptions can move the values of agricultural and competing uses closer together than is apparent when only comparing annual rental values. In any case, the derived demand for water in most industrial uses is very inelastic and can generally be satisfied with little impact on agriculture. Generally, I would agree that small incremental adjustments in water use are unlikely to cause any serious secondary economic impacts. We should always expect measures of impact on the national economy to be positive for water reallocations. However, we must recognize that rather large economic communities throughout the West are based solely upon irrigation. As the quantity of water and distance to the new use are increased, the negative local impacts will also increase, regardless of how well the farmer is compensated. There are examples of whole communities being significantly reduced by the thirst of Los Angeles and the California water system—not to deny that the state and society have been made better off after the reallocation. A recent study in Washington State provides some estimates of secondary impacts of irrigation.[1] Though subject to all of the vagueness of inputoutput analysis, the results do show greater secondary impacts than the studies quoted by Young. Increased value added at the secondary level was approximately $540 per acre or about $140 per acre-foot of water diversion. Additional employment created at the secondary level equaled one job per 26 acres or 100 acre-feet of water diverted. To conclude, we should not be unduly concerned about reallocation of water from agriculture to competing uses. In fact, we should aid that transition whenever possible through better economic studies and improvements in the legal and institutional
― 272 ― system for water exchange. The net societal impact will be positive. We must, however, be prepared to deal with problems of primary value and secondary impact when they do arise.
Chapter 11— National and International Commodity Price Impacts by Earl O. Heady
Abstract Reduced supplies and higher costs for water in the future will lead to higher food costs. However, these tendencies cannot be separated from other variables which also will cause higher prices for food. Major variables affecting food prices include world population, per capita income, and agricultural technology in developing countries. Developing countries have capabilities to produce enough food to keep real prices at reasonable levels. These outcomes will overshadow U.S. water supplies in determining future food prices. Another condition of similar importance in food prices is the general level of agricultural technology in the United States. Some agriculturalists believe that crop yields are plateauing. If so, these yield limits would dominate water supplies in affecting food prices. However, other agricultural scientists foresee technological advances in crop and livestock production which will entirely offset water supplies in determining U.S. food prices over the next 30 years. Statistical models to predict the impact of water supplies on food prices do not exist. However, a programming model providing a normative analysis indicated that reduced water supplies which cause a fourfold increase in water prices would increase food prices by 6 percent. Reduced water supplies in combination with restraints on land use and soil loss would cause much higher increases in real costs of food. Based on estimated food demand elasticities, each 1 percent decline in food supplies due to reduced water availability would increase food prices by 4 percent in terms of domestic conditions and .75 percent in terms of world markets.
The United States has had an abundance of land, and real food prices have declined over most of this century due to a number of planned conditions and favorable prices for resources. Some suggest that these conditions will not prevail in future because the
― 274 ―
suggest that these conditions will not prevail in future because the nation is approaching a plateau in per-acre yields. Agriculture increasingly competes with other sectors for surface water, is exhausting its groundwater supply, and is faced with increasing real prices for energy. We will return to these propositions at a later point. The extent to which these limits to food supplies and rising real costs of food will be realized depends on our ability to recreate conditions of the past, which allowed us to develop cheap substitutes for land and to increase farm output much faster than population growth. Reduced supplies of water for irrigation in the western states, with subsequent restraints on supplies of food commodities, will have their impacts on domestic and international markets since the nation exports a large proportion of its grain production. Because of strong interdependence of U.S. agriculture with international commodity markets, food prices in the U.S. will be closely related to variables of food supply and demand the world over. Hence, generally we must relate water supplies of the West and their effect on food prices, to food production and consumption of the world. Domestically, the impact of changes in irrigation will be offset or augmented by future technological developments and factor prices for the rest of U.S. agriculture.
World Variables Affecting U.S. Commodity Prices The future supply and real price of food depends on a complex set of variables and conditions—of which one is the U.S. supply price of water for agriculture. The real price of food will depend as much on demand variables as on those on the commodity and resource supply side—of which water is one element of a major set. Certainly two of the dominant demand variables are the rate of growth of population and per capita incomes in developing countries. Even with a reduction in their birth rate, total populations will still increase greatly since a large portion of these populations is still below childproducing age. But nearly as important are potentials in per capita income. The income elasticity of demand for food generally is high in developing countries. It is high even in relatively developed countries such as Eastern Europe and centrally planned economies where institutional restraints, rather than market demands, has limited use of meat and feed grains. The further release of these institutional
― 275 ― restraints could mean a further heavy leverage in demand and prices for U.S. agricultural exports. In the 20 years from 1960 to 1979, we increased grain exports by 300 percent. In 1979, we exported the product of one-outof-three acres of grain, including 33 percent of corn production, 57 percent of wheat production, 37 percent of soybean production, and 46 percent of all grains. Obviously, if it were not for this export demand, American agriculture
would, given our technology and stock of natural resources, be an extremely depressed industry, and we would not be worried about domestic land and water supplies and strategies. World export demand quantities are not, of course, independent of food supplies in the respective countries. Export demands of the future will depend on the ability of potential importing countries to increase their domestic supply of foods. The "supply variables" of other countries affecting the demand for U.S. exports include (a) improving technology through research and education, including high yielding and water-fertilizer-pesticide responsive varieties, (b) bringing more land under cultivation, (c) intensifying agriculture and land and water use through extended multiple cropping, (d) further development and better allocation of water supplies, (e) improving the laws and institutions governing the allocation and use of water, (f) improving livestock production, and (g) prevention of postharvest waste. These world variables and conditions relating to supplies directly, and through domestic supplies to demand for U.S. exports, are vast and complex and readily could offset or reinforce any impacts of limited U.S. water supplies on commodity prices. The fact that they have the potential of offsetting reduced U.S. water supplies over the next 30 years is evident: developing countries have 64 percent of the world's cereal acreage but produce only 40 percent of the total supply. In the period 1934-38 their average grain yield was 1.14 tons per hectare, compared to 1.15 tons for developed countries. However, by 1973-76, developed countries had increased per hectare yields to 3.0 tons, but developing countries to only 1.4 tons. If developing countries increase cereal yields only to the developed country level, even with currently known technologies, cereal production could be increased by 67 percent. And that is a modest possibility, since developing country locations roughly conform with the tropical area of the world, with much greater opportunity for multiple cropping and utilizing solar energy compared with the temperate climates of developing countries.
― 276 ―
Cropland Conversion and Land Substitutes A considerable proportion of the land which could be converted to crops has been shifted over the last three decades. FAO[1] estimates that 125 million hectares over the world could be improved and irrigated in a decade, that food production could be increased by 3.8 percent per year to the year 2000, with 28 percent of the increase coming from added land. Exactly how much land could be converted at realistic costs remains somewhat uncertain. Some estimates[2] suggest that of potentially arable land, only 22 percent in Africa, 11 percent in South America, and about 45 percent worldwide is now under cultivation. Others are even more optimistic. These estimates undoubtedly are too optimistic, and use of fragile lands would cause some environmental deterioration. However, there is still some land which can be converted to crops even in the United States. The 1977 SCS inventory (RNI)
estimated that as much as 127 million acres[3] could be converted to the equivalent of Class I and II land. But most researchers expect that world food supplies can be increased most readily by use of improved technology on land already cropped. While some estimates are pessimistic under any scenario, other estimates indicate that over the next 20 to 30 years world food supplies might push ahead enough to allow a worldwide increase in per capita consumption.[4] Food production in developing countries probably could be increased by 3.5 percent per annum to the year 2000. (Existence of the potential does not guarantee implementation of policies to attain it, however.)
Yield Limits and Production Possibilities In addition to those variables of world food demand and supply, another set of circumstances will either dampen or augment the price effects of reduced supplies of U.S. water for irrigation. These relate to future technological possibilities in U.S. agriculture generally. Over the last decade several agriculturists have proposed that U.S. yields are beginning to plateau. If this is true, then reduced water supplies would have a very significant effect in raising commodity prices. If, however, future productivity advances are as large as those of the recent past, the commodity price impact of reduced water supplies could be small. It is possible that the seeming emergence of yield limits in the
― 277 ― mid-1970s was due to weather and the shift of somewhat marginal land into grain production out of former cropland set-aside. When observations for 1979-82, years of record U.S. crop yields, are included, a yield plateau cannot be statistically verified.[5] Some persons are optimistic about our ability to generate new technologies which can continue to increase productivity levels. Lu et al.[6] estimate that if future additions to expenditures on agricultural research only offset inflation, productivity growth in agriculture will slow to 1 percent by 2000, while a real growth in research and development at 7 percent would increase it by a 1.3 percent rate. Whether diminishing returns to agricultural research investment will be encountered as efforts are turned to "exotic" technologies, as compared to the more conventional ones emphasized in the past, is unknown. Fuller[7] believes that we already are at a point where diminishing returns to research can be expected. Wittwer, an optimist, says "far from achieving scientific and biological limits, the world has only begun to explore the capabilities of increasing agricultural production." He also states that "biological limits have not been achieved for productivity of any of the major food crops . . . a comparison of average world yields for every major crop shows a production ratio of three to one, with some records greater by a factor of six."[8] In a later analysis, he suggests that the
genetic potential of corn yield is 900 bushels per acre.[9] Other scientists are optimistic in terms of possibilities in genetic engineering; increasing crop adaptation to stress conditions; improved irrigation technologies; hybrid wheat; increased protein content of corn; breaking the yield barrier of soybeans; improving photosynthetic efficiency of plants; developing nitrogen fixation by nonleguminous plants, and improved efficiency of those that now fix nitrogen in the soil; nontraditional approaches in genetics to more effectively use available genetic material; improving the efficiency of nutrient uptake of plants; developing appropriate technologies so that land not now cropped can be substituted for resources which are growing increasingly scarce; and a host of other innovations.[10] Even more than in the past, the urgency is to induce a flow of technologies consistent with the relative supplies and prices of resources which will prevail in the future. With a systematic ordering of our research, I am optimistic about our ability to continue growth in agricultural productivity and food production. Starting in the 1920s and abetted by both public and private investment in research and favorable real prices for energy and chemicals, we developed a vast set of new capital inputs (fertilizer-responsive crop varieties, improved chemical fertilizers,
― 278 ― pesticides, etc.), which substituted for land. The supply of land was thus made less binding on food supplies, and the real price of food declined rather continuously up to recent times. Of course, during much of this same period, low energy prices and a favorable public pricing policy also caused water to be substituted for land as irrigated acreage increased. These substitutions were so vast that during times of the 1960s and early 1970s the nation paid farmers for holding up to 65 million acres out of production. Another indication of this substitution is the fact that total grain production in 1910 was 120 million tons on 193 million acres, but in 1979 was 316 million tons produced on 162 million acres. With the prevailing technologies of the 1960s and early 1970s, the nation's food supplies could have been maintained without important price impacts (except for specialized commodities adapted to specific climatic conditions) had we used the 60 million acres held out of production instead of any irrigated acreage. Again, in the future, the impact on commodity prices of reduced water supplies to agriculture will depend on the availability of water-substituting inputs and technologies. Their availability, in turn, will depend on the nation's agricultural research expenditures and the real price of the inputs. Whereas the real prices of chemicals and energy-based inputs declined in previous decades, the probability is that they will increase in the future along with energy prices. The public challenge is an induced research program which relates technologies to resource prices. While we were able to develop technologies for land and water which allowed us to implement a large world food aid program even while holding over 60
million acres of cropland idle during the 1960s, surplus conditions of this extent are not likely to return in the future. Export demand is expected to continue to grow along with world population and per capita incomes, even if not as rapidly as in 1970-79. Aside from declining U.S. water supplies, I expect the real price of food to increase in the long run due to greater population and income, institutional changes which allow centrally planned and developing nations to participate in world grain markets, tightening restraints on limited resources worldwide, and, especially, rising energy prices. These rising energy prices will dampen somewhat the rate of development of agriculture through increased real prices for several categories of inputs and increasing costs of pumping groundwater. If we had a closed economy where this complex set of demand, supply, and resource price variables had been operational for 40 years with carefully collected time series observations, we
― 279 ― probably could predict or simulate the net impact of declining U.S. water supplies on commodity prices. However, with the prices of U.S. agricultural commodities increasingly linked to resource supplies, developmental and institutional changes, and food supply-demand variables in many countries, it is not possible in a few months to quantify a model which can give these net effects. There can be many possible combinations and permutations of these variables in the future. Their expected effect is to increase real prices for farm commodities, but the exact extent that reduced U.S. water supplies will add to this direction currently cannot be deciphered from this complex. If one set of variables dominates in direction and magnitude, they will offset the tendency of decreased U.S. water supplies to increase commodity prices; if another set dominates, a scarcity of U.S. irrigation water will augment their effect. Farmers, ranchers, and land owners collectively would be best off under the latter, consumers would be better off under the former.
Some Estimates of Commodity Supply Prices under Various Water Regimes and Other Scenarios For the assignment undertaken in this chapter, it would be useful if we could pick out specific future dates, set all exogenous and some endogenous variables fixed at expected levels, vary (reduce) water supplies, and "read off" the resulting expected increases in commodity prices. Data for statistical, econometric and other methods or models for these types of predictions do not, however, exist. Nor are they likely to do so in the near future. Changes in the variables and institutions affecting water supplies and prices may change both gradually and discretely in the future. In the meantime, observations on all of these expected changes do not exist in time series data so that we can statistically predict their future impacts on prices. Many things which will affect water supplies and prices will only occur
in the future. Thus our main opportunity to appraise a future of reduced supplies and higher prices in interaction with other events such as greater exports, soil conservation programs, changes in U.S. land use, technological developments, and conservation and environmental programs is to simulate the future. Some data are available, which we will summarize as one indication of potential impacts of water supplies and prices on commodity and food
― 280 ― prices. While these are not perfect models, and have limitations that we know better than anyone else, they give probably the best data available to gauge the future in terms of our specific assignment. For some years we have incorporated groundwater and surface water sectors for the 17 western states into large-scale interregional programming models of U.S. agriculture. Generally, these models allow transfer of certain land not now in crops to cropland, project future nonagricultural demand for water by regions, suppose a future reduction of groundwater supplies through use of water at only recharge rates, consider trend and other levels of yield improvement over time, and incorporate alternative population and export levels. These variants provide alternative scenarios for normative evaluations of potential changes in regional and national production and resource use in agriculture. A parallel analysis also is possible of resource returns and commodity supply or shadow prices under these scenarios. An early one of these analyses reduced use of groundwater to recharge rates by the year 2000, used trend levels of yield increase, and decreased surface water availability according to projected nonfarm and varied population levels by the year 2000.[11] Some alternatives in supply control and environmental enhancement also were considered. Only two levels of export demand were used and gave somewhat conservative estimates for 2000. However, since domestic and export demands were exogenous to the model, variations for them can be combined in a scenario which better represents current expectations of future exports. If we select a combination of domestic and export demand levels which approach current projections, suppose groundwater use only at recharge rates by the year 2000, and project a diversion of 16 million acrefeet of water from agriculture to other uses under trend technology, we discover real supply (shadow) price increases of about 10 percent for feed grains, 11 percent for food grains, 10 percent for oilseeds, and 20 percent for meat, as a result of the restricted water supply. Fruits, vegetables, and nuts were exogenous to the model and thus shadow or supply prices were not generated for them. Either dampened or accentuated trends in total demands and agricultural technology would, of course, change these normative supply prices—or even any set of price estimates that might represent econometric projections of equilibrium prices. In every case, it is not easy to isolate future price changes due alone to demand changes,
technological changes, and reduced groundwater and
― 281 ― surface water supplies for irrigation. In a system in which all of these and related variables were endogenous, a change in magnitude of one variable over time would induce, to an extent, compensating changes in other variables. In models for the National Water Assessment (NWA), the Resources Conservation Act (RCA), and other national commissions or agencies, we generally have included land and water use, resource (land and water) returns, commodity shadow prices, and related variables on an endogenous basis. The dominating impact on farm commodity shadow prices results from the level of exports, the level of technological change assumed for all of U.S. agriculture, the amount of land included in the cropland base, and the tightness of restraints on soil loss. U.S. agriculture needs quite different amounts of water to meet specified commodity demands under various combinations of these variables or conditions. The shadow price of water and its relationship to the supply prices of agricultural commodities also differs greatly among these combinations or scenarios. A set of shadow prices generated for solutions of the RCA model for the year 2030 suggests the general interaction of these quantities.[12] The "required water use" and shadow or supply prices are shown in Table 11.1 for (a) a base-1 solution (A) which uses a standard (380 million acre) cropland base, (b) a base-2 solution (B) which allows the additional 127 million acres inventoried by the Soil Conservation Service[13] to be used in crop production, while technology is at trend levels and exports at levels of base1, (c) a high technology scenario (C) with yields increasing 60 percent faster annually than trend, while the land base and exports are the same as base2, (d) a low technology scenario (D) with yields increasing at about only 75 percent of trend, with the land base and exports the same as base-2, and (e) a maximum production scenario (E) where technology is at the high rate and the land base is the same as in base-2. It should be remembered that these are shadow prices resulting from a programming model specified to allow analysis of the scenarios described. To my knowledge, no other quantities exist to suggest potential values for these resources and commodities under the conditions set forth. The prices for water represent the value of water, at the margin, to produce the nation's output under the combination of conditions outlined. The supply prices for the commodities show the levels necessary to attain the prescribed level of production under the resource and technology conditions summarized. (Domestic demand and exports are
― 282 ―
Table 11.1 Indices of Shadow Prices for Five Scenarios in Land and Water Use, Technology, and Exports for 2030
Item
Base-1: Standard Land (A)
High Base-2: Tech., High High Land Land (B) (C)
Low Tech., High Land (D)
Maximum Production: High Land High Tech. (E)
Water use
100
91
65
109
210
Water 100 shadow price
63
44
63
280
Corn price
100
50
37
64
167
Wheat price
100
64
54
74
176
Soybean price
100
71
58
59
179
Cotton
100
70
71
77
139
projected to 2030 in terms of population, per capita income, and export trends.) The figures indicate that under trend technology and the potential of adding 127 million acres of land as inventoried by the SCS, water use could decline by 10 percent in comparison of base-2 with base-1. Water value would decline while commodity price would be 29-50 percent lower than in base-1, with a 33 percent smaller land base. Water use in the high technology-high land base decreases by 35 percent over base-1 solution. Supply prices for water and commodities also would be lower than in base-1. With a low technology but high land base (D), water use would increase by 9 percent over base-1, but production capacity, under high technology and the larger land base, would still be great enough that water value and commodity supply prices would be lower than in base-1. Hence, if water supplies for endogenous crops were reduced considerably below the D level, commodity prices could move upward considerably, exceeding those of base-1 which suppose only trend technology and exports.
The maximum production scenario explores the potential if production, under conditions of the high land base and high technology, were raised to the maximum level possible. To fully use this land would require 110 percent more acre-feet of water as
― 283 ― compared to the base-1 scenario. It also would increase water shadow price by over 100 percent and commodity prices by an average of about 67 percent over the "normal" or base-1 scenario. The higher water and commodity prices are a function of the level of production, a complete use of land, and the potential of an enlarged water use under very high exports. If this amount of water available in 2030 was reduced, then commodity prices would be raised further—purely as a reflection of restrained water supplies. Unfortunately, we did not run the model under this scenario. Another study organized to examine the potential of U.S. agriculture for meeting domestic and export demands for food, attaining soil and water conservation, and improving the environment, was the National Water Assessment (NWA) made for the Water Resources Council.[14] It also was a study of potentials made by a normative interregional and national programming simulation model since (a) quantities to be examined were those which had not been experienced in the past and thus lacked time series observation for econometric or statistical prediction, and (b) scenarios were designed to examine the full capacity or potential of the nation's agricultural resources under full production and certain restraints on soil erosion and water availability. The analysis was made for the year 2000 and assumed exports at current levels projected to that year, use of groundwater at recharge rates by 2000, and trend level yield increases. Under this base scenario of high exports but no other restraints on land use and water availability, water use for the endogenous crops and livestock was 86.7 million acre-feet. Prices (in 1972 dollars) were $1.82 for corn and $3.84 for wheat. Another scenario was the same except that (a) soil loss per acre per year was restrained to t-levels, (b) no further development of wet lands for crops was allowed after 1975, (c) the water supply available for agricultural uses was reduced (to 64.6 million acre-feet) to allow minimum streamflow for maintenance of water quality and protection of fish and wildlife, and (d) livestock wastes could not accumulate but must be returned to the land. Under these conditions, prices (in 1972 dollars) increased to $2.89 for corn and $8.82 for wheat. Soybean and cotton prices increased similarly. When soil loss restraints alone were applied, commodity prices remained near the level of the base scenario. Hence, the above increases could be imputed mainly to the water restraint which was reduced (for endogenous crops) from 87.6 million acre-feet to 64.6 million acre-feet.
― 284 ―
Water Price Changes Not all water prices have been subject to market forces. For some surface water, historically they have more or less been institutionalized at publicly subsidized rates. In recent times, some water previously used for agriculture has been purchased by other users and market transfers have taken place. However, the number of time series observations and the data base for these transfers is so sparse that statistical estimation of water demand functions, with their implied impact on commodity supplies and prices, is currently impossible. Accordingly, we made a normative analysis of demand for groundwater and surface water. While fully aware of the water rights, legal restraints and institutional arrangements which prevent sale, interfarm and interbasin movement of water, and market reflection of the marginal value productivity of water, we made some normative estimates of water demand under the premise that some knowledge is better than none.[15] In this programming study made up of 105 producing regions, we defined supplies of groundwater and surface water in each. We then set prices (costs for groundwater) at four levels for each. The initial price was the 1975 price; we then doubled, tripled, and quadrupled that, to give 16 price combinations of each, as illustrated in Table 11.2, where G1S1 is the initial level, G3 is groundwater price tripled, S3 is surface water tripled, and G4S4 represents both prices quadrupled.[16] The programmed water demand responses show, as normative estimates, the price of water associated with each quantity used and, in a sense, also are proxy representations of the price of water which might exist at different levels of water availabilities—under the usual claim of the limitations which prevail under such models. (As mentioned before, we are entirely aware of the limitations of such models and the particular assumptions underlying them.) Reduction in water use at the highest prices of water are only about half that at the lowest price of water in Table 11.3. These sizable reductions in water bring only modest increases in programmed commodity supply prices. In effect, these are changes in commodity prices reflecting reduced quantities of water used for irrigation (induced by higher water prices, but should parallel reductions in water use made through other means). The resulting commodity price increases in Table 11.3 are smaller than those resulting from a smaller (and somewhat similar pattern of) reduction for the NWA assessment which (a) assumes a higher level of exports, and (b) limits the amount of land which can be
― 285 ―
Table 11.2 Groundwater and Surface Water Price
Combinations at Varying Levels of Water Availability Surface Water
Groundwater Price Levels
Price Levels
G1
G2
G3
G4
S1
G1S1
G2S1
G3S1
G4S1
S2
G1S2
G2S2
G3S2
G4S2
S3
G1S3
G2S3
G3S3
G4S3
S4
G1S4
G2S4
G3S4
G4S4
Table 11.3 Indices of Water Use and Prices of Endogenous Crops Under Four Price Combinations for Water Water Price Levels Item
G1S1 G2S2 G3S3 G4S4
Groundwater usea
100
59
46
44
Surface water usea 100
85
65
51
Price corn (bu.)
100
100
103
105
Price wheat (bu.)
100
104
106
110
Soybeans (cwt.)
100
102
103
105
Pork (cwt.)
100
102
103
105
Fed beef (cwt.)
100
103
104
106
a
Million acrefeet.
― 286 ― converted to crops. Similarly, the commodity price increases are less than those indicated in Table 11.1 for the RCA analysis, where added water use also is necessary[17] for the maximum level of production and exports, because the RCA estimates also assume (a) much higher levels of exports, and (b) all available land is cropped. For the results in Table 11.3, the land base for the lowest price set is only 380 million acres. Hence, as less water is used, varying amounts of the 127 million potential crop acres indicated in the SCS inventory are able to substitute for reduced water use at a higher price. From this analysis, it would appear that over a considerable range (perhaps somewhat less than suggested in the above quantities) of reductions in water use could take place without causing large increases in commodity supply prices if (a) the level of exports is modest, (b) only a trend level of technology is supposed, and (c) a considerable amount of arable land is still available. However, the several sets of data suggest that with a high level of exports and complete use of the nation's potential cropland base, as might happen sometime in the future, declining water availability (due to diversion of water to other uses, higher energy prices, and depletion of groundwater) could cause considerable increases in commodity supply prices. With sufficiently high energy prices, extended depletion of groundwater stocks, and diversion of water to other sectors from agriculture, water prices could be considerably higher than those used in Table 11.2. For the low price combination in Table 11.2, the average national prices are respectively only $9.80 and $7.83 for groundwater and surface water.[18] For the highest combinations, these prices are quadrupled. But the possibility of much higher water prices is suggested by Ayer and Hoyt[19] and by situations such as that quoted below: "Ten years ago Colorado-Big Thompson water rights were selling for $240 an acre-foot and I thought that was really high," said Earl Phipps, director of the Northern Colorado Water Conservancy District. "Three years ago when the water rights were up to $850 per acre-foot, if you had told me the price would hit $2,000 by 1979, I'd have said you were crazy. That's where it is today. I still can't believe it! . . . Six weeks later the price had gone to $2,250.
In 1947 it was $1.50."[20] Water prices considerably higher than those used in Table 11.2 could cause a drastic decline in water use and thus larger increases in commodity supply prices. Each further decrement in
― 287 ― water use would have an increasing impact on agricultural production and commodity prices. It is possible that the "long run" aggregate commodity supply function potential in agriculture parallels is of this nature: over some range, it may remain highly elastic as opportunities remain to convert more land to crops and to further adjust the allocation and technology of water use. But eventually, with complete use of all potential cropland which can be converted at reasonable costs, higher prices and smaller supplies of water and exhaustion of reallocation possibilities for water, the supply elasticity may decline greatly with a sharp upturn in the commodity supply function. A good many persons suggest that we have already "turned the corner." My own estimate is that, for the reasons mentioned earlier, we will "turn the corner" into an era of rising real prices for food sometime in the next 20 years.
Changes in Institutional and Technical Possibilities From the standpoint of irrigation water, possibilities of remaining on the flatter portion of the curve for some time rests on schemes which might remove institutional restraints in water allocation, application of improved water saving technologies, and improved distribution systems. Technological possibilities are numerous, including improved water delivery systems, water saving techniques such as laser or dead leveling of fields, trickle irrigation, greater pump efficiency, water scheduling, and others. There is even considerable evidence that farmers use water beyond profit maximizing levels, or even beyond yield maximizing levels, due to low administered prices of water.[21] Since water response functions indicate diminishing marginal yields, use of given water on larger land areas also could help maintain commodity supplies under lowered water availability. Many of these technological changes would likely be induced under much smaller supplies of, and higher prices for, irrigation water. These conditions might also help cause removal of institutional restraints which stand in the way of the most productive use of water. If so, they would dampen the impact of reduced water supplies for agriculture on commodity prices. The importance of other variables and conditions (export demand and related production in importing countries, land used in the U.S., domestic technology trends, energy prices, etc.)
― 288 ― besides declining water supplies, also is emphasized in another study using the Ogallala Aquifer area in an interregional and national programming model.[22] This study indicated that rising energy prices are likely to be as important as groundwater mining and greater pumping depth in increasing water costs by the year 2000. With exports at higher levels in 2000 (corn at 5,424 million bushels, wheat at 3,213 million bushels, soybeans at 1,890 million bushels, and cotton at 4,743 thousand bales), an increase in energy prices from moderate to high levels would raise corn supply price from $2.45 to $3.31, wheat from $4.55 to $6.24, soybeans from $5.63 to $7.42, and cotton from $207 to $267 (1979 dollars). The increased supply prices result not only from higher costs of water due to both greater prices and greater pumping depths, and thus the use of less water, but also from the high level of demand, expansion of crop acreage to less productive land, and some reduced use of fertilizer. Mainly, I have been discussing major basic feed, cereal, and fiber crops as their production and prices are reflected in the quantitative analysis. They, along with pork, beef, and dairy products, are treated as endogenous to the models. Other irrigated crops and poultry are included, but on an exogenous basis, supposing that they will be produced in the projected amounts (based on consumption trends and per capita incomes and food competition). Of the 60.7 million irrigated acres (including pasture) in 1977 estimated by the NRI,[23] 55.7 million acres were in cropland, 5.0 million acres were in pasture, and 50.2 million acres were in the 17 western states. The large acreage of cropland not vegetables, fruits or nuts, and the 5 million acres of irrigated pasture are included in the above models. (Because of the use of irrigated land for high value crops in the West, about 25 percent of the value of crops grown in the United States is attributable to irrigation. About 13 percent of U.S. cropland and 11 percent of land, including pasture, is irrigated.) The high value crops (fruits, vegetables, nuts) are a small portion of irrigated acreage and total cropland acreage in the United States. They are, however, a large proportion of specialized crop acreage, particularly in the West. In general, their high value would give them comparative advantage over other crops in the claim to water. However, their prices would be especially affected by increased water prices stemming from reduced water supplies. Whereas dryland production would dilute the price effect of smaller water supplies for grains, cotton, hay, and pasture, it would not do so as greatly for specialized high-value vegetable crops grown in multiple-
― 289 ― cropping systems. Thus, we would expect the price effects to be relatively larger under reduced water supplies than those discussed above for
conventional field crops.
Elasticity Impacts Another potential means of evaluating the impact on commodity prices of reduced irrigation water would be to estimate reduction in food production due to restrained water supplies and relate it to price elasticities of demand for each commodity involved. To do so, we would need to know the reduction in water drawn away from each crop, estimate its decline in production (for otherwise "normal" conditions), and effectively apply its price elasticity of demand to the change. Aside from programming models which can normatively estimate such reallocations relative to a stated objective function, there is no ready quantitative or statistical means to predict the pattern of these reallocations at a future time when higher energy prices and increased pumping depths reduce groundwater supplies while competing sectors reduce surface supplies. Hence, there may be little reason, in a predictive sense, to spend any great time on expected price changes for individual commodities. Most of the price elasticities of demand estimated for food in aggregate in the United States over the last 40 years range from –.20 to –.33, with –.25 being somewhat the "central tendency."[24] Hence, we might expect that each 1 percent reduction in domestic food supply resulting from reduced water supplies would increase food price by about 4 percent—other things remaining equal, on both the supply and demand sides.[25] This would be the more expected level of price change if grain export markets paralleled those of the 1950s and 1960s. At that time, supply controls were in effect. U.S. exports were modest, and the overwhelming outlet for major export crops was the domestic market, with exports moving particularly under public assistance. However, since export markets have grown greatly over the past decade, foreign (world) demand elasticities for U.S. exports now may be most relevant in gauging the effect of reduced U.S. water supplies on commodity prices. Estimates of these elasticities are available for only a few major export commodities, cover a wide range of numerical values, and are greatly tempered by the supply elasticities of the importing countries.[26] They are expected to be larger than domestic elasticities, and, as
― 290 ― an average, are probably about –1.33 for grains which are the major U.S. export commodities. In these terms, a 1 percent reduction in output due to a reduction in water supplies to produce grain would increase price by about .75 percent.
Distribution and Equity Aspects Reduced supplies and higher prices for water would likely bring about increases in the marginal productivity of water, thus dampening somewhat the impact of reduced supplies on commodity prices. A complex of water rights and institutional restraints now stands in the way of prices in allocating water more nearly in line with its marginal productivity. These rights and institutional arrangements have value to the users; to abolish them would force a capital loss on farmers to whom they attach. Hence, compensation to these farmers through better access to markets for their water, or by other means, is necessary if improved allocations of water are to be realized. These means may not be created soon, even though they would lessen the impact of reduced water supplies on food prices. However, with the proportion of farmers in the population tending towards zero, a means may be more readily created if the real price of food advances rapidly.
Discussion: Kenneth R. Farrell In his inimitable style, Heady has dealt competently and comprehensively with a very complex subject. As he correctly points out, there can be no unequivocal empirical determination of commodity price impacts from a decline in western irrigated agriculture. The region is but a part of a large system of national and international markets for agricultural commodities— markets in which numerous economic, technological, and institutional variables interact in complex, dynamic ways in the course of highly uncertain future events. Nevertheless, Heady has given us some possible "boundary" outcomes to reflect upon in our speculations and planning for the future.
― 293 ― For purposes of discussion although at the risk of oversimplifying Heady's conclusions, I have chosen to highlight three of his principal points. (1) The future supply of water for irrigation in the western states will decline. I concur with this, but think it important to amplify in three respects. The first is to note that Heady is referring to the economic supply of water, i.e., for any given quantity of water, the price (unit cost) to agriculture will increase, for reasons he has cited (increased costs of pumping groundwater and increased competition from other areas). This is quite different from saying that agriculture will confront absolute physical constraints on water supply. Second, we should note that the economic supply of water now differs substantially among areas within the region, and that such differentials could well widen in the decades ahead, depending upon the rate of mining of underground supplies, the costs of energy, and
the market or institutional arrangements by which water is allocated among competing uses. As Frederick has pointed out in a recent report, the locus of growth in irrigated agriculture in the West during the past 25 years has moved from south to north, and will so remain in the decades ahead.[1] Finally, we should note that while competition for surface water will inevitably heighten, to the economic disadvantage of agriculture, the political-administrative institutions governing the allocation of that water are slow to change. Notwithstanding the imperatives of economics, agriculture may continue to muster sufficient political strength to defer major reallocation of supplies or major modifications in water prices for some time to come. (2) ". . . the impact on commodity prices of reduced water supplies to agriculture will depend on the availability of water-substituting inputs and technologies." Such substitution includes the possibility of dryland farming of land now in irrigation, land now in other uses, and the adoption of current or new water-conserving management practices and technologies. As Heady notes, one of the public challenges we confront in the context of rising real costs of resources is that of inducing R and D programs which relate technologies to prospective resource prices. With respect to the substitution of land for water, options differ widely within the West. In states such as California, the option is extremely limited. In the Great Plains states, the technical possibilities of shifting to dryland cropping are greater; but the economic costs of farm operators would be substantial. A recent study of the six-state Ogallala aquifer region concluded
― 294 ― that, under conditions of crop prices and yield relationships of 1975-80 and with currently projected rates of groundwater depletion, a transition to dryland farming over the next 40 years would reduce gross farm income in the region by 25 to 50 percent.[2] With respect to bringing land into crop production from other uses, the greatest possibilities would seem to be outside the region in the Southeast and in the upper Midwest. Heady observes that there is a lack of knowledge of irrigation technologies and institutional changes which might be induced to improve and make more productive the use of water. It is frequently observed that application of water in agriculture is excessive from a technical or physiological point of view. What are the potential physical savings on water use given current technology? With new or improved technologies? What are the economically feasible savings of water under alternative technical and water-commodity price relationships? Such questions would be appropriate subjects for interdisciplinary research involving agronomists, irrigation scientists, and economists.
(3) The general conclusion which Heady appears to draw from the results of his several models is that water reductions could take place over a considerable range, without causing large increases in commodity supply prices, if the level of exports is modest, the trend level of technology is maintained, and the 127 million acres of cultivable land inventoried by SCS are available for conversion to cropland. Heady goes on to say, however, that at some point the commodity supply function could become quite inelastic, and that a combination of high exports and declining water availability could result in considerable increases in commodity supply prices. This conclusion is in accord with those of Crosson, and Crosson and Brubaker in their recently published reports.[3] Heady's analysis illustrates clearly the sensitivity of American agriculture to export demand and in turn the economic "leverage" which exports could exert upon the price of commodities and use of resources in the United States. As he points out, there is great uncertainty concerning the future strength of that demand. In conclusion, I would like to comment briefly on one of the premises of Heady's paper, indeed a premise of this entire volume—the need for additional information and research to narrow the bands of uncertainty concerning the basic issue, "Impacts of Limited Water for Agriculture in the Semiarid West." I have suggested a need for interdisciplinary research to better estimate the potential savings of water under alternative economic and technological scenarios. In addition, we need better,
― 295 ― more complete estimates of the economic and social value of water in its alternative uses in the principal watersheds of the region and, within agriculture, better and more complete estimates of the value of water among alternative agricultural uses. Although a substantial body of such information is scattered among research institutions, it is of uneven quality and currency and probably not easily additive. The report to the National Water Commission in 1972 by Young and Gray provides an excellent conceptual framework within which to begin a coordinated regional or national effort to construct such estimates.[4] Finally, I would urge my fellow economists to seek more effective research alliances with other disciplines, particularly law, to examine and analyze the institutions which govern the use of water, to document the social costs and benefits, and the respective distributions of each under current, alternative, or modified institutions. As social scientists, we have a responsibility to induce innovation by providing relevant, usable research results. The need is neither new nor revolutionary. It is simply more pressing.
Discussion: David L. Watt This excellent chapter provides a long needed perspective on the relationship of agricultural resource problems in the U.S. to world commodity markets. Because many of the land-extensive commodities irrigated in the United States are grain crops, and the grain market is indeed a world market, we are attempting to measure the impacts of one possibility among many unknowns.
― 296 ― The 1978 Census of Agriculture indicates that less than 11 percent of U.S. cropland is irrigated. The chapter points out appropriate evidence that there is great potential for improvement in the efficiency with which water is being used. Between 1949 and 1978 irrigated land in farms increased from 25 million acres to 50 million acres. This increase has been fostered by technological improvements in irrigation techniques—and by extensive expansion in international trade, particularly in the last 15 years. Between 1967 and 1981 the annual average productivity growth of U.S. agriculture was 1.66. U.S. agricultural exports have increased at a rate of 6.7 percent per year, while aggregate farm output has increased only at a rate of 1.7 percent. Productivity growth has permitted the increase in output to be accomplished with a negligible increase in the quantity of inputs. However, changing relative prices have created significant change in the mix of the inputs used. For example, labor use declined by 35 percent during that period, while quantity of agricultural chemicals used increased by 74 percent. If agricultural exports continue to grow at the same rate as during the last 15 years, and if domestic supply, demand, and productivity growth continue at trend levels, the increasing importance of exports as a demand for U.S. agricultural commodities will indeed cause real prices of U.S. commodities to increase, as indicated in the chapter. However, the impact of reduced water to produce grain is a long-term adjustment. With other countries having time to adjust to a changing situation, both in supply and demand, price impacts will be dampened much more than the amount estimated from currently accepted short-term world demand elasticities. The availability of additional land and yield potentials for crops is handled well. The only conclusion is that sufficient land and yield technology is available to meet significant growth in demand. The question is simply, "What price will be required to fill future demand?" Expansion in demand will have its greatest impact on the quantity of irrigation.
It would be useful if we had enough knowledge about the future to justify statistical and econometric studies with reasonable prediction errors. It is essential for strategic planning by corporations and for capital investment decisions in the public sector to have an estimated future economic environment, including prices, on which to base decisions. Public Law 49587, October 22, 1976, commissioned a study to determine the cost and
― 297 ― benefits of reasonable options to ensure an adequate supply of food to the nation and promote the economic vitality of the High Plains region.[1] In this study, commodity supply price estimates over the life of any policies which would be implemented were required to determine the benefits of alternative policy options. Also, the economic vitality of the High Plains region would be greatly affected by commodity supply prices. A baseline scenario was developed under the assumption that no explicit Congressional actions would be undertaken with respect to the declining water situation in the Ogallala. For the baseline scenario, the productivity of the agricultural sector was assumed to grow at a 1.5 percent per year rate for the near term, and decline to 1.0 percent by the year 2020. Prices paid by farmers for production inputs were assumed to increase slightly faster than the price of all goods and services in the U.S. The projections for U.S. population and income growth, combined with the assumptions of growth in international demand, resulted in demand increasing by 1.75 percent per year in the near term and declining to 1.25 percent by the year 2020. These assumptions result in aggregate farm output measured as an index (1967 equals 100) rising to 210 by the year 2020. Prices received by farmers in this scenario experience a real growth rate of approximately .25 percent per year from the 1967 base. For this scenario, the total cropland harvested makes a gradual increase up to 388.5 million acres by the year 2000 and continues up to 435.1 million acres by the year 2020. Of the cropland harvested, 53 million acres are projected to be irrigated by the year 2000 and 61 million acres by the year 2020. These results imply that significant growth in agricultural production can be achieved without a large increase in irrigated acreage and only a slight increase in real prices received by farmers. In the High Plains study, several management strategies were studied to determine their impacts.[2] Of significant interest in looking at reductions in water use was management strategy 2, which looked at policies designed to force reduction in the amount of water pumped for irrigation. Researchers from the six states involved developed estimates of changes in production in each of their respective states from the baseline. The change in High Plains production was divided by the baseline U.S. production to reflect the percentage change in production caused by the new policy. The study showed that there are many factors which offset the reduction in available water for irrigation. Most descriptive and typical is the impact upon corn
production. In
― 298 ― management strategy 2 the percentage reduction in national production (with prices and other factors fixed) was 1 percent for 1990 and approximately 1.5 percent for both 2000 and 2020. When inserted into an aggregate model for the U.S. agricultural sector, the production impacts were partially offset by increased price effects and production increases in other parts of the U.S. The 1990 equilibrium production was reduced by only .5 percent, production by the 2000 was reduced by almost 1 percent, and production in 2020 was reduced by 1.25 percent. The price increase over baseline in this scenario was .75 percent in 1990, 1.8 percent for the year 2000, and only 1 percent by 2020. Thus, the net elasticity of change increases with the length this particular scenario is in effect. Net price elasticity is .66 in 1990 and rises to 1.20 by 2020. Indeed, the distributional aspects are the most serious problems associated with reduced irrigation water in the West. The significance of this is highlighted when we recognize that reduced production of agricultural commodities in the West will result in higher net farm income for the agricultural sector at the national level. The most redeeming feature of the current problem is that increased attention is being directed toward determining more efficient ways of using water. We are also seeing significant improvements in the economic use of water in agriculture.
Chapter 12— Impacts upon Business Communities by Vernon M. Crowder
Abstract This chapter is an examination of the probable impacts of limited water supplies on agribusiness, banking, and the resulting effects on the economy. Since I am an agricultural industry analyst for a major commercial lender in California, the primary focus of my discussion will be California. It is reasonable to make an induction from California to the western region, because the situation in our state reflects that of the West. This analysis begins with a discussion of the major assumptions of water use, availability, and development, particularly in relation to California agriculture. Assumptions about water are a topic of debate; nonetheless, there is a consensus among the experts in the agricultural industry.
An Examination of Assumptions Assumption 1 World demand for food has been rising and is expected to continue increasing. The world population is not only continuing to grow, but income per capita has also risen. Increases in world income should boost the demand for many of the "luxury" crops grown in California, such as fruits and nuts. In contrast, many developing countries are making attempts to increase their production of staples such as grains. Since real world income is projected to increase nearly twice as fast as estimated population, there will be an increase in future world per capita income, and, therefore, a probable increased demand for California agricultural goods. (These estimates were supplied by the Wharton econometric model.)
― 300 ―
Assumption 2 Energy prices will continue to rise. Costs will increase because energy resources are becoming scarce and more expensive to develop. The cost increases are not likely to be as high as the last decade, however. The cost of energy is a direct input in the cost of water. Energy to claim water is necessary, whether it is pumped from basins or transported across territory to an area of need. Even if water is developed and used in the same area, energy will play a major role since irrigation is energy-intensive.
Assumption 3 The capital cost of developing water supplies has risen sharply and will continue to increase. Reservoir and other water facilities were less expensive decades ago when compared to many of the projects on the drawing board today. The increase in project cost can be attributed to the effects of inflation on inputs—labor and materials—and the sophistication in engineering that is required for remaining sites. In addition, safety and environmental concerns have also contributed to higher capital costs. For example, the proposed facility at Auburn or the enlargement of the Shasta reservoir may result in water that costs more than $300 an acre-foot. In comparison, some projects built prior to the Central Valley Project cost only a few dollars an acre-foot.
Assumption 4 Conservation will be very difficult for agriculture. Contrary to popular belief, agricultural water consumption is already relatively efficient. Most water is reused until it is lost to transpiration, evaporation, or runoff. Very little is lost to evaporation or plant transpiration; most is lost to runoff where it ends in the ocean to begin the hydrological cycle anew. Regardless of the type of irrigation, what one grower does not use is typically used by a neighboring grower. Many growers are using more efficient types of irrigation systems, such as drip or sprinkler, for the purpose of reducing energy and labor costs. This reduced consumption of water, and the resulting decreases in runoff, mean that the next water user "down river" must obtain other water. Therefore, an increase in efficiency in a particular grower's irrigation system has negligible impacts on the overall use of water by agriculture. Essentially, there is little hope for solving future water shortages by conservation without taking land out of production.
― 301 ―
Assumption 5 The transfer of water rights will be very difficult because of institutional and political barriers. In addition to the legal prohibitions to transfer, there is the highly emotional reaction by those not getting the use of water as the result of a transfer. To illustrate, Los Angeles' Department of Water and Power thought that its water rights were very secure in the Owens Valley, since they had purchased vast amounts of land in the area. However, recent court actions have made these water rights dubious. In another case the emotional nature of the water-market issue was evident when the voters of Yuba County turned down a measure to allow Kern County water users to pay for the expansion of a local water reservoir. In the proposed measure, Kern County would have paid for the right to use the water while it was in surplus, leaving it for local use in times of need. In spite of the potential benefit to Yuba County, the voters rejected the plan as a "raid" on their water rights. Since the right of appropriation in California deems that water should go to beneficial use, there will always be controversy, because the evaluation of "beneficial" can vary by individual opinion.
Assumption 6 Urban water use will continue to increase, resulting in more competition for scarce water supplies. Theorists point out that urban water consumption will decline per capita because of more dense housing. However, it is unlikely that such reduction in per capita water consumption will offset increases in
populations. According to the National Planning Association, California's population is projected to increase 15 percent by the year 2000. Compounding the problem is the loss of water entitlements to Arizona. As a result of the 1964 federal court ruling, the Metropolitan Water District, which is the primary water distributor to Southern California, will lose more than half of its water entitlements once the Central Arizona Project is completed in 1985.
Assumption 7 Political in-fighting between different interest groups is blocking the way to additional water development. In addition to the friction between environmentalists, farmers, and urban dwellers, there are divisions within each group as well. The recent battle over the California Peripheral Canal referendum is a good example. Agriculture, which normally votes as a bloc, split over the
― 302 ― proposition, and large agricultural interests were allied with their traditional rivals, the environmentalists. Such coalitions do not last, however, as was demonstrated on the subsequent Water Resources initiative. The polarization of interests has prevented any progress in the development of additional water supplies. I fear that such battling will continue until the situation worsens sufficiently to demand a resolution. Evidence demonstrates that the demand for water is continuing to increase, and that development of additional supplies is doubtful. Since conservation alone cannot offset consumption enough to avoid reduced agricultural production, current facilities will be less than adequate.
An Analysis of Impacts The major impact of limited water supplies will be a reduction in agricultural production. Any decrease in production for the long term will mean a lessening of overall economic activity. To illustrate the importance of agriculture to the overall state economy, the California Crop and Livestock Reporting Service estimates that three additional dollars are generated in the state's economy for every dollar of farm receipts. This means that agriculture accounted for $55.6 billion in California during 1981. For the same year, Security Pacific Bank reports a state gross product of $355.2 billion.
Change in crop selection as a result of higher water prices is a commonly cited impact of water scarcity. However, the primary determinants of crop selection are market prices and the availability of alternative crops. In many instances, the availability of water is more important than price. While sufficiently strong market prices can possibly offset higher water costs, uncertain availability makes it less feasible to plant crops that depend upon regular irrigation, or crops that cannot tolerate any long periods of drought. The quality of water, the amount of dissolved solids (salt), is also influencing the selection of crops. The amount of capital invested in land is also an important factor in crop selection. As the value of land increases and more capital investment is necessitated, operators seek higher returns per acre. The predominant means of obtaining higher returns is to make additional improvements to the land by planting permanent crops such as trees or vines. Ironically, such intensive farming usually means a greater use of water resources. While
― 303 ― alfalfa is usually cited as an inefficient use of water resources in comparison to cotton, orchards and vineyards use much more water per acre annually. But the higher returns associated with the permanent crops justify the greater production costs, including the increased water use. To illustrate, Table 12.1 indicates what portion of production costs in the San Joaquin Valley is for irrigation. The two different percentages are for areas of low- versus high-priced water. As other production costs increase, the costs of irrigating become less significant.
Table 12.1 Irrigation Costs as a Portion of Total Production Costs Crop
Low Priced Water
High Priced Water
Alfalfa
36
68
Grains
22
52
Cotton
19
48
Processing tomatoes 19
47
Almonds
17
38
Thompson seedless grapes
12
34
Citrus
12
33
Table grapes
7
22
Peaches and plums
5
15
The immediate impact of rising water prices or decreasing availability is on land values. Real estate that is entitled to less expensive and/or more available supplies commands a higher price on the market than farmland without available water supplies or supplied only by very expensive water resources. To illustrate, the following examples come from Kern County, at the southern end of the San Joaquin Valley. Open land in the western portion of the county served by the Berenda Mesa Irrigation District sold for between $2,200 and $2,400 per acre this
― 304 ― year. Only expensive State Water Project (SWP) water is available in this area, and there is no groundwater available. Where groundwater is available, as in Kern County's Simi-Tropic Irrigation District, similar land sold for about $3,700 this year. In the northern portion of the county served by the North Kern Water District, the area is supplied by both the SWP and the relatively inexpensive Central Valley Project, and groundwater is also available. Comparable land there sold for $4,800 this year.
Conclusions This chapter assumes that energy prices will rise, capital costs for water development will continue to increase, urban water demand will grow, and world demand for food and fiber grown in California will be greater in the future. Additionally, assumptions are that new conservation, greater transfers of water rights, and more water development will be very difficult. Ultimately, this means less water will be available in the future. Water costs will rise and because of less water availability, agriculture will
have to reduce production. This will have a damaging effect on the overall economy. Naturally, agribusiness, banking, and other sectors will feel the effects. With regard to the remaining agricultural production, higher water costs and less water availability will have great impact on the value of land. There will be significant changes in land values corresponding to its associated water costs. Higher land values will encourage more intense agriculture that eventually challenges water resources to even greater extents. The situation in San Diego, where both water costs and land values are very high, provides an example; agriculture will continue despite water scarcity. Agriculture under water constraints will be very different, though, since more intensive planting will call for more efficient irrigation techniques. The picture seems bleak. Additional water development would help to alleviate many of the detrimental impacts cited here. Such development cannot come about, however, unless special interest groups find mutually agreeable solutions to our water issues. The in-fighting among agricultural interests will have to be resolved to facilitate agreements.
― 305 ―
Discussion: Dorsey R. Meyer, Sr. Two primary considerations apply to the general topic of water as it concerns agriculture in the western states. First is the political process, which makes any future water plans difficult. In California the Peripheral Canal issue and the Water Conservation initiative of 1982 are both clear illustrations of this political problem. Second, too little thought is given to the idea that agricultural production is essential to the welfare of man. A balance must be created between domestic, industrial, and agricultural needs. Vital crop production occurs very often in arid areas dependent upon irrigation water originating in watersheds not always adjacent to productive lands. Yet agriculture competes with the constant demand for water by metropolitan, domestic, and industrial users. Crowder covers the economic effects of water shortages on the overall California and western agricultural economy. Our history shows that we have maintained low farm prices in order to control consumer food prices. This is unfortunate, as the return on investment to the American farmer here in the West often is inadequate, and limits his ability to seek solutions to the problems of water.
The chapter states that less water will be available for agricultural production. Yet the same amount of water exists on this planet that existed before domestic agriculture was initiated. We process it, change it, drink it, use it, but it nevertheless remains. The question is one of distribution and utilization of this reusable resource, in contrast to hydro-carbon fuels which are a finite resource. Domestic, industrial, and agricultural users must be stewards of water. The distribution of available resources needs adequate long range planning, taking all three categories of users into consideration. The increased recycling of wastewater, both for industrial and agricultural use, also provides a partial solution to water shortages. Tail waters which carry impurities and high salinity will be utilized in future more than at present. Research indicates that it is possible to raise two bales of cotton per acre on land with higher salt water content, as high as 6,000 parts per million, compared to the normal 500 parts per million contained in water from the California Aqueduct. This possibility is offset somewhat by salt buildup in soil, but nevertheless the benefits of recycling remain.
― 306 ― The redistribution of water in subcanals and thence into furrows, overhead devices, etc., to produce crops in the semiarid West requires a great deal of energy. Since energy prices are expected to increase, energy needs to obtain water for agriculture will become even more acute in the near future. Political decision makers must be continually informed and properly persuaded that agriculture has limitations as to what it can afford to pay for surface or underground irrigation water. The domestic and industrial water user must bear an even larger share of the cost of distributing water in the West from one point to another, and relieve some of the burden from agriculture. Economic production of farm crops must be maintained to keep consumer food prices reasonable. Costs of water development are escalating daily. Because of the slow process necessary for approval and eventual construction of facilities for moving water, costly projects are inevitable. Here again, consumers, industry, and agriculture must take a commensurate share of the burden. In publications such as the California-Arizona Farm Press, we see methods being undertaken by various growers, educators, and extension services to improve and make more efficient agricultural use of the available water supply. Some of the more exciting developments are the use of computers, drip irrigation, and modified overhead irrigation using the drip principle. It is interesting to note that much of this technology is coming from Israel, where necessity has been the mother of invention in respect to agricultural use of water. More effective use of water by agriculturalists is progressing in many areas. Improvement in pumps, drip irrigation, recycling of wastewater, and the
development of agricultural crops which have higher salt tolerance, will add to more control of water by farm growers. A total water program needs to be created for the semiarid West. With a sufficient amount of water, hundreds of thousands of acres can yet be brought into production in climatic areas most favorable to high production of both food and fiber. The problem, obviously, is to transfer water from where it is created to the place where it can be utilized. Arizona represents a strong potential area, in my view, for the additional development of agricultural acreage, but the metropolitan areas will probably use up the water available and prevent further significant agricultural development in the Arizona desert. A new master water plan which incorporates all of the western states is badly needed.
― 307 ― If no new water is developed in the next decade, it will be a tragedy resulting in exaggerated costs in future. Tax legislation is also badly needed in regard to our land resource in the western states. In the near future, governmental control of all underground water will probably occur, as in Arizona, with the resulting higher cost of water for growers. Land with available water will be expensive, and land without water will not be fully utilized. Because of economic pressures on growers, the development of various machines and new approaches to more efficient crop production and reduced operating costs are processes of dire necessity, rather than desire. Though some say that the western states may be less competitive in agricultural production with areas that have greater water resources, I do not agree with this view. Many of the western irrigated lands have more favorable climatic conditions, and with proper research and development, recycling and proper use of water, the West can continue to outproduce, per acre, other parts of the nation. The semiarid West must share in untapped water resources. One of the constant problems, however, is that underground aquifers are continually being reduced without proper replenishment. In the EPA Journal of March 1980, Eckhardt C. Beck, Administrator for Water and Waste Management, stated: "Some of the underground aquifers in Arizona, for example, drop ten feet per year, and are replenished at the rate of about a quarter of an inch per year."[1] This clearly illustrates that mining of underground water is only a temporary cheap supply at best. I have great confidence in the ingenuity of our western farmer and agribusiness community to solve problems, including water supplies. Farms
in the West will become larger, as far as commercial production is concerned. The very small part-time farm will also advance, but these farms do not produce a high percentage of our essential food production. All of us in agribusiness serving agriculture today are aware of the problems facing agriculture, including water resources. A purposeful depression of farm profits is an ancient strategy to hold down basic food costs, but is in my opinion self-defeating in the long run. It is far better to permit growers to make adequate returns on their investment and thus be able to spend adequate amounts to solve their own problems. The almost $14 billion produced as revenue for California farm products in 1981 represents 10 percent of the nation's gross farm receipts, derived from only 3 percent of the country's farm
― 308 ― acreage. Western agriculture is a force to be reckoned with. If growers can derive a profit from their hard efforts, they can produce, to the amazement of the entire world, food and fiber needed not only by this country, but much of the world at large.
Chapter 13— Social Impacts on Rural Communities by Albert Schaffer and Ruth C. Schaffer
Abstract The adoption of dryland farming as the availability of water declines creates serious difficulties for local institutions and disturbs the community's relationships with its residents and the larger society. This chapter examines those local institutions—banks, services, and leadership—which respond to the spread of dryland farming in ways which increase pressures on residents to relocate elsewhere. The dwindling supply of credit and the closing of local businesses signify a reallocation of wealth from the rural to larger, more prosperous communities. Migration of farmers, business, and professional people weakens leadership and undermines the community's adaptive capacity at a time when problems become more serious. This chapter also explores various adaptive measures available to rural communities. These include efforts to diversify the local economy, strengthen local organizations, and establish intercommunity and regional
coalitions to gain assistance from the federal level in addressing the area's water problems. The outcome of these efforts over the next few decades may be indicative of how America will cope with a diminished resource base, either through reduction in scale of organization or improvements in the environment's carrying capacity.
The advance of industrialism has been marked by an enormous increase in productive capacity and in man's capacity to rearrange the natural environment. Sprawling cities have developed in strategic locations, linked by multi-modal transportation systems. Natural resources in huge quantities are removed daily from the earth. Changes in farming have been no less remarkable, as evident in the increasing use of machinery, in size of farms, and in declining farm population.[1] Today only three out of a hundred workers are engaged in farming compared to almost four out of ten workers in 1900.
― 310 ― One threat to agriculture, besides overproduction and falling income, is the depletion of water in the arid and semiarid West and in those areas of the High Plains dependent on the Ogallala Aquifer. Many areas of irrigated agriculture will shift to dryland farming in the next few decades, a change presently occurring in the southernmost area of the High Plains. The reduction in crop yields and farm income will have serious consequences for farm communities and their residents, changes which will spread to areas undergoing this agricultural transition. This chapter considers several dimensions of the process of community decline: first, the local structures which play a strategic role in the adaptive process; second, the socialpsychological consequences of change, especially for those who sell their farms; and third, measures whereby stability may be achieved at an economic and population level higher than otherwise might be possible. The community, especially that based on family farms, plays a vital role in the operation of American society by linking residents to basic values and social institutions.[2] Residents participate in the larger society mainly through involvement in local institutions. The community can facilitate integration since it is part of and contributes to national patterns of interdependence. The market economy involves all regions and localities in a nationwide and global system of exchange and resource allocation.[3] The community participates in this system mainly through export activities which, in the case of rural localities, consist of various farm products that provide capital for local producers by meeting needs of organizations throughout society. These features of the economy may have a large influence on the material well-being and status of local residents. Where the majority can achieve important goals through participation in the farm
sustenance system, allegiance to core beliefs and values is likely to be strong.[4] The legitimacy of the authority structure which sustains the capitalist economy, and such features as private property and the sanctity of contractual relationships, will be widely accepted. Productive labor in the local economy which is well rewarded has important psychological consequences, due in part to the value system. Success is largely defined in materialistic terms, to be achieved through disciplined personal effort.[5] Those who attain these ends usually enjoy respectable class and status positions, and receive the plaudits of colleagues, friends, and loved ones. These significant others become the foundation of the actor's esteem and self-confidence.
― 311 ―
Arid Lands and the High Plains Adapting the community to water scarcity is not unique to the United States. One-third of the earth's land area is considered arid,[6] an environment characterized by ten to fifteen inches of annual rainfall, and the frequent occurrence of drought, erosion, and famine.[7] Seventeen western states in America experience varying degrees of aridity, in contrast to the more humid eastern states. The difference in rainfall and ecosystem has been so considerable that development would have been less traumatic and destructive had settlement taken place from the West.[8] Water transfer projects and use of groundwater have made possible extensive urban and agricultural development similar to that in the more humid eastern states. The growth of cities, industry, agriculture, and population has decreased the supply of water while rising energy prices increased pumping costs. Apart from the six states in the High Plains, sections of Arkansas, Arizona, California, Florida, and Idaho also depend on groundwater.[9] In the future, . . . . Areas showing rapid rates of decline and high pumping lifts will likely be the next regions to lose irrigated acreage. Higher energy prices, rather than dwindling water supplies, will likely trigger the decline. Energy price rises have affected population costs more than declining groundwater levels. States containing significant areas of high pumping lifts (more than 200 feet) and rapid rates of decline (more than 3 feet) include parts of Arizona, California, Idaho, Kansas, Texas and the Oklahoma Panhandle.[10] Although irrigated agriculture in the High Plains has been possible only in the area overlying the Ogallala Aquifer, roughly 10 percent of the acreage in the six states, the gain in farm productivity has been remarkable. The area
produces, for example, approximately 40 percent of the nation's sorghum, 25 percent of its cotton, and 17 percent of its wheat.[11] Any major decline in water table combined with increased energy costs will have a sizable impact on both regional and national farm production. The impact is likely to be more severe in the southern tier of High Plains states—Texas, New Mexico, Oklahoma—where annual water use may decline by 53 percent by the year 2020 due to aquifer depletion, while annual water use will increase 33 percent in the northern states, Kansas, Colorado, and Nebraska.[12]
― 312 ― However, severe drought and rising energy prices may accelerate the shift to dryland farming throughout the six-state Ogallala area. Roughly two and a quarter million people inhabited the Ogallala area of the High Plains in 1980, slightly less than 9 percent of the total population in the six states.[13] While several of the High Plains states have large metropolitan centers boasting spectacular growth, e.g., Denver and Dallas, the Ogallala area itself reflects the characteristics of small town America. Of the approximately 166 cities in the United States with over 100,000 population, only three are located in the Ogallala area; all are between 100,000 and 300,000. Three states, Texas, Kansas, and Nebraska, have a total of twelve small cities with populations ranging from 10,000 to 100,000. The approximately 812 other communities found principally in Nebraska, Kansas, and Texas are below 10,000 population. Many of these communities will be adversely affected by the adoption of dryland farming as location and water scarcity reduce the likelihood of providing nonfarm employment by attracting industrial and commercial enterprises. Population and economic decline will be unavoidable in many of these communities.
The Process of Community Decline Rural community decline is initiated by a weakening of the economic base which triggers an interactive cycle that spreads throughout the locality and extends its influence into nearby towns and cities. Weakness in farming spreads to other economic organizations and to various local institutions, which leads to population losses. The decline in these several sectors are mutually reinforcing, magnifying the impact otherwise occurring separately, and encouraging the continuation of the cycle of decline. A process of reallocating wealth, resources, and people is underway, from the declining areas to those rural centers elsewhere in the nation with the potential for expansion, and to urban communities. The deterioration in local conditions upon which various organizations depend, and the social-psychological perception of the situation as one of diminishing opportunities unlikely to be reversed, underlie the disinvestment process.
Banks in small towns and cities quickly feel the impact of declining farm income since many borrowers have difficulty repaying loans. A phenomenon similar to "red-lining" in urban
― 313 ― neighborhoods may occur in rural areas if bankers consider farm loans too risky or incapable of earning an adequate return. Any major reduction in the availability of credit would cause some of the less efficient or more highly leveraged farms to cease operations. The high cost of capital also increases the pressure even for the most efficient and productive farmers to seek nonagricultural employment. Decline in farm income and population weakens the market for local and small city businesses and professionals serving the farm areas. Once the numbers of customers and income level fall below a "critical mass"[14] or threshold, financial rewards are too limited to permit continuation of the enterprise. Services and retail trade needing a large market would be most sensitive to community decline. Terminating operations effectively transfers functions to larger communities,[15] forcing local residents to do without some important commodity for a period of time and to incur sizable expense from shopping trips to more distant communities. These factors further increase the cost of remaining in the farm community. Professional services with high thresholds were first to leave declining villages in Wisconsin,[16] losses which probably had adverse consequences for the health and well-being of local residents. Commercial establishments also felt the effects of reduced income as customers cut back on purchases. Establishments requiring a large trade area, such as dry goods stores and auto dealers, were the first to depart, followed soon thereafter by various personal services, such as beauty parlors and repair shops.[17] Since the population could no longer support multiple stores in the same line, the number of establishments such as filling stations and grocery stores declined, leading to price increases. The decline in the rural community's resources imposes various costs and deprivations on inhabitants, causing the rural lifestyle to decline below that of most urban residents. The declining economic base has adverse effects on local schools and government, requiring cutbacks in various services, programs, and personnel. Laying off county clerks and school bus drivers, for example, seriously reduces the income of some farm families. Neglect of farm roads and bridges increases transportation costs, and necessitates more frequent auto repairs. The psychological consequences of decline are manifest in a malaise of defeatism which complicates if not defeats efforts to stabilize local institutions.
― 314 ― The departure of farm owners, professionals, and businessmen, and the closing of banks, also depletes the ranks of leaders: people with a substantial stake and involvement in the community. This outflow of an indispensable community resource has numerous consequences. The community's resources for exercising power—wealth, information, skills in management, public relations, brokering conflicts, access to key influentials outside the community—also have been diminished. The examination of the diverse roles which usually must be performed to complete a project indicates the seriousness of the losses.[18] These include, in addition to those mentioned above, initiating and formulating a specific plan and gaining support from decision makers. The exodus of leaders leaves few people capable of performing the tasks essential for success. Projects which depend on such specialized activities as communicating with a key legislator, or brokering disputes between local factions, may be crippled due to lack of external support and internal unity. These difficulties may befall both efforts at community development and the management of local institutions, e.g., schools and churches. The community also will be weakened by the absence of leaders with vision, a capacity to see beyond the immediate disrepair of the locality and recognize conditions as assets for future development which others ignore or fail to appreciate. These abilities are extremely important for declining communities, as one strategy for halting or reversing decline requires the use of "old resources in wholly new ways, so that they are really new resources."[19] Some western communities with environmental amenities have been able to shift their economies from extraction to culture, recreation, or both, and become a mecca for art lovers or ski enthusiasts.[20] Vision, however important, does not suffice to assure success of new ventures. Willingness on the part of leaders to take risks, to invest resources—both money and skill—in enterprises whose outcomes are doubtful and which require a lengthy period of time before results can be determined, is as important as the plan of action. The reversal in the economic well-being of several Wisconsin villages was attributed mainly to leaders who were entrepreneurial in risk taking.[21] The economic improvements required for halting decline are unlikely to occur in farm communities which have been losing many businessmen and farmers, since those who remain will be concentrated in the older age brackets, and less inclined to take risks required for supporting innovative programs. They are more likely to be fatalistic about the community's future.
― 315 ― Coalitions may overcome weaknesses in some organizations. A civic, youth, or educational group could improve its program by cooperating with other interested associations to acquire the needed resources. These interorganizational coalitions[22] enable key members to meet often for
resolving differences, formulating plans for development, and allocating resources for a few crucial projects. A communitywide association may be established to present a "united front" in dealings with external agencies.[23] A community's ability to cope effectively with decline may depend on degree of interorganizational linkages.[24] Any success which these coalitions achieve that improves local institutions, both economic and social, will upgrade conditions of daily life and demonstrate the capacity of local groups to influence the community's future. As this view gains support, resources for future projects should be more readily available.
Departure from the Farm Community For those who cannot continue in farming, the move to nonagricultural employment involves numerous changes. These may be minimal in communities whose residents can commute to jobs in the city. For others the change involves disengagement from one locality and economic sector and establishment in different structures. Many will encounter considerable difficulty and some will not make a successful adjustment. Even for those who find new employment and build new lives in the city, the level of satisfaction may be less than had been customary, causing some alienation from society's core values. An understanding of the factors involved in disengagement from agriculture and participation in the urban economy can be gained from comparing farming with a career in complex organizations. Various aspects of farming resemble a career, although the concept has been mainly applied to professional and administrative roles. A "career" signifies a stable and sequential pattern of employment in a similar line of work providing advancement over a lifetime in skills, earnings, and responsibility.[25] A career signifies continuity of work experiences since job changes comprise a general pattern of development. A career becomes a central part of the person's life plan, which absorbs considerable energy and commitment, and usually becomes a crucial basis for self-evaluation.
― 316 ― To the owner and operator of the family farm, especially one who has inherited the farm, farming represents lifetime employment as income is derived mainly from farm operations. Improving and expanding the farm are equivalent to career advances for the manager or the academician. Acquiring information and skills associated with innovations, e.g., use of the microcomputer for farm management, is similar to the surgeon's mastery of a new life-saving procedure. The former often are associated with gains in earnings and, among local associates, in prestige and possibly power. The more successful of the farmers may serve as directors of local organizations and of financial institutions. They often are in a position to influence decisions affecting the locality.
Plans and activities for improving farm operations provide direction, purpose, and commitment for the farmer and members of the family. Farming and related activities provide a continuity of experience over a lifetime, which could be passed on to the next generation should children choose to stay on the land. The continuity of experience which is a central feature of a career for the farmer also is associated with sustained contact with family and other community residents. This life plan changes drastically when the farm is sold and one or both parents enter the urban labor force. Few older farmers will be able to establish a new career, for these are open mainly to younger persons with college degrees. Establishing a business and blue collar employment that offers the opportunity for skill development provide the best prospect of approximating a career. Continuity of work experience will be difficult to achieve as many ex-farmers have less seniority than younger people who joined the firm after leaving school. The modest skills required for many blue collar jobs do not permit period progression in know-how and responsibility characteristic of the typical career. The importance of these factors as personal goals will decline. Since work and advancement lose saliency and ability to motivate activity, personal energies may be directed to other, nonwork activities. The satisfactions farming provides probably cannot be matched by factory employment as these depend largely on worker autonomy and ability to control work procedures.[26] Few ex-farmers will have as much responsibility and autonomy as they had on the farm. Most will have a subordinate position in a bureaucratic structure, with much less opportunity to exercise discretion and judgment. Since nonfarm employment for many will involve
― 317 ― lesser occupational responsibilities and rewards, there is far less likelihood of obtaining leadership positions in local organizations. For many of those who are forced to sell the farm and move to the city, especially those who do not receive substantial payments for their holdings, downward occupational and status mobility will be difficult to avoid.
Unemployment and Underemployment Lack of work seldom is a problem for farmers. In bad years and in good years buildings and equipment must be maintained, plans formulated for next year's activities, arrangements made for obtaining seed, fertilizer, pesticides, breeding animals, manpower, and other inputs. While nonfarm employment may involve various benefits, such as higher wages, pensions, health plans, paid vacations, it also entails a higher risk of unemployment.
Many former farmers and members of their families may be more subject to layoffs as they will have less seniority than persons of comparable age, as suggested above. People over forty may have considerable difficulty obtaining nonfarm employment. Understanding unemployment requires consideration of the place of work in the lives of most Americans. Work provides a central focus for organizing activity, and planning one's life. Work provides "meaning" for life, even for those who hold menial positions, if the work is necessary and considered productive.[27] These relationships are understandable since employment in an organization provides material and psychic rewards which link the person to society's core institutions and values. The importance of work in America also is indicated by recent public opinion polls which found that a large majority of Americans value work, prefer to work hard, and consider its benefits as both moral and material.[28] Work provides direction for most people, since daily activities are arranged to facilitate the performance of various work tasks. Family and organizational responsibilities have to be scheduled during leisure periods. Associations with colleagues in the office or plant help time to pass more quickly.[29] Work provides a purpose for living, a basis for supporting a family and assisting children to achieve upward mobility.[30] Prolonged unemployment deprives people of these goals. They become apathetic and withdrawn, consider themselves useless and superfluous and, when in public, often wander aimlessly.[31]
― 318 ― The consequences of unemployment do not disappear when the individual returns to work. The frustration, anxiety, and despair experienced during the layoff leave a painful residue. Employees who have been unemployed, even for a short time, tend to be more misanthropic and distrustful than those who have never lost their jobs.[32] They also are more pessimistic about themselves and their children,[33] since they view the organizations which determine their life chances as uncontrollable. While these aspects of unemployment may not weigh heavily in any deliberations concerning measures to safeguard and enhance the water supply for arid or semiarid regions, they should not be overlooked or treated as inconsequential. For persons who suffer even occasional unemployment, the psychological, material, and social costs will be severe.
Decision Making and the Exodus from Farming The decision or series of decisions which culminate in sale or retention of the farm connect the community changes resulting from adoption of dryland
farming, the prospects for suitable nonfarm employment, and the locality's future. Despite the importance of decision making for countless farm families, the process has been largely neglected compared to studies of decision making in complex organizations. Some attention should be given this matter since it has a vital effect on the region, its communities, and inhabitants. The information could provide a basis for counseling families on the course of action most suitable for their circumstances. Many factors discussed above operate to dissuade the farm family from moving elsewhere. These include anxiety over the transition to urban residence and employment, the separation from friends and kinfolk, from previous generations of the family. For those whose families have farmed for generations, moving severs ties with a venerable past. Friends, relatives, associates may suggest that such a decision should be postponed in expectation of some turn for the better. Delay of the decision, however, may not be in the best interest of the family, given the difficulties of the transition to a new and different type of community and mode of life. Prices for land and farm commodities may fall and require the family to take a sizable loss when the decision to sell is made. In the interim, considerable psychic energy may have been expended in the effort to save the farm
― 319 ― and the family's roots in the community, leaving members with meager emotional resources for coping with relocation when the farm is sold. In the interim, coping with uncertainty and ambivalence will be trying, as family members are on the verge of becoming marginal to the rural community while having no base in the community to which they will move. Even for those farm families which adapt to dryland farming and obtain an adequate income, the psychological strain may be considerable.
Planning for Community Decline Since community decline has multiple facets, as indicated above, a variety of adaptive strategies are required, both short term and long term. Short term policies should aim at limiting the exodus of people, resources, and organizations, and seeking, wherever possible, to strengthen the local economy. Establishing programs and, where necessary, organizations to accomplish these goals will counteract the fatalism which afflicts many residents, and provide leadership experiences for younger people. These will instill the confidence required for understanding more ambitious projects. Long-term efforts should be directed at obtaining nonagricultural functions and, when feasible, to restoring the area's resource base through some type of interbasin water transfer project. Although the prospects for such costly projects are dim at present, unforeseen events can put a different light on these proposals.
Some insight into the policies which might stabilize the rural community can be gained from the efforts to cope with similar problems in industrial cities.[34] While the measures discussed below will not accomplish miracles, implementation should improve conditions in the farm community and protect the markets for the cities serving as rural trade centers. The strategies emphasize conserving resources, careful selection of improvement programs, and strengthening the local economy. A study of planned contraction in Cleveland recommends a number of policies.[35] Since any development program is costly and resources in a declining community are scarce, the conservation of local assets should be the first priority. Any savings will yield resources which, however meager, may be needed for future development programs. Every plan, including those which have been customary in the past, should be examined carefully to determine both feasibility and the benefits to the community.
― 320 ― This type of rigorous scrutiny will reduce the likelihood that scarce resources will be squandered on projects which have little prospect for success. Second, savings may be achieved from reorganizing various government agencies. In some Texas counties, for example, commissioners are responsible for certain functions in their precincts, mainly road maintenance and, in some cases, fire protection. Centralization of these functions in one countywide office can lead to more efficient utilization of equipment and personnel, and savings for taxpayers. In some instances, various work rules may be archaic and costly. Plumbers in Pittsburgh's water department, for example, did not drive vehicles to various work assignments. Other municipal employees had to be used for this purpose.[36] For some counties and municipalities significant savings might be achieved by computerizing tax, voting, and other records, especially property assessments. Third, some local functions might be transferred to higher governmental bodies, such as counties, regional authorities, and possibly the state. Highway maintenance, water and sewage services, and sanitary landfills are some of the functions which could be performed more efficiently by governmental units serving a larger territory and population. Fourth, local officials and planners should assist and work with community organizations seeking to strengthen local institutions. The leaders of schools, youth groups, neighborhoods, and minority groups should be encouraged to improve their homes, localities, and institutions. Although such assistance might be construed as politicizing groups, which could lead at times to challenges of government initiatives, the dialogue resulting from such exchanges might lead to better plans and stronger citizen commitment to
the locality. This form of cooperation between elected officials and local organizations may reaffirm the faith of all residents in the vitality of the local community and forestall the spread of defeatism, which could paralyze efforts to stabilize the area. Equally important, these efforts at cooperation will facilitate development of leaders to replace any who have left the area, and thereby revitalize the "grass roots." Fifth, the possibility of using resources and facilities for purposes different from those in the past should be studied closely both for diversifying the economy and for conserving investment. One Ohio community, for example, converted a closed school building to a recreation center.[37] The prospect of attracting or developing nonagricultural functions should be seriously
― 321 ― examined. While this strategy might not be suitable for many farm communities, those near cities and major transportation facilities, especially highways, railroads, and airports, might attract some manufacturing or office establishments. Efforts to restructure the economic base may require some type of development group, a competent director, and cooperative relations with the state development organization. Local leaders must be willing to invest time, energy, and money in recruitment activities, which will encounter considerable competition from many other communities. Finally, local groups should join with area organizations concerned with or having some responsibility for water resources. Since the problem of diminished water supply is regional, programs for long-term improvement must be applicable throughout the area and are likely to require collective action by the respective state governments. The transfer of water between some or all of the states in a region also will require a long-term, unified effort to gain the support of the legislative and executive branches of the federal government. A strong consensus on both the efficacy and political acceptability of a particular plan for interbasin transfer will aid such an effort. Since the outcome is highly uncertain, equal if not more emphasis should be given to improving the conservation and management of the region's water resources. Uniformity of governmental arrangements among the states for accomplishing this end might be beneficial. At present, . . . laws concerning ground water vary from no statewide regulatory controls in Texas to full authority of the State Engineer to control ground water extractions in New Mexico.[38] Two types of regional coalitions may be useful, one consisting of government officials, the other of water resource associations in the respective states. Since these organizations have diverse interests, achieving consensus may require protracted periods of study and negotiation, and a broad program which includes urban and rural interests. Prospects for interbasin transfer
may improve considerably if the project can ease shortages in both urban and rural areas.
― 322 ―
Summary and Conclusions The community, both rural and urban, is a vital link between society and its members. Involvement in institutions and the development of core values take place in the groups and organizations of the neighborhood and locality. It is through situations at work, and among kinfolk, neighbors, and parishioners that commitments to society's values, norms, and roles are maintained and affirmed. These forms of social involvement, by providing respect and prestige, reinforce the individual's self concept and confidence in ability to cope with the everyday tasks required for supporting a family and community. Serious disturbances to relationships between levels of social organization and within the community occur often in industrial society, in this instance from depletion of a nonrenewable resource. Since the causes of such changes are indigenous to the industrialized, urbanized society, many solutions also must involve the larger system. This set of circumstances poses a dilemma for the rural community. Solutions often must be sought through coalitions with those in similar circumstances in other regions of the nation. Can communities which have lost assets to expanding communities muster the resources to shape policy decisions on the national level? The answer is particularly difficult when it is recognized that national and regional involvement can absorb resources and energies needed to adapt local institutions to conditions created by dryland farming. This chapter has focused on processes of community decline and of community adjustment. The former takes place mainly through changes in the economy, polity, and population; the latter through use of political agencies, both local and extra-local, to stabilize the area and provide resources needed by both economic and social organizations. The chapter also has emphasized the social-psychological difficulties that those who have been displaced from the rural community will experience. While adoption of dryland farming represents a realistic adjustment to the depletion of water resources in the semiarid West, the increased dependence on rainfall makes the rural community more vulnerable to drought and declining farm prices. If a drought should persist for several years, many farm communities will cease to exist.
― 323 ― Whether these circumstances constitute a national problem depends on conditions elsewhere in the country. Whatever the pain and suffering which befall those who are forced to leave their farms and communities, the impact nationally may be minimal if the economy, both rural and urban, is sound, if unemployment is low and farm prices high. The difficulties in the West may be no more serious than a bad cold for an otherwise healthy person. If, on the other hand, the patient has been seriously ill for some time, occurrence of another problem may suffice to cause permanent damage. The decline of agricultural productivity in the semiarid West combined with dislocation in industrial communities can aggravate the employment problem and weaken confidence in democratic institutions. Technological changes are eliminating many blue and white collar jobs. People displaced from rural communities, especially those who are older, will become part of an "underclass," along with those blue and white collar workers whose jobs were eliminated by technological changes and by the relocation of manufacturing overseas. A serious drought also will expand the numbers of people at the bottom of the social pyramid. Not only will the ranks of jobseekers in the city grow, but the nation's food producing capacity may be seriously impaired. The decline of the water supply and food producing capacity in a once fertile region should cause great concern in a nation which, for many years, has supplied food for people at home and abroad. The power of the United States in the world depends as much on the ability to produce food as on the ability to produce weapons.
Discussion: Estevan T. Flores[*] The pressing problems and social impacts that farmers face in upcoming decades due to the decreasing availability of water are clearly and succinctly discussed by the Schaffers. No doubt, in [*] The support of the Chicano Studies Center and the Institute of American Cultures of UCLA for this presentation is gratefully acknowledged.
― 326 ― the near future, a decrease in the number of small farms will continue with rural communities battling for survival in the face of decreased capital and human resources. The authors provide a rational and appealing strategy which rural communities and families might adopt in order to preserve the small farm as an institution. I will discuss a few salient issues brought out by the authors and present a brief account of an aspect omitted in the chapter,
namely, the impact on migrant farm workers. Primary responsibility for the reduction of the number of small farms in the U.S. has been placed on the corporate multinationals which have squeezed the small farmer out through competition in price, technological innovations, and other methods. The number of small farms has been markedly reduced during the last half century. The consequences of this reduction on the small farmer, when viewed in the context of water's declining availability, is discussed by the authors. Reduced opportunities and standards of living will befall the small farmer and family unit forced to remain in a declining agricultural community. The authors argue that mobilization of resources along either ethnic or other organizational foci (e.g., religious) must take place if the endangered community is to survive. Alternatively, a community may seek to establish novel kinds of economic production previously not considered. Small farmers will inevitably face the prospect of migrating to urban centers when their income declines beyond a certain point and no alternatives appear in sight. In this respect they will resemble Mexican-American/Chicano farm workers who have "settled out" of the migrant stream. An analysis of the adaptive measures both utilized by and provided for this ethnic group would be instructive for migrating white ethnics. In the late 1960s and 1970s, a number of Department of Labor programs were initiated to assist underemployed or unemployed persons. Migrant farm workers who decided to settle in an urban community availed themselves of such programs as Job Corps, where they could acquire the labor skills needed to survive in a nonrural setting. For example, courses in carpentry and plumbing were offered. These programs were often successful in placing their graduates, though sometimes they were not, for a variety of reasons. The point is that some form of government involvement in the urban settlement of rural migrants (small farmers) might be necessary.
― 327 ― One might speculate that under the Reagan Administration, which emphasizes government austerity, assistance of the type cited above might receive low priority, if considered at all. However, there remains governmental financial support for various domestic corporate groups (e.g., Lockheed and Chrysler), not to mention foreign governments (e.g., El Salvador and Brazil). One might suggest to communities which face decline and the prospects of migration that government assistance in both the place of origin and destination be provided. Methods of structuring such organizations are outlined by the authors.
The process of community decline is clearly and thoughtfully outlined. The loss of both human and monetary capital—but especially the loss of leadership—spells doom for a community. Where decline is evident and likely, consideration should be given to providing nonfarm occupational alternatives to the existing community and its organizations. Such foresight and the attendant program implementation would be costly, particularly in that recognition of the inevitability of the decline has psychic (individual) as well as social and economic effects. An alternative to rural community decline is the creation of "federal relief zones" patterned after existing "disaster areas." Communities suffering from climatic and resource changes are as much in need of assistance as those suffering from "act of God," e.g., a severe flood. But does our society (i.e., government), especially now, value the institution of the small farm sufficiently that it would accord it relief? Possibly—but probably not. However, the federal government has entertained the idea of creating "business enterprise zones" in blighted central cities in order to help the climate of business in these areas. Should the federal government not extend assistance to industries other than big business? In terms of the migration destination points of the small farmer, urban areas might also receive assistance from the federal government where sufficient numbers warrant such a program. This is a measurement problem. How many small farmers and their households are to be considered? In addition, what happens to migrant farm workers who also depend on the small farmer for seasonal employment? Thousands of farm workers would be thrown out of jobs upon which they have relied. What alternatives will be provided for these workers? In arguing for assistance to impacted rural areas, one could use the example of the federal government's aid to areas
― 328 ― impacted by military facilities. Already there has been a four-year debate in Congress over the government's role in assisting southern border school districts with a sizable number of legal resident alien children. Should Congress pass such a bill, it could be argued that urban areas impacted by rural migrants should also receive assistance. The analogy is applicable. The general strategy outlined by the Schaffers for community survival is rational and plausible. To accomplish these goals in the face of resource depletion, however, may be impossible. Resettlement assistance may be a better alternative. But will government come to the aid of the rural community (small farmers and farm workers) as it has for the business
community? This question will be answered if and when the federal government responds to the political mobilization of communities in need.
Discussion: William H. Friedland My intention here is to comment on the Schaffers' chapter, and then to extend their analysis of the High Plains area to the entire West. A major point concerns the generality of the phenomenon which the Schaffers discuss. The authors have described the anticipated social consequences for a specific declining aquifer. However, the outcomes they envision for the western High Plains can be utilized to describe American agriculture and rural society generally since the 1880s. In that time, U.S. agriculture and rural communities have undergone a massive transformation: the former has shifted to large-scale, commercial, chemically-based, energy- and capital-intensive; the latter (shading the social reality with only moderate exaggeration) has effectively vanished.[1] Thus, what the Schaffers analyze as the possible product of a declining water resource turns out to be a near-universal phenomenon, occurring in other circumstances where water has not been the causal agent of rural community decline. The specifics of this universal phenomenon vary from place to place, region to region, and in different historical periods of U.S. agriculture. We need only note the decline in the percentage of the labor force dedicated to agriculture, forestry, and fisheries from over 50 percent in the 1880s to 3.6 percent at the present[2] to understand the universality of the phenomenon. A similar process has also occurred in other rural occupations such as fishing, lumbering, and mining and mineral extraction.
― 329 ― In the midst of this decline, the West has found a "solution" to the water problem, although the social outcome remains very much the same as in the Ogallala area. The resolution of the water problem through developing community organization and alliances has been undertaken in the West through powerful political organization. This has produced a rich and complex network of physical transformation to dam and carry water over distances previously unknown in human history: the western water developments that have taken place since the adoption of the 1902 Reclamation Act. These developments, however, have not produced rich and varied community life. Rather, as documented by social scientists such as
Goldschmidt, they have produced a wealthy agriculture accompanied by limited human communities.[3] One could conceive, of course, of a programmatic solution to the declining Ogallala aquifer, but it is unlikely, in the present or projected political and economic climate, that works of such magnitude would be feasible. The Schaffers pose several problems that should be briefly mentioned. First, there is an implicit contradiction between the authors' discussion of the value system of the United States with its emphasis on success, material acquisition, and "free market" orientation, and the exigency to plan for the kind of social change they envision with the depletion of the aquifer. I can only wonder why, for example, planning seems impossible for the management of the Ogallala resource so that its depletion will end and that community life, perhaps with reduced "success," can continue. Second, an even more fundamental question cries to be asked: what is—or should be—the policy of the U.S. in agricultural production when the U.S. is exporting crops in such volume abroad? Should we be seriously worried about the maintenance of a production system that has created such abundance that its disposal has constituted a major problem for the nation for over 50 years? In other words, why worry about maintaining or expanding production levels? Why not worry about social policies to form a different economic base for human communities in the Ogallala area and elsewhere? And finally, any "solutions" for the problems of community decline suggest one additional question that should be asked: who benefits? Investments in social infrastructure such as occurred under the Reclamation Act have benefited varying
― 330 ― segments of the U.S. population differentially; not everyone has benefited equally as a result of the Reclamation Act. In the Westlands Water District in California, for example, the benefits to large landholders of federally subsidized water are different from those to farm workers, to mention but one social category. The justification for such water projects has been that they benefit all of us, i.e., the "public." It is unclear that the public benefits anywhere near as much as some tiny and privileged segments of U.S. society. In other words, to put the matter bluntly, wealthy and powerful interests benefit more from such projects than poor people. Should this be the way in which federal policy operates with respect to water development?
Chapter 14— Social Impacts upon Urban Communities by Lay James Gibson
Abstract Initially, a simple general model is introduced to describe what might happen should irrigated agriculture be eliminated or greatly reduced in the semiarid West. Consideration of this general model raises a number of additional questions: (1) what are the spatial patterns of potential impacts?; (2) what are the employment implications, i.e., how many workers are involved?; and (3) what are the potential scale and other mitigative effects— e.g., to what extent will geographic scale of analysis or previous experience influence the magnitude of impacts? The first question is addressed by analysis of several maps which show the location and relative importance of irrigation agriculture. Data clearly show that irrigation activity is highly concentrated in a handful of states. Furthermore, within these states irrigation agriculture is often spatially associated with metropolitan areas. The second question is approached through case studies which focus on agricultural employment in three states which have exceptionally high levels of irrigation agriculture. "Worst case" estimates of employment dislocation are offered. Even worst case estimates suggest relatively modest dislocations. Finally, speculation is offered as to the scale effects and other mitigative effects that will likely soften dislocation impacts. Impacted regions have opportunities to adjust to diminished water supplies by adapting new farming practices and technologies. Additionally, we can anticipate that impacts will be spread over space, they will occur gradually through time, and governmental intervention can be expected to assist both rural and urban distressed areas. Given the history of outmigration from agricultural areas, additional declines in agricultural population are likely to be of modest magnitude and of manageable proportion when viewed from both the perspective of rural sending areas and of urban receiving areas.
In the years since 1945, total land in farms in the United States has declined by 10 percent, as has acreage of harvested
― 332 ― cropland. The number of acres of irrigated land, on the other hand, has increased by 147 percent. In 1945, there was one acre of irrigated land for every 22 acres of cropland; today the ratio is one to nine. The growth of irrigation agriculture in both relative and absolute terms has been an
important topic of concern among resource managers, politicians, and the general public. Water transfer projects, groundwater draw-down, and agriculture-urban/industrial water allocation conflicts have all received widespread attention. Studies of water for agriculture normally focus on supply or demand within an agricultural region; more rare are studies which deal with secondary effects of intraregional shifts in supply or demand for water. This chapter looks at interregional linkages—the spill-over effects on urban regions that might be associated with reductions in supply of water within agricultural regions. Special emphasis is placed on social/demographic impacts. The paper is organized around three main topics: (1) a general model of intraand interregional relationships; (2) calibration of the populations involved; and (3) speculation about the full consequences of impacts on the urban sector of limited water for agriculture.
A General Model A general model for understanding what might be expected if quantities of water for agriculture were greatly reduced is fairly simple. Reduction of supply of water would reduce the amount of land used for agriculture (or at least the intensity of use). This, in turn, would reduce labor requirements (both proprietors and wage earners). Displaced workers might live within the impacted region or they might be "seasonals" who live elsewhere, but in either case they would be without jobs. A few might find employment in their local region's agricultural sector or in other industries in their local areas. Others might, at least in the short term, rely on public assistance in their home region, but most are likely to eventually find themselves in an urban residential environment and in an urban job market. It should be noted that whereas many agricultural workers live in rural settings, many others live in, or in close proximity to, relatively large urban centers, e.g., Fresno and Phoenix. These "urban farm workers" look beyond the city for jobs and in many cases, actually live away from home for much of the year. The
― 333 ― important notion at this point, however, is that regardless of place of residence, a large share of those who depend on irrigation agriculture for their livelihood would be forced to look toward urban centers for employment if supply of water available to agriculture were greatly reduced. There would be increased reason for these "irrigation workers" and their families to become integrated into the urban mainstream. A slightly more detailed version of the simple model starts with reduction in direct agricultural employment. These reductions, in turn, produce secondary
employment reductions through the multiplier effect; these secondary reductions are likely to be felt first by those in agricultural service activities, e.g., cotton gin employees, and later by those who provide a whole range of goods and services (both public and private) within the impacted regions. Workers made redundant may take other jobs in the impacted region or they may persist, supported by transfer income. But most are likely to head for urban centers with their families. If those displaced already reside in, or adjacent to, urban centers they will likely be forced to become more a part of the urban scene. We might speculate that for every three agricultural families forced to relocate, there will be one "secondary family" that, eventually, is forced to relocate. Before speculating about specific urban impacts, it is logical to ask questions about the number of workers involved and their locations. Similarly, questions must be asked about the places where water is used. In this paper, critical locations are defined in terms of irrigation. Obviously, all types of agriculture use water. But on the assumption that large water consumers are spatially associated with irrigation and, because irrigation agriculture is frequently labor intensive, attention is focused on leading areas of irrigation agriculture.
Location of Irrigation Agriculture The relative and absolute importance of irrigation activity is shown on Tables 14.1-14.3 and Figures 14.1-14.3. As can be seen by inspection of Figure 14.1 and Table 14.1, 50 percent of all cropland harvested in seven states is irrigated; irrigated cropland is a conspicuous part of the total in nine other states. These are the states with a high relative dependence upon water for agriculture—states where reductions in the amount of water available would seriously modify the agricultural landscape. It is interesting to note that whereas western states dominate the list, large relative dependence upon irrigation is not a feature exclusive to the West.
― 334 ―
Figure 14.1 Irrigated Cropland as a Percent of Total Cropland Harvested
― 335 ―
Table 14.1 Irrigated Cropland as a Percent of Total Cropland Harvested State
Percent
Nevada
100
Arizona
99
California
87
Utah
72
Wyoming
63
Idaho
61
New Mexico
61
Hawaii
49
Florida
48
Colorado
47
Oregon
41
Nebraska
34
Texas
31
Washington
29
Arkansas
22
Montana
17
Source: 1978 Census of Agriculture
Figure 14.2 and Table 14.2 also show relative dependence on irrigation, although the pattern is different from that shown in Table 14.1 and Figure 14.1. The variable described here is a sort of "potential landscape change" variable—it suggests that agricultural landscapes, especially in California and Idaho, would change dramatically were irrigation to be withdrawn. The implications are, perhaps, more aesthetic than economic. It is interesting to speculate about the extent to which irrigation creates rural landscapes that somehow enrich the lives of those who pass through them—especially when the irrigation provides a sort of greenbelt around urban centers. A noteworthy feature of these data, when compared to those previously described, is the fact that the same states appear on both lists but their rank order (and interval scale position) is very different on the two lists.
― 336 ―
Figure 14.2 Irrigated Land as a Percent of All Land in Farms
― 337 ―
Table 14.2 Irrigated Land as a Percent of All Land in Farms State
Percent
California
26
Idaho
24
Florida
15
Nebraska
12
Utah
11
Arkansas
11
Colorado
10
Oregon
10
Washington
10
Nevada
9
Hawaii
8
U.S.
5
Source: 1978 Census of Agriculture.
The third measure of location and importance of irrigation agriculture is provided by Figure 14.3 and Table 14.3. In terms of absolute shares, California and Texas are clearly the U.S. leaders with almost one-third of all irrigated land. These two states, along with Nebraska, Colorado, and Idaho, account for over one-half of the irrigated acreage in the U.S. These states, presumably, would be the hardest hit by massive reductions in the amount of water available for agriculture.
Metropolitan Irrigation Agriculture The distribution of irrigated land among the states of the United States is clearly not even; the same can be said about the distribution of irrigated acreage within each state. In some leading "irrigation states" a large portion of the irrigated acreage is found in metropolitan areas. Tables 14.4 and 14.5 provide information on what might be called metropolitan irrigation agriculture. Whereas data do not specifically describe irrigated agriculture on the urban fringe (some SMSAs include large, remote areas), they do support the assertion that much irrigation activity, and presumably employment, is already spatially associated with metropolitan systems. Many of those working in metropolitan irrigation agriculture may hold nonurban values and beliefs, but they are likely to be more familiar than their
― 338 ―
Figure 14.3 Location of Irrigated Land: Percentages of U.S. Total
― 339 ―
Table 14.3 Location of Irrigated Land and Percent of U.S. Total State
Percent
Cumulative Percent
California
17
17
Texas
14
31
Nebraska
11
42
Colorado
7
49
Idaho
7
56
Kansas
5
61
Florida
4
65
Montana
4
69
Oregon
4
73
Arkansas
3
76
Washington
3
79
Wyoming
3
82
Arizona
2
84
New Mexico
2
86
Nevada
2
88
Utah
2
90
Source: 1978 Census of Agriculture.
Table 14.4 Irrigated Agriculture in Metropolitan Areas, Selected States State
Percent of State's Irrigated Land in SMSAs*
Percent of U.S. Irrigated Acreage in SMSAs
California
52
9
Texas
19
3
Nebraska
1
-
Colorado
19
1
Idaho
3
-
Kansas
1
-
*Standard Metropolitan Statistical Areas Source: 1978 Census of Agriculture.
― 340 ―
Table 14.5 Selected SMSAs with Large Irrigated Acreage
SMSA
Irrigated Acres
U.S. % of Irrigated Acreage
Fresno, California 1,153,052
2.3
Bakersfield, California
892,636
1.8
Stockton, California
519,769
1.0
Sacramento, California
473,946
0.9
Greeley, Colorado 420,154
0.8
Modesto, California
340,750
0.7
McAllen, Texas
318,382
0.6
Lubbock, Texas
266,937
0.5
Riverside, California
256,093
0.5
Salinas, California 212,315
0.4
Houston, Texas
203,791
0.4
Brownsville, Texas
194,186
0.4
Vallejo, California 141,241
0.3
Denver, Colorado
109,491
0.2
Oxnard, California 106,925
0.2
Boise, Idaho
0.2
97,797
Source: 1978 Census of Agriculture.
rural counterparts with urban values and opportunities. Should irrigation activity decline, it is likely that metropolitan irrigation agriculture workers will find the adjustment process much less stressful than their more rural counterparts. The six states listed in Table 14.4 together account for 61 percent of the irrigated land in the United States. They are a mixed group in terms of the importance of metropolitan irrigation agriculture, but the figures clearly indicate that metropolitan irrigation is a conspicuous feature in some parts of the country. California is clearly the most noteworthy. This state has 17 percent of all irrigated land in the U.S., and 52 percent of it is in SMSAs. Put another way, 9 percent of all irrigated land in the U.S. is in California's SMSAs. Texas, the nation's second ranking irrigation state, has about onefifth (19 percent) of its irrigated acreage in its SMSAs; 3 percent of all irrigated land in the U.S. is in a Texas SMSA. Fourth ranked Colorado (Table 14.3) also has about one-fifth of its irrigated acreage in an SMSA.
― 341 ― Data for a small group of SMSAs with substantial irrigated acreage are given in Table 14.5. California clearly dominates, but Texas and Colorado make a strong showing. Just three California SMSAs alone hold over 5 percent of the irrigated land in the U.S.
Sources of Impacts and their Magnitudes Ideally, data would be available to describe the number of workers in irrigated agriculture by county in the U.S.; no such data exist. This is unfortunate inasmuch as such figures are needed if we are to know just how large the potential urban impacts might be. At least some light can be put on the problem by estimates of number of workers subject to dislocation. Such estimates will clearly not yield exact numbers, but they will provide at least a general picture of the order of magnitude and spatial distribution of potential urban impact source areas. It must be recognized that estimates presented in this paper are "worst case" estimates. Estimates of number of employees dependent on irrigation agriculture are very likely higher than the actual number that might be affected by major declines in irrigation activity. The use of "worst case" estimates is standard practice for many types of planning. The military, for example, when evaluating the impacts of a base closure, will use a worst case scenario to assure that plans cover a wide range of possible outcomes. In this study, the worst case is used partly to protect against understatement and partly for more immediate reasons. Specifically, the data which are utilized when making estimates are simply not detailed enough to allow for exact determination of the extent to which individual workers depend upon irrigation.
Source Areas Although no data exist to describe the number of workers in irrigated agriculture per se, data do exist to describe agricultural employment in counties dominated by irrigation agriculture. For the purpose of generating employment estimates, it will be assumed that all workers in a county with 80 percent or more of its total cropland in irrigation are employed in irrigation agriculture. Obviously such an assumption will overstate the actual numbers inasmuch as workers for noncropland related uses are not discounted. Nor does such an assumption account for variable labor needs of different crops or for farm management practices. But such an assumption is justified in that it will produce
― 342 ― at least macro-level estimates which will be of value in establishing the location of broadly defined source areas. In arriving at direct impact estimates, data on proprietors, hired workers (both paid and unpaid), and agricultural service workers were gathered for key counties in three leading irrigation agricultural states. Specifically, 11
California counties, 16 Colorado counties, and 16 Idaho counties—all with more than 80 percent of their total cropland in irrigation—were inventoried. Variables were defined as follows: ·Proprietors: one per farm was assumed. ·Hired Workers: This term covers paid family workers. Those working 150 days per year or more were discounted by 0.1 to account for some who do not work a full year. Those working less than 150 days per year were discounted by 0.8 to account for those who (a) work less than 5 months per year, and (b) are double counted because they work for more than one employer. ·Agricultural Service Workers: Workers of this type are reported as "paid" and "unpaid" and by the period worked (less than 150 days or 150 days or more). Workers, without regard to pay status, are discounted using the multipliers provided above. The net result is a series of estimates of full-time-equivalent workers (FTE) that would be displaced if irrigation agriculture were discontinued.
Case Studies At this point, we shall retreat to case studies of three states which would suffer relatively great losses if irrigation agriculture were discontinued. Ideally, perhaps, we would have a general model which would allow us to produce reliable estimates of labor loss throughout the country. Unfortunately, data are not available that allow the creation of such a model; place-to-place variations in labor utilization are simply too great. Even generation of state multipliers for case studies is hazardous, but statespecific estimates will at least provide figures of general utility. Case studies of California, Colorado, and Idaho are offered to illustrate what the loss of irrigation might mean to three very different areas. California would clearly be hard-hit by reduced supply of agricultural water. With 8.6 million acres under irrigation, this
― 343 ― state is certainly irrigation oriented. California has some 1.3 million persons working in agriculture (including agriculture services). The state's estimated FTE employment (using the procedures outlined above) is 511,601. Using data on California's 11 principal irrigation counties, it is estimated that there are 0.0344 FTE workers per irrigated acre for a total of 295,968 FTE
irrigation workers in all counties. In other words, 58 percent of what might be called "full-impact" agricultural employees depend on irrigation agriculture; these are the workers who would be displaced if water is no longer available to agriculture. Whereas this number is certainly substantial, it must be remembered that California has a civilian labor force of some 11 million—displaced agriculture workers would produce unemployment increases of about 3 percent if all 296,000 workers entered the job market at the same time. Colorado, without irrigation, would lose 70 percent of its estimated 59,000 FTE agricultural workers—a dramatic percentage loss, but less serious than the California case, because Colorado has a smaller irrigated area (3,458,031 acres) and a smaller "body count" (108,766). With a civilian labor force of about 1.4 million, Colorado (like California) would suffer an increase of unemployment of about 3 percent. This is a significant figure, but probably not a disastrous one. The situation in Idaho is a bit different inasmuch as Idaho does not have the benefit of a broad industrial base as do California and Colorado. With 3.5 million acres of irrigated land—just a bit more than Colorado's figure—Idaho is clearly a ranking state in irrigation acreage. With 114,151 persons in agriculture, this sector enjoys prominence within the state's overall economy. It is estimated that elimination of irrigation agriculture would see the loss of 38,591 of the state's estimated 55,872 FTE agricultural workers— 69 percent. Since Idaho's civilian labor force is only some 425,000, irrigation losses of 38,000 or so would represent a major blow to the economy.
Potential Impacts and Potential Mitigative Effects Metropolitan areas such as Fresno, Sacramento, and Bakersfield in California's Central Valley, and Phoenix, Arizona, already have large communities of agricultural workers living on their margins. Substandard housing, poor sanitation, and other deficiencies are common in such places. The prospect of these
― 344 ― areas and intercity areas growing to several times their current populations because of an influx of displaced farm workers is indeed disturbing. And it is clearly likely that displaced workers would turn to urban areas in large numbers if their source of agricultural income were to disappear. Geographic interaction theory suggests that migrants are most likely to select proximate destinations; metropolitan areas in the impacted regions would be the greatest beneficiaries of rural-to-urban migration, at least in the short term. Such migration would certainly produce a new poverty class in the receiving areas—to a large extent, the migration process would reduce levels of rural
poverty by increasing levels of urban poverty. A large group without financial resources would now be given the added burden of adjusting to a new and essentially foreign way of life. Social networks would be broken down in sending areas; new networks would need to be built in receiving areas. Potentials for conflict would be numerous as former agricultural workers move to urban areas and compete for low-cost housing and low-paying/lowskill jobs with an existing group of urban poor—an urban poor with longer tenure and better developed urban survival skills. Evaluation of potential impacts of displaced agricultural workers on urban areas is tricky for two types of reasons. First are a series of items related to agricultural production practices and technologies. Second are a number of considerations that define the nature of the impact process itself. It must be remembered that the estimates of workers affected are "worst case" estimates of the total number that could potentially be displaced. It is highly unlikely, however, that rapid, wholesale displacements would occur.
Practices and Technologies All regions, including those now experiencing diminished supplies of water for agriculture, have a number of ready options available to prolong their life as productive agricultural areas. Perhaps the most obvious is a move to (or return to) dry farming. Many areas which now depend heavily on irrigation were originally developed as areas of dry farming. Second, many areas might turn to crop substitution for their salvation, i.e., more water efficient crops might be introduced to replace the heavy water users now cultivated. Third, new field preparation techniques which encourage water conservation, e.g., laser leveling, might be employed. Fourth, new water-efficient irrigation practices might be introduced. Fifth, water transfers or even deep wells might prove to be the answer in some areas.
― 345 ― The options selected will depend upon the willingness of an area's farmers to adapt new practices and technologies and on the ability of the natural environment to support them. But at least in many places, agriculture can be expected to persist even in the face of diminished water supply.
The Impact Process The nature of the impact process itself is also important to consider. 1. Geographic Scale . Even "worst case" estimates of nationwide impacts might suggest a situation that would be serious but not disastrous. However, when these same estimates are applied to specific urban areas, potentials
for negative impacts will often be substantial, i.e., impacts are likely to be concentrated in a relatively small number of urban areas in California and the Southwest. California would clearly suffer the greatest impacts. Further, water here is often more than simply an amenity that allows for diversity in crops or increased yields—it is often essential for the very existence of commercial agriculture. Perhaps one bright spot for a place like California is the fact that many of its farm workers are now employed in close proximity to metropolitan areas—they are already somewhat "street wise." A number of other states (see Tables 14.1-14.3 and Figures 14.1-14.3) would also be impacted, but in most cases impacts would be less severe because the number of workers involved is less and because the opportunities for alternative employment in agriculture within the general area are greater. 2. Timing. Obviously, the time period involved is critical. If all irrigation agriculture were eliminated simultaneously, impacts would be dramatic. If, on the other hand, reductions in irrigation activity were spread over a number of years (as they certainly would be), the adjustment process would be much smoother. In fact, one could argue that the impacts of a relatively long-term rural-to-urban relocation would be little more than an extension of shifts that have been in evidence since the turn of the century. Further, it might be argued that because numbers of people are relatively small, especially in relation to the size of receiving centers, and major receiving centers, e.g., western metropolitan areas, are usually high-growth areas anyway, new populations could be accommodated with only minor dislocations. 3. A Further Note on Timing. The history of decline of agriculture population and labor force merits additional comment because that trend serves as a standard against which the
― 346 ― severity of irrigation losses can be measured. In the 40 years between 1940 and 1980, U.S. farm population declined by almost 500 percent or 24,500,000 people (Table 14.6). During this period, U.S. population grew by 72 percent to the 1980 figure of 227 million. During the period 1950-1970 alone, farm population declined by over 13,000,000. Every state experienced declines during these years (Figure 14.4); with the exception of Texas, the biggest losers were not states with large areas in irrigation. Nevertheless, the six leading irrigation states did lose over 1.6 million farm population—not a trivial number. A somewhat different accounting system (Table 14.7) produces another picture of decline that is essentially consistent with the one just presented. Agriculture's role in the U.S. labor force has declined significantly in both absolute and relative terms since the late 1940s. The agricultural labor force has declined by about 4.6 million; agriculture presently directly supports
only about 3 percent of our total labor force. Using figures presented elsewhere in this chapter, we can produce a rough estimate of irrigation agriculture employment for the nation. An estimated figure of 1,000,000 is offered for purposes of discussion. Such an estimate almost certainly overstates the true number, but such overstatement is consistent with the "worst case" approach. But the important point is this— given the history of decline of both "agricultural employment" and "labor force," the worst case still presents us with a situation which is considerably less dramatic than our actual experiences in the years following World War II. 4. Alternative Livelihood Opportunities. Not all displaced workers will leave the impacted region. At least some will shift jobs without leaving their present place of residence. Still others will stay in place and substitute transfer income, e.g., public assistance, for earned income. Finally, some secondary breadwinners may simply drop out of the labor market. Aggregate family income would suffer in such cases, but if the primary breadwinner's job is secure there will be little reason for at least many of them to move one. 5. Diffusion of Impacts. Some workers are migrants with home bases in many parts of the country and even in foreign countries. Their expenditures in areas where they are employed are usually modest at best; their absence should go largely unnoticed in employing regions. Since sending regions are widely dispersed, impacts above the family level should be minimal here, too.
― 347 ―
Table 14.6 Farm Population and Employment in the U.S., 1930-1980 Year
Farm Population* 1000's
Farm Employment** 1000's
1930
30,529
12,497
1940
30,547
10,979
1950
23,048
9,926
1960
15,635
7,057
1970
9,712
4,523
1980
6,051
3,705
*Farm population consists of all persons living on farms in rural areas. **"Farm employment" covers hired workers, farm operators, and family members doing farm work without wages. Source: U.S. Bureau of the Census, Statistical Abstract of the United States, 1981.
Table 14.7 Agriculture and the U.S. Labor Force: Selected Years, 1947-1980 Year
Total Labor Labor Force Force in 1000's Agriculture 1000's
Agriculture as % of Total
1947
60.9
7.9
13
1950
63.9
7.2
11
1955
68.1
6.5
10
1960
72.1
5.5
8
1965
77.2
4.4
6
1970
85.9
3.5
4
1975
94.8
3.4
4
1980
106.8
3.3
3
Source: U.S. Bureau of the Census, Statistical
Abstract of the United States, 1981.
― 348 ―
Figure 14.4 Farm Population Declines Between 1950 and 1970
― 349 ― 6. Political Considerations. The farm lobby is still strong in the United States. There is every reason to believe that even if political pressure cannot make water, it can make waves—waves which will produce support for projects and programs designed to extend the agricultural life of impacted regions. In short, both farm operators and farm workers have numerous opportunities for minimizing or at least delaying impacts. The full force of any potential impacts will certainly be blunted by the fact that they will be spread through time and over space. But perhaps the greatest comfort comes from knowing that, after decades of outmigration from agricultural areas, there are just not that many people left that can be displaced.
Discussion: Darrell K. Adams During the past decade, the research area subsumed under the title "social impact analysis" (SIA) has increasingly seen a focus in approach which suggests, if not the beginnings of maturity, at least the close of the adolescent period of development. We began this enterprise with a plethora of approaches which had, as a common feature, a kind of encyclopedic examination of the social world, in an effort to assure that nothing of importance escaped scrutiny. Now, the focus is on narrowing the range of variables to those significant to a decision. A general paradigm for SIA now usually includes some provision for assessing changes in (1) employment, (2) income, (3) population, and (4) the social meaning those changes might have from a variety of perspectives. The first three constitute "impact" analysis (i.e., an analysis of a measurable change directly attributable to some other changed circumstances), while the fourth would be a "social effect" analysis, or an assessment of social meanings and interpretations of impacts. Gibson has presented a model designed to examine the urban impacts of reduced water availability for agriculture in the West. As he indicates, the model is quite straightforward. A reduced water supply would tend to reduce agricultural production with reduced labor requirements displacing workers which, in turn, would result in residential relocation (rural to urban). This general paradigm is used to organize data so as to answer some important questions dealing with the spatial location of areas of severe impacts in terms of numbers (both absolute and as a proportion of workforce). Thereby, contributions are made to:
― 350 ― (1) scoping the potential problem, and (2) spatially locating the potential problem areas. While Gibson does not offer his analysis as the definitive answer, his contribution is nonetheless instructive. The potential for negative impacts of some significance in a relatively small number of urban areas in California and the Southwest is noted. He then comments that even these potential problem areas are subject to a variety of reasonably mitigating conditions. One might be inclined toward a relatively sanguine view of the urban impacts of a reduction in water supply for irrigated agriculture in the West from Gibson's analysis. However, such a view could be somewhat premature. The model is yet in an early stage of development, and emphasis is placed on employment (number and location of jobs) and population movement impacts. These are but two of the four general classes of
variables useful for analyzing social impacts and effects. As the next stage of development of the model, it would be helpful to trace the income variable through the model. Reduction in crop intensification or reversion to dryland practices on the same amount of land should result in reduced farm income. Reduced farm income, in turn, would have a variety of other impacts. It might, for example, eventually result in reductions in urban support facilities and services. Such reductions would adversely impact both long-time urban residents and newly displaced rural-to-urban migrants needing such support. It is possible, especially during periods of poor economic conditions, that such impacts could be significant and troublesome. The actual significance of this and other multiplier effects would need to be examined in further development of the model. The other major class of variables—the social effects analysis—would be more difficult to assess. If reasonably solid assessments of the spatial and temporal locations of employment, income, and population impact variables were available, they could be presented to the potentially affected publics in order to obtain their interpretations of the social meanings of such impacts. This analysis becomes more complex because, as we have found in sitespecific social analyses, each significantly affected group of the public is likely to have a different interpretation of the social meaning of a particular event. In the same way that a one-dollar change-in-income will have different meanings for a wealthy person than for a poor person, the projected impacts of reduced water supplies for irrigated agriculture upon employment, income, and population will have different social meanings for different groups and communities.
― 351 ― It is important to recognize that, regardless of the practical difficulties of completing the social effects analysis, it is only at this stage that a thorough understanding of the social importance of the impacts is attained. Toward this end Gibson's model has made a useful contribution.
Discussion: Evan Vlachos Gibson's presentation addresses the major question of trying to anticipate the general impacts of limited water for agriculture in the semiarid West and, more specifically, the potential effects on urban localities. One must really relate this particular chapter to earlier community migration studies, as well as to the vast literature that developed after the National Environmental Policy Act. The latter, in particular, has contributed to elaborate conceptual and methodological frameworks concerning the assessment of direct and indirect impacts of programs, projects, or activities on the surrounding
environment. In this context the search for an accounting of all relevant impacts became not only a legal requirement, but also raised important theoretical questions leading, perhaps, to a more cogent interdisciplinary model incorporating the sets of circumstances and web of interactions that contribute to both short-term as well as far-reaching consequences. Gibson bases his argument on a rather greatly simplified "model" in which, as a result of the reduction of water supply and with attendant reduction of labor requirements, displaced workers (particularly those living around metropolitan areas) will increase the population of surrounding urban localities. Such a "model" must obviously be further elaborated by considering three major subdimensions that eventually could more accurately describe both impacts and long-range consequences, namely: a) the classical demographic understanding of migratory movements in terms of "push and pull" factors (i.e., reasons for out-migration as well as forces of attraction of specific localities); b) the overall time as well as the rate of change, i.e., both the entire time horizon (whether temporary or permanent) and the rate of transformation (whether rapid or slow);
― 352 ― c) the composition of migratory stream, especially in terms of ethnic, racial, sex, and other components. In Gibson's presentation the model concentrates on calculation of impacts in agricultural states as a result of the number of workers who might migrate if water supply is reduced in the irrigated West. Quite correctly, Gibson points out that since no relevant data exist, guestimates must substitute for precise information. He points out that, depending on the particular case, although there may be significant numbers of potential migrants, the overall movement to urban localities may not be particularly disastrous. In trying to supplement Gibson's discussion I would like to point out additional items that could be meaningful. First of all, one should take into account not only the "formal" agricultural population but also (especially in the case of California) "invisible" workers. Reference should be made to alien workers who have not traditionally been counted and whose contribution to the surrounding economies may be quite significant (directly and indirectly).
The distinctions made by Gibson between Colorado and California, on the one hand, and the expected impacts in the case of Idaho, on the other hand, depend on the economic and sectorial composition of these three states. Since Idaho does not have the broad industrial base of California and Colorado, it should be much more significantly affected (although again the number of alien workers may alter the extent of expected effects). Yet, despite their historical backdrop, many states in the West have been recently characterized by more diversified economies and more resilient localities, especially urban centers of high absorptive capacity (such as the emerging megalopolis of Colorado's Front Range). In addition, throughout Gibson's chapter there seems to be some vacillation as to the ultimate consequences of a reduction of water for agriculture. While in certain parts it is emphasized that there may be some significant consequences, elsewhere (see notably the conclusion) it is pointed out that the potential urban migration is simply part of the continuous urbanization and suburbanization of American society and of diminishing farm employment. Heavy automation in American agriculture and the emergence of an efficient agribusiness industry may also account for hypothesized minimal impacts, certainly not of the proportions of previous migratory movements such as those felt during
― 353 ― the drought of the 1930s and the exodus associated with the Depression era. All in all, Gibson has correctly pointed out both the inadequacies of the present data as well as the essential parameters of a broad model that could account for the relationship between existing population concentrations in agriculture and the increasing urbanization in the West. If one is to examine the importance of irrigated agriculture and the potential of far-reaching social consequences stemming from water reductions, further distinctions and elaborations must be made with regard to the type of affected populations, particularly in terms of the demographic characteristics of such states as Colorado and California; in terms of the ability of cities and of surrounding urban and semiurban localities to absorb the limited number of workers currently employed in irrigated agriculture; and in terms of larger social policies that can cushion the effects or could mitigate earlier disastrous voluntary and nonvoluntary population movements. The above remarks should not be construed as implying that there can be no negative impacts from a potential reduction of water in agriculture. Indeed, what is most important is not the total number of people who may be affected. More important are the far-reaching social consequences—and the transition from a predominant ideology and culture that still emphasizes a balance between rural hinterland and urban localities, to one of a highly
urbanized and intense postindustrial economic base. What needs to be recognized vis-a-vis the urban impacts is to what extent urbanites, especially refugees from the humid East, are capable of understanding the cultural heritage of irrigated agriculture in the West. Can they respond with sensitivity to the need for coexistence with irrigated agriculture—that agriculture being both a means of survival and a way of life that has characterized the salubrious environment of the western United States? Otherwise, an alternative view (perhaps even a future scenario) may be a totally transformed "Sunbelt" characterized by cybernetic industries, hydroponic farms, water for energy development, and a playground for the rest of the nation, with only dim memories of irrigated agriculture.
― 354 ―
Chapter 15— Environmental Impacts by B.A. Stewart and Wyatte Harman
Abstract Agricultural activities affect the environment in four general ways: (1) use of chemicals to increase agricultural production, (2) excessive and/or inefficient use of water, (3) injudicious agricultural practices, and (4) conversion of lands to expand cultivated crops. The extent to which the environment will be affected by agriculture in the future will depend on many factors, perhaps the greatest of which will be the degree of pressure placed on soil and water resources to meet demand for food and fiber. It is clearly recognized that the environment will be changed as land use and crop production practices evolve. The impacts will not, however, always be negative because many agricultural practices lead to an enhancement of the environment. This paper examines trends and projections of future requirements for food and fiber, the likely changes in land use that may be required to meet these demands, and the possible impacts of these land use changes on the environment.
Agriculture in general, and irrigated agriculture in particular, has impacts on the environment, positive or negative. Irrigated crops account for more than 25 percent of the total value of crop production in the United States, but require only 14 percent of the cropland. Irrigated acreage has increased dramatically, growing from about 18 million acres in 1939 to 37 million in
1958 and 58 million in 1977. At the same time, cropland acreage dropped from 531 million acres in 1939 to 449 million in 1958 and 413 million in 1977. A positive impact of the increase in irrigated acreage is that the overall quality of cropland has improved because some erodible cropland has been put to other uses. However, high rates of fertilizers and pesticides sometimes used on irrigated lands can degrade the environment. The conversion of lands into irrigated agriculture may also have diminished wildlife habitats.
― 355 ― Irrigated acreage is expected to increase in the future, but at a slower rate because of competition for limited water supplies and the depletion of groundwater in several areas. The 1978 National Water Assessment projected that an additional 6.9 million acres would be brought under irrigation by the year 2000.[1] Considerable attention has been given in recent years to the effect of agriculture on water quality. Stewart et al. (1975), Unger (1979), Bailey and Waddell (1979), and White and Plate (1979) are among those who have assessed the potential for pollution and have suggested appropriate management practices.[2] Environmental effects of agricultural activities arise from four general sources: (1) use of chemicals to increase agricultural production, (2) excessive and/or inefficient use of water, (3) injudicious agricultural practices, and (4) conversion of lands to expand agriculture. The extent to which the environment will be affected by agriculture in the future will, of course, depend on many factors. Perhaps the greatest single factor will be the degree of pressure placed on the soil and water resources to meet the demand for food and fiber. Therefore, consideration will be given in the following discussion to the trends and projections concerning future requirements for food and fiber, the likely changes in land use that may be required to meet these demands, and the possible impacts of these land use changes on the environment.
Projected Demands for Food and Fiber World food production is projected to increase 90 percent over the 30 years from 1970 to 2000. During the same period, population will increase about 50 percent. While these projections indicate a per capita increase in food, world distribution problems will remain. The bulk of the increase will continue to go to countries that already have a relatively high level of food consumption. Meanwhile, food will remain scarce or actually decline below present inadequate levels in many of the less developed countries. Over the next 20 years, USDA projects the demand for U.S. agricultural
products to increase by 60 to 85 percent over the 1980 level. The increased demand will be due to growth in exports, increased domestic use for conventional purposes, and for ethanol production. However, these projections are based on the assumption of constant real prices. A significant rise in real cost
― 356 ― of agricultural products in general, and food in particular, could drastically alter demand. Export demand will have the greatest impact because presently the harvest from one-third of U.S. cropland is exported, and USDA projects the volume of U.S. exports by the year 2000 to grow by 140 to 250 percent above the 1980 level. The projection that demand for U.S. agricultural products will increase suggests that there will be major changes in land use. Negative impacts on the environment can be minimized or avoided if these changes in land use can be seen in advance and adequately planned. The production of food and fiber in the United States has increased dramatically during the past 40 years, even while the amount of cropland harvested declined by more than 20 percent. The primary reasons for this remarkable achievement have been the use of fertilizers and pesticides, a vast expansion of irrigated acreage, improved crop cultivars, and improved management practices. During the 1960s crop yields increased nationally at an average annual rate of 1.6 percent, which was sufficient to meet increased demands. However, during the decade of the 1970s, the average annual yield increase dropped to 0.76 percent, and three-fourths of the increased production had to be met by an increased acreage of cropland. After several decades of declining or stable cropland acreage, the 1970s saw an increase of more than 60 million acres in harvested cropland. The National Agricultural Lands Study (1981) concluded that if the yield increase rate of the 1970s continued until 2000, and projected demands materialize, an additional 140 million acres of land would be required for the production of principal crops, or an increase of about 50 percent.[3] Even at the 1.6 percent yield increase rate of the 1960s, some 85 million acres of additional cropland would be required. While there is little consensus among the agricultural community as to the future rate of increase in yields, a good case can be made for a continued diminishing rate of increase due to rising costs of fuel, fertilizers, and other energy inputs; declining water supplies to sustain the growth in irrigated acreage that occurred during the past few decades; a lowering of the average quality of cropland as fragile lands are used for principal crops; and loss of soil productivity due to erosion and salination. Although there is enough land that could be shifted into cropland to meet the projected demands, even at the low growth rate of increased yields of the 1970s, the cost of food and fiber in real dollars may rise
― 357 ― significantly since production incentives will be required to develop such an expanded crop acreage. Rising costs may, in turn, reduce demand. In view of these complexities, it is difficult to project with accuracy the additional cropland which will be required by 2000 to meet the demand for U.S. agricultural products. It seems safe to conclude, however, that the acreage requirements will increase.
Impacts of Land Use Changes on Soil, Water and Air Resources Many Americans take soil and water resources for granted. There has been sufficient soil, and usually enough water, to grow all the food and fiber needed in the U.S., and then some. Most years, supplies of U.S. agricultural products have been sufficient to export to many foreign nations and still have a worrisome surplus. Soil and water resources are not without limit, however; they are finite and vulnerable to erosion and exploitation. Environmental impacts may vary, depending on physical and economic uses of soil and water resources; consequently, it is difficult to be specific in discussing the impacts of land use changes. Nevertheless, some of the issues can be reviewed.
Irrigated Lands The 17 western coterminous states have some 49 million acres of irrigated land and account for over 85 percent of all the irrigated land in the United States. The environmental consequences of irrigating this land fall into two broad categories—water pollution and conservation of water and land resources. Water pollution is a major concern in irrigated crop production because of the generally intensive use of fertilizers. Studies have shown that fertilizers and pesticides can be used very effectively with little or no negative environmental impact. Other studies, however, show that, under some conditions, the environment can be degraded. Nitrate leaching into groundwater supplies has been documented as well as the movement of nutrients and pesticides off the land with sediment. There is, nonetheless, reason to be optimistic; through the use of improved inputs and advanced management practices, environmental quality may be maintained or even enhanced. If the real costs of irrigation water, fertilizers, and pesticides continue to increase in relation to the value of the crops produced, farm operators will utilize inputs much more efficiently. Also, an increased awareness of potential hazards may lead to more careful use of inputs.
― 358 ― Improved technologies are emerging in irrigated crop production. Of particular significance are irrigation scheduling programs that result in more efficient use of irrigation water. These can reduce leaching of nitrates and also reduce runoff and erosion. Reduced runoff, coupled with improved nutrient application methods, will also reduce losses of plant nutrients from irrigated fields. The use of lasers for more precise land leveling can also greatly improve water management under some conditions.
Nonirrigated Lands There are about 155 million acres of nonirrigated cropland in the 17 western United States. A large part of this is in areas receiving less than 20 inches of average annual precipitation, where rainfall is often highly variable and sometimes intense. If irrigation becomes restricted either by limited supplies, uneconomic conditions, or by competition with other uses, expansion of dryland acres must increase. As nonirrigated cropland acreage increases, cropland quality will decrease because more and more marginal land will have to be utilized. Currently, water and wind erosion soil losses average about 5 tons per acre in the United States. In some areas, such as portions of the Palouse Area in Washington, Oregon, and Idaho, the combination of steep slopes and seasonally intense rainfall have resulted in erosion rates of 50 to 100 tons annually. Erosion in excess of topsoil formation is the most critical concern. Even at lower rates of erosion, however, the environment can be negatively affected. Wind erosion is a major problem for much of the nonirrigated cropland in the 17 western states and particularly in the Great Plains. In the Northern Plains (Kansas, Nebraska, North Dakota, and South Dakota) and Southern Plains (Oklahoma and Texas), annual sheet and rill erosion by water is about 3 tons per acre. Wind erosion amounts in Kansas, North Dakota, South Dakota, and Oklahoma are very similar to water erosion amounts. However, in Texas, wind erosion losses average 15 tons per acre, about five times greater than water erosion. Wind erosion is also high on Colorado and New Mexico croplands. If cropland acreage in these areas is expanded, erosion hazards will increase and improved management practices will be needed. Again, however, new technologies are emerging. Conservation tillage is very effective in alleviating both wind and water erosion. Conservation tillage is defined as any tillage sequence which reduces soil or water loss compared to conventional tillage. Conservation tillage is synonymous with
― 359 ― maximum or optimum retention of residues on the soil surface and the utilization of herbicides to control weeds where tillage is not or cannot be performed. In water deficient areas, conservation tillage generally also results in higher yields because of improved water conservation. Conservation tillage will result in increased usage of agricultural chemicals, particularly pesticides. Research and monitoring will be required to insure that the crop production systems developed do not impose a threat to the environment. Sediment, which is clearly recognized as the most undesirable single pollutant, is significantly reduced by conservation tillage. The control of sediment will also, to a large degree, control nutrient and pesticide losses. Thus, conservation tillage offers real promise for enhancing the environment, improving crop yields, and reducing energy inputs. Conservation tillage has increased from about 30 million acres in 1972 to more than 100 million in 1982, but satisfactory cropping systems are still lacking in many areas. Among the 17 western states, the Northern Plains states led with 33 percent adoption of conservation tillage; Southern Plains states were lowest with only 6 percent. The Mountain and Pacific states were intermediate with 28 and 20 percent, respectively. The very low adoption rate in the Southern Plains states is disappointing because both wind and water erosion rates are high in that area and conservation tillage could significantly reduce these losses. Also, water is the main limiting factor in crop production, and conservation tillage can increase soil water storage. Present cropping systems do not lend themselves readily to conservation tillage systems, which is the primary reason for the lower adoption rate. The lack of suitable cropping systems for conservation tillage has been largely due to the limited availability of effective herbicides for the common crop sequences. Satisfactory systems and improved herbicides are now being developed, and there is reason to think that conservation tillage will be widely used in the future. The U.S. Department of Agriculture has projected that conservation tillage will be practiced on about 80 percent of the U.S. crop acreage by 2000. This should have very positive environmental impacts.[4]
Reversion of Irrigated Land to Dryland Irrigation water will become limited or nonexistent in some areas as groundwater supplies are depleted or become unprofitable to use, and as other sources are partially diverted to other uses. Recreation, energy, municipal, and industrial uses will become increasingly competitive for water supplies. Each of
― 360 ―
these uses has definite impacts on the environment. Consequently, it is important that environmental safeguards be provided.
Declining Groundwater Supplies Overdraft of groundwater in specific areas, particularly in the western United States, is causing concern because of the impact it has on the future of irrigated agriculture. Examples of overdraft areas are the San Joaquin Valley of California, central Arizona, and the Ogallala Aquifer area of the High Plains. Depletion of groundwater is not the only factor causing reversion of irrigated land to dryland in these areas. The cost of energy for pumping groundwater has risen in recent years much faster than the value of crops produced, and has made irrigation unprofitable in some cases. For example, high pumping lifts and sharp increases in prices for natural gas resulted in a sudden drop in irrigated acreage in the Trans-Pecos areas of Texas. Significant amounts of irrigated cropland in overdraft areas will revert to dryland in future years. Because of its large size and severity of overdraft, particularly in the southern part, the Ogallala Aquifer area has received considerable attention in recent years. Therefore, it seems appropriate to look specifically at this area as a case study. The detailed studies being made on the area may not only lead to more efficient use of the remaining water in the aquifer, but also lead to better utilization of other aquifers as well.
The Ogallala Aquifer Area A huge underground layer of sand, gravel, and silt saturated with millions of acre-feet of water, the Ogallala Aquifer underlies some 115 million acres of land, largely in six High Plains states. Before World War II, land in the High Plains was primarily used for producing cattle and dryland crops. Irrigation began in the early 1900s, but did not begin to accelerate until the late 1930s. Following World War II, and particularly during the great drought of 1951-56, irrigated acreage expanded rapidly. The combination of a seemingly unlimited supply of excellent quality water, highly fertile soils, newly developed hybrid grain sorghum and other crops, and a favorable climate resulted in tremendous expansion of agricultural production and associated agribusiness. In a matter of a few years, acreage irrigated from the Ogallala Aquifer accounted for more than 25 percent of all irrigated land in the United States. As irrigation accelerated, however, it
― 361 ― became apparent that the aquifer was being mined at a rate far in excess of the rate it was being replenished by the sparse snowmelt and rain.
The Ogallala Aquifer has in recent years become of great concern to the nation and world, but particularly to the people whose livelihood is directly affected. The United States Congress initiated the six-state High Plains Study in 1976 to assess the present and future status of the aquifer. Research results and recommendations from the study were to be reported to the Congress in July 1982. As a part of the High Plains Study, projections through time were made regarding dryland and irrigated acres by crop, value of agricultural output, input costs, employment, and income for each of the six states under a number of alternative development strategies. The baseline analysis was designed to project, from the base year 1977 to 2020, possible changes in the pattern of irrigated and dryland production and water use, by state, under the general assumptions that no new purposeful public action would be initiated to restrict or otherwise regulate irrigation water use in the area. Therefore, the baseline reflects future changes in acreages if no new voluntary or regulatory water management schemes are implemented and if no new water sources are developed. However, interactions between crop yields, water use, improved technology, declining well yields and rising pumping costs, competing crops and cultural practices were considered in the analysis. Mapp (1981) summarized the findings of the analysis and discussed some of the more important of the many assumptions required to perform the study.[5] Space does not allow full discussion of the assumptions, but we report a portion of the results here because of the important environmental implications of the projected changes.
Results from the High Plains Study Data presented in Figure 15.1 for the High Plains region project a continued increase in irrigated acreage. There is a slight decrease between 1985 and 1990 which results from anticipated deregulation of natural gas prices. After 1990, however, increases in crop yields and real product prices outstrip further increases in energy prices, and irrigated acreage continues to expand. It is especially significant to note in Figure 15.1 that the amount of irrigation water pumped from the aquifer decreases markedly through the 1980s even though irrigated acreage is continuing to increase. After 1990, the water pumped
― 362 ―
Figure 15.1 Projected Acres Irrigated and Acre-Feet Pumped for the High Plains Ogallala Aquifer Area Source: Adapted from H.P. Mapp, "The Six-State Ogallala Aquifer Area Study: Baseline Results for the Agricultural Sector," 1981. increases somewhat in proportion to the increase in irrigated acreage. In 1977 about 1.5 acre-feet of irrigation water were pumped for each acre of land irrigated in the region; this is projected to decrease to 1.3 by 1985 and 1.2 by 1990, and then remain fairly constant. Water use will vary greatly between states, however, because of availability. For example, usage in Texas, where underground water supplies are becoming quite limited, is assumed to drop from 1.38 acre-feet per acre in 1977 to about 0.65 acrefeet per acre in 2020. This decreased usage in applied water for each acre of irrigated land is expected to result in marked changes in crops grown, irrigation application methods, and cultural practices. Significant differences in water supply exist among the High Plains states that overlie the Ogallala Aquifer. The aquifer contains an estimated 21.8 billion acre-feet of water, which if evenly
― 363 ― distributed would be about 190 acre-feet of water under each acre of land. Texas, Oklahoma, and New Mexico, however, contain approximately 30 percent of the aquifer area but only about 15 percent of the water, whereas Nebraska contains 36 percent of the aquifer area but 64 percent of the volume.
The baseline projections for the six states studied are shown in Figure 15.2. Nebraska is expected to continue to rapidly expand its irrigated acreage while other states show fairly sharp decreases, or remain constant. The projections for Nebraska also show that irrigated acreage will expand much more than dryland acreage will decrease. Consequently, large acreages of land presently used for purposes other than cropland will be brought under cultivation, much of it undoubtedly in sandy areas presently in grass. The large expansion of irrigated land in these areas, particularly on sandy soils, will present pollution potentials because of the marked increase in fertilizer and pesticide usage that will be associated with intensive crop production. Natural recharge of the aquifer is higher in this area than any other area in the region, and with added irrigation, the possibilities of leaching nutrients and salts into the aquifer will be greater. Good management systems which address pollution hazards will be needed. Projections for Kansas and Texas show substantial decreases in irrigated acreage and corresponding increases in dryland acreage. The dryland acreage in Kansas is projected to increase even more than irrigated acreage will decline, which again indicates that total cropland acreage will have to come from somewhat marginal lands with perhaps higher than average erosion potential. The data for Colorado and New Mexico (Figure 15.2), and Colorado in particular, suggest that irrigated acreage will decrease without an accompanying increase in dryland acreage. Therefore, much of the irrigated land in these areas is expected to go out of cultivation. In some areas within other states this will also happen; in many cases these will be sandy areas that were not in cropland until center-pivot sprinkler irrigation systems were installed. Much of this land will not be suitable for dryland farming, and unless special care is given, serious environmental consequences could be encountered. Wind erosion will be a major problem and revegetation of the areas will be very difficult, unless it is done before irrigation is stopped. A bill was introduced in the Nebraska legislature that would have required centerpivot irrigators to revegetate wind erosion-prone
― 364 ―
Figure 15.2 Projected Acreage of Irrigated and Dryland Cropland in Six States of the Ogallala Aquifer Area. Source: Mapp, 1981.
― 365 ― land before irrigation systems could be removed. Although it is unlikely a bill of such nature will be passed, its introduction recognized the potential environmental hazard of irrigated lands reverting to dryland. In areas where cropland was primarily dryland-farmed prior to the time it was irrigated, the land can generally be returned to its former use without serious environmental impacts. The production from dryland areas will be extremely variable, ranging from fairly high yields in above average rainfall years to very low yields or even crop failures in drought years. There is very little likelihood, however, that widespread dust storms such as those that occurred during the "Dirty Thirties" will reoccur. For example, recently improved cropping methods and cultural practices result in more efficient storage of soil water during fallow periods. Large farming equipment developments allow more timely and effective cultivation. Better crop varieties are less prone to complete failure. Other technologies are also
emerging that, when coupled together into integrated farming systems, are very effective in controlling erosion. This is not to say that there will not be localized areas where environmental hazards are acute, but the region as a whole is not expected to be seriously damaged. The conversion of irrigated land to dryland in the High Plains states will result from either a declining supply of water, the inability to realize enough profit from irrigated farming to pay for the associated energy costs, or a combination of the two. If water availability is the primary constraint, the conversion of irrigated land to dryland will be gradual and will generally move from fully-irrigated to limited-irrigated to dryland. Limited irrigation will involve only one or two irrigations, or perhaps only preplant irrigations during the winter to reduce evaporation losses. This orderly conversion to dryland presents little environmental hazard. The most serious environmental threat would result from a situation in which energy costs, or some other economic condition, causes a sudden abandonment of large areas of irrigated land. The most environmentallycritical areas, as already mentioned, would probably be sandy areas presently irrigated with center-pivot systems. These lands were broken out of native range due to economic incentives and generally have low dryland production potential. Unless some orderly plan is developed to revegetate these lands with permanent cover, serious environmental hazards will result. The most serious hazard, of course,
― 366 ― would be wind erosion. Figure 15.3 shows the principal soils overlying the Ogallala Aquifer. The sandy soils that present the greatest environmental hazard are illustrated by crosshatched areas. The double crosshatched soil areas represent the most severe environmental hazard potential. Irrigated acreage has expanded substantially in some sandy areas in recent years. It is evident that if irrigated acreage expands further, as projected in the High Plains Study (Figure 15.2), much of the increase will likely occur on soils having a severe environmental hazard potential. Similar problems occurred during the 1930s when many farmers abandoned sandyland farms near Dalhart, Texas. To alleviate the vast erosion from the area, the federal government bought the farms and charged the USDA Soil Conservation Service with the task of revegetating the land. These lands now are part of the National Grasslands managed by the U.S. Forest Service. Similar projects occurred in other parts of the Great Plains. The discussion above points out some of the complexities of the High Plains region. It is clear that there will be a gradual decrease in irrigated acres for all states in the region except for Nebraska, where the water-to-land ratio is high. The decline in acres irrigated will likely be much slower than the actual
decline in acre-feet pumped from the aquifer. Improved irrigation techniques and equipment are being developed which allow more efficient use and distribution of irrigation water. Also, cropping systems are being developed that emphasize utilizing limited amounts of irrigation water; fully irrigated systems of the past were designed for maximum yields rather than efficient use of water. The primary benefit of limited irrigation in this region is that it allows for much more efficient use of the natural precipitation. The average amount of irrigation water pumped for each acre of irrigated land in the region is about 20 inches. The addition of just 8 inches of irrigation water to the natural precipitation of the region could have a very beneficial effect on crop yields and would help stabilize production and reduce risks. Groundwater pumped from other major aquifers in the western United States will also likely decrease in future years as a result of overdraft or uneconomic conditions. Unlike the High Plains region, much of the irrigated land in other areas of the western United States is in arid areas. In general, 14 inches or more of annual rainfall are required to sustain dryland agriculture. However, water harvesting technologies and more drought tolerant crop varieties are emerging that may extend dryland crop production in areas previously considered too dry.
― 367 ―
Figure 15.3 Principal Soils Overlying the High Plains Ogallala Aquifer Areas of sandy loam and loam soils are cross-hatched, and sandy soils are double cross-hatched. Soils in other areas are primarily loams and clay loam s. Source: Fred Pringle and Gerald Ledyard, USDA Soil Conservation Service.
― 368 ―
Loss of Irrigation Water to Domestic and Commercial Uses Although domestic and commercial use of water represents only a small percentage of total withdrawals and consumption, these uses have a high priority which makes resource management critical. In 1975, these uses accounted for 8.5 percent of total fresh-water withdrawals and 6.9 percent of consumption. In contrast, irrigation accounted for 47 percent of
withdrawals and 81 percent of consumption. By the year 2000, domestic and commercial uses are expected to increase by about 30 percent—and by as much as 50 percent or more in some of the western regions. Much of this increase will come from water presently used for irrigation, and the transfer of this water will likely result in decreased acreage of irrigated land. This is particularly true when groundwater rights are sold for domestic uses. In areas where dryland agriculture is not feasible, the diversion of water should be accompanied by revegetation of the land. In areas where increased use of domestic and commercial water is diverted from rivers or sources other than groundwater supplies, there will not necessarily be a decline in irrigated acreage. Developing technologies are making agriculture more water-efficient, and some diversion to other uses can be made without seriously affecting the acreage of irrigated land.
Loss of Irrigation Water for Mining Fuels Minerals production or mining has relatively minor water needs compared to irrigation. The National Water Assessment (1978) stated that the mineral industry accounted for only 2 percent of fresh water withdrawals in 1975, and projected that this would increase only to 3 percent in 2000. However, because quantities and qualities of minerals vary by regions, water demands vary accordingly. Even in the western regions where minerals are abundant and water supplies are short, the National Water Assessment does not project water needs for mining to represent a substantial portion of total water consumption. The 1975 and projected 2000 withdrawals of fresh water for fuels production, as compared to irrigation, are shown in Table 15.1. These data illustrate that the projected requirements for water for mining fuels are relatively small in relation to irrigation, and even though water demands for mining fuels will increase dramatically on a percentage basis in some regions, irrigated acreage will not be greatly reduced. Localized impacts, however, may be severe, because in most cases the increased water for mining will have to be taken from agriculture. The diversion
― 369 ―
Table 15.1 Fresh Water Withdrawals for Irrigation and Fuels Production, Selected Regions Water Resources Region
Irrigation
Fuels Production
(million gallons per day) 1975
2000
1975
2000
Missouri1
31,636
39,376
144
236
Arkansas-WhiteRed2
9,980
9,776
172
185
Texas-Gulf3
11,538
7,427
837
930
Upper Colorado4
6,400
6,672
68
171
1
Missouri (Nebraska, South Dakota, most of North Dakota, Montana, and Wyoming, and northeastern Colorado and northern Kansas) 2
Arkansas-White-Red (southeastern Colorado, southern Kansas, Oklahoma, Texas Panhandle, and western Arkansas 3
Texas-Gulf (Texas except for the Panhandle and Trans-Pecos)
4
Upper Colorado (western Colorado, eastern Utah, southwest Wyoming, and portions of Arizona and New Mexico)
― 370 ― will have political, social, and environmental impacts. In most western states, the diversion of irrigation water will result in a loss of cropland because rainfall in these areas is too low to sustain dryland crop production. Consequently, the lands taken from production should be revegetated to ensure that environmental hazards are minimized.
Conversion of Lands to Expand Agriculture In 1977 there were nearly one billion acres of nonfederal rural land not used for cropland in the United States. Of this total, 127 million acres have high or medium potential for cropland.[6] Consequently, there is ample land available for expanding our cropland base. Converting this land to cropland would result in both losses and gains. Wind and water erosion problems could be substantial, and special care would be necessary. If large acreages of rangeland and forest land were converted to cropland, this would reduce production of forage and wood products. Loss of forest and rangelands would also affect water runoff and streamflows in some areas. If wetlands were also drained and converted to cropland, wildlife habitat would be changed. The conversion of these lands to cropland could, however, significantly increase the nation's ability to produce food and fiber for use at home and for export. The rate of conversion and the extent of environmental impact are difficult to assess. Technologies are presently available and others are emerging which could expand agricultural production even while maintaining or enhancing the environment. Adoption of these technologies, however, is not sufficient; analysis of the political, social, and economic factors associated with the adoption of these technologies is also needed.
Impacts of Land Use Changes on Other Resources Fish and Wildlife Fish and wildlife are extremely sensitive to environmental change. Land use changes nearly always affect them, as a result of one or more of the following—stream temperature, amount of runoff, draining of wetlands, clearing of forests, cultivation of rangelands, and sedimentation. Land use changes are imperative, however, if the anticipated needs for food and fiber are to be met.
― 371 ― Declining water supplies and rising costs associated with irrigation will have pronounced effects on the use of water, the most significant of which will be the reduced quantity of water applied per acre for irrigation. Water conservation and irrigation efficiences will have direct effects on environmental, social, and economic conditions as changes in streamflow and quality occur. Although change in land use is inevitable, it is important to realize that change sometimes enhances the environment. A well managed farm is an
ideal habitat for many kinds of wildlife. By 2000, conservation tillage will be utilized on about 80 percent of the cropland, and this will greatly increase cover for wildlife. In the Texas High Plains, dramatic increases in the populations of dove and pheasants have already been noted with the increased use of conservation tillage systems. Responsible agencies should monitor the effects of agricultural activities on fish and wildlife resources closely; at the same time, they should try to dispel the beliefs of many who assume that only negative impacts occur.
Natural, Historic, and Wilderness Areas Natural, historic, and wilderness areas require water of ample quantity and quality, or the esthetic values of these areas will suffer. Although the amount of the nation's water resources that is consumed by such uses is minute with respect to the total, it is appropriate that some areas be preserved. While all groups generally agree with this principle, they can seldom agree on the specifics. Though only relatively small quantities of water are at stake, particular locations will be crucially affected. Natural areas are particularly sensitive to irrigation projects. Considerable interest in recent years has pertained to wetlands, as vast acreages have been drained to expand cropland areas. Society will have to decide the proper balance between national economic development and historic and cultural values. As the pressure on our natural resources becomes greater, water and land resource assessment and planning will take on an ever increasing importance.
Summary and Conclusions Irrigated acreage is expected to continue to expand, but at a much slower rate than during the past few decades. Acreage will decrease in some regions because of overdraft of groundwater, uneconomic conditions, and loss of water supplies to other uses.
― 372 ― As water supplies decline and the costs of applying the water increase, technologies will emerge to increase conservation, which may provide water for alternative purposes such as fuel production. Even with improved conservation, however, streamflows in the semiarid West are likely to continue to decrease. The relationship between quantity and quality of water is clear; water quality problems become more acute with reduced streamflows, and this affects fish and wildlife maintenance as well as recreational activities. All impacts, however, need not be negative. Improved
water technologies will also allow better control of fertilizers and pesticides, and lesser amounts of these reaching surface or groundwater supplies. Conservation tillage systems result in substantially more plant residue remaining on the surface, and this encourages some forms of wildlife by providing better habitat. Marked changes in irrigation practices and land use will have environmental impacts. While it is impossible to foresee perfectly, we can see trends and make some projections about the implications of certain developments. Careful assessment at this time should help us to better utilize our natural resources in the future.
Discussion: Thomas L. Kimball Stewart and Harman have presented a good discussion of the impact of agricultural activities on the environment. I would like to add some further comments. Water manipulation has some serious adverse impacts on the environment. Dams, diversions from streams, and a lowered water table from overpumping are cases in point. Increasing series of dams and impoundments has greatly impaired and in some cases destroyed the anadromous fish runs along both coasts. Hatcheries have had to replace much of the natural spawning lost, but most of the hatchery production is near the coast which is no help to the production lost in stream courses inland. The diversion of smaller streams has a disastrous effect on the aquatic ecosystem. The problem is further exacerbated by the fact that greater demands for water usually come when streamflows are at the lowest ebb. The fisheries values in the Blue River of Colorado will be greatly impaired unless minimum streamflows can be guaranteed below the Dillon diversion when most of the water is diverted across the Continental Divide to Denver. In the Central Utah Project there will be seven small trout streams in the high Uinta Mountains whose water flow will be completely diverted to serve the agricultural interests of central Utah, with no mitigation for the loss of the fisheries resource. The lowering of water tables by overpumping underground reservoirs can have a serious adverse effect on wildlife. The mesquite bosques of the lower Santa Cruz River in Arizona were destroyed by a lowered water table. These large trees served as the principal nesting area of the white-winged dove, and their destruction brought about a marked decline in dove numbers. Irrigation canals, particularly those lined with concrete, pose some serious problems. Unless they are fenced, many of the terrestrial forms of wildlife may drown; wide canals often interfere with the migrations of many of the ungulates. Fencing and natural looking bridges can solve most of these difficulties.
― 374 ― World food production is projected to increase 90 percent over the thirty years from 1970 to 2000. An additional 140 million acres of land would be required for the production of principal crops. Stewart and Harman conclude that such a shift in land use will impact the environment, but not all those impacts will be negative. Negative environmental impact, however, is difficult if not impossible to define—the definition is, like beauty, in the eye of the beholder. For example, if we view environmental quality as maintaining the integrity of our natural ecosystems, then it follows that whenever we alter those systems a negative impact occurs. On the other hand, if we define maintaining environmental quality as mitigation where possible, or the substitution of a modified ecosystem that produces benefits that are acceptable to landowners, the public, and public policy makers, then we can say that many impacts are not negative. We could have fifty million buffalo again in the United States, but we would have to take out the fences in the midsection of the country, restore the prairie, and eliminate the competition from domestic livestock for the grass. The transformation of the prairie into farmland also extirpated the grouse and prairie chicken. The grain farm ecosystem, however, created a suitable environment for the Chinese ring-necked pheasant, and for some this has been an acceptable substitute for the indigenous species lost. Nevertheless, all is not well for the ring-necked pheasant. Monoculture, clean farming, and the use of chemicals, pesticides, herbicides, and fertilizers have increased crop yields but taken away winter and nesting cover to the detriment of the birds. The problem is that generally we have single use concepts of land and water management. What is really needed is to develop multiple use objectives for every land and water project. We should encourage every private landowner to consider the many values and objectives that are inherent in land and water management, and provide him with as much information as is available to make intelligent decisions. Multiple use objectives should be required on all major projects where public tax money is utilized. Although there are many laws designed to accomplish this purpose, many of our public servants have to be pushed into efforts to achieve that objective. Water pollution is a much greater problem than recognized by Stewart and Harman. While great strides have been made in cleaning up our nation's water supply from known sources of pollution, nonpoint sources continue to be a real and increasing threat. Pesticides and residue nutrients continue to play havoc
― 375 ― with aquatic ecosystems. One of the consequences of the tremendous
quantity of added nutrients is the accelerated eutrophication of our lakes. Lake Okeechobee in Florida, one of the nation's largest fresh water lakes, is rapidly losing its premium water quality by pesticide and fertilizer runoff and pumpback from agricultural lands irrigated from the lake. Salt water intrusions into fresh water aquifers and estuaries is also a major problem. The quality of water in the brackish water zones in our estuaries is becoming more difficult to maintain. These waters are critical to the wellbeing of many pelagic fishes and, biologically speaking, are the most valuable and productive. Diversion of the principal flow of large rivers, such as the Sacramento, could allow salt water intrusions that could impair the entire Delta and San Francisco Bay ecosystems. Waste of irrigation water is one of the most critical environmental problems of proper water and agricultural management. The competition for available water grows daily in the semiarid western states. While food production will always enjoy a high priority in water use, that priority should not extend beyond the actual amounts of water necessary to grow crops to maturity under the best available technology. Western water law is based upon beneficial use of water; waste can never be construed as a beneficial use. The time will come when water right owners will lose water that is wasted. The authors project that nonirrigated farmland will increase substantially in the future as underground supplies are depleted and the need for food increases. Let us hope to avoid the mistakes of the "Dirty Thirties." Those lands whose soil texture is subject to severe wind erosion, particularly national grasslands, should be purchased by the federal government to protect them from serious and continuing erosion under cultivation. Those lands should never be put to the plow unless proven technologies demonstrate adequate wind erosion protection. In the minds of most naturalists, variety and abundance of wildlife is the litmus paper of environmental quality. It is true that changes in habitat are not always negative to all species of wildlife, but such changes will adversely affect some or many species. Many of our wildlife species are adaptable to environmental change. For example, the ubiquitous coyote is now as much at home in the garbage cans of Los Angeles as he is in the Sierra wilderness. On the other hand, the prairie chicken is usually extirpated from areas where the strutting grounds are plowed and planted with crops. The mountain lion and grizzly
― 376 ― bear are true wilderness animals; when humans move in, they move out. Once priorities of land and water use are determined, the solution to many
environmental difficulties is to collect enough knowledge and information about the established objectives to minimize adverse impacts and maximize the enhancement of environmental quality. Such effort will preserve adequate habitat for variety and adequate numbers of wildlife. In order to minimize adverse environmental impacts created by a diminishing water supply, the following suggestions and recommendations are made. 1) Devise a program to eliminate water waste in irrigated agriculture. If such a program could be developed and successfully executed, nothing could provide more benefits to all interests. 2) Develop multiple use objectives on all land and water development projects. When concern is shown for the many and varied interests in land and water management, there may be increasing support for the project. 3) Take a close look at impacts on fish and wildlife resources. These are indicators of environmental quality. 4) Include economic and social factors in long range planning, because these will probably have greater impact on the future of agriculture in America than any other. With two-thirds of the world hungry today, the United States still cannot sell its bumper crops of grain for an amount sufficient to cover the cost of production. Even if the grain could be sold at a profit, the means of transporting foodstuffs to those who need it most is completely antiquated and inadequate. 5) Develop a program to preserve the "Class I" farmlands in the United States. Robert Frost once said, "What makes a great nation in the beginning is a good chunk of real estate." In the United States we have a great chunk of real estate. Whether we remain a great nation will depend upon how wisely we develop and use it. The most dramatic success story in the United States is our agricultural production. We can stay a super power only insofar as
― 377 ― we maintain that agricultural success. The world cannot march ahead on an empty stomach. 6) The United States Department of Agriculture should review its priorities, and do so frequently in the future. The Soil Conservation Service was created to protect our nation's farmland from soil and water erosion. Now we should enlarge and expand research and extension efforts to achieve better land and water management. Technologies must be developed and brought to the landowner and applied on the land.
7) Agricultural as well as all other special interests should wean themselves from the public treasury. The nation's current economic condition is due in part to all segments of society running to the taxpayer for help. Government can no longer afford to expend more money than it takes in. Water projects and programs must bear their true costs—those who benefit must pay. Such a principle applied to all interests subsidized by the taxpayer would go a long way towards solving our nation's current economic ills as well as its environmental problems.
Discussion: George H. Wallen Stewart and Harman do a good job in discussing how reductions of irrigated agriculture will likely result in the use of more marginal lands for production. Intensive farming practices, where chemicals are used to enhance production and all available space is tilled, limit environmental amenities, whether or not the fields are irrigated. Such generalizations are useful from a theoretical viewpoint. However, more specific information on the relationships between irrigated agriculture and environmental quality is necessary if irrigation farmers and project managers are to maintain desirable environmental amenities. The addition or withdrawal of water may have significantly different environmental impacts in different parts of the country. Effects on fish and wildlife illustrate the point that environmental values vary with farming practices and with regional climatic conditions.
― 378 ― Fish and wildlife and other environmental resources are significantly affected when irrigation systems are installed and operated on lands previously dryfarmed or idle. The species composition and populations of wild animals and native plant species change significantly. Native species are not always lost; however, their numbers may be greatly depressed, while species that can adapt to the new water regime and cropping pattern may expand. For example, in the Texas Panhandle, species such as prairie chicken, prairie dog, and antelope decline with more intensive farming and improved water delivery. On the other hand, populations of pheasant, whitetailed deer, and waterfowl increase in response to the increase in available food and the additional permanent water areas provided to store and deliver irrigation water to the fields. In some parts of the country, the principal effect on wildlife resources from the installation of irrigation facilities may be the drying out of wetlands so
that crops can be produced with the regulated application of the irrigation water. This type of change augurs against wetland-dependent species in favor of upland varieties. In these areas it is the drainage rather than water delivery facilities that has the most significant effect. Irrigation projects may also be attractive recreation areas. Data for reclamation projects show that, in 1980, approximately 67 million visitordays were spent at the almost 6 million acres of land and water available for recreation at 214 operating reclamation projects or units. Sightseeing was reported to be the most popular activity, followed by fishing and camping. Most of the use was at multipurpose projects, where water is stored for power production, flood control, and municipal water supply in addition to irrigation. However, visitor use of smaller irrigation reservoirs and conveyance facilities was also substantial. When water that has been available for irrigation is reduced or diverted to other uses, a change in environmental quality occurs that is just as dramatic as the first application of the irrigation system. In most of the West, the most common reason for halting irrigation in any given area is the expansion of urban growth. In those instances, fields become roads, parking lots, buildings, and lawns. Water formerly used in agriculture is used for municipal and industrial purposes. Irrigated fields are seldom abandoned because of lack of water. The more likely scenario has been reversion to nonirrigation, or the temporary return to dryland crops until new arrangements were made for water. In these cases, the environmental attributes of an area change little.
― 379 ― Under unusual circumstances, fields may be left idle or abandoned with the loss of irrigation water. Such lands return to natural conditions with a dominance of native vegetation at a rate that can be correlated to the amount of natural precipitation available. In the central Washington area, where the Columbia Basin Project is located, fields return to natural conditions after three to five years. In the much dryer central part of Arizona, perennial plants such as greasewood may be established in wetter areas after 8 to 10 years, but many native species never return to former densities. The speed with which lands formerly irrigated return to desirable quality is affected by the measures taken by land managers, whether private landowners or public agencies. Fish and game species can be encouraged to return to formerly irrigated areas by proper food and cover plantings and by the provision of suitable watering areas. Careful use of pesticides and fertilizers also may encourage reestablishment of desirable plant and animal species. An abandoned field that is surrounded by cropland may provide an
island of cover and sanctuary for many wildlife species. Abandoned ditches and canals may also provide desirable food and cover if properly managed. Native species may be encouraged if that is a desirable goal. As irrigation facilities are reduced, public use of such facilities will also decline unless positive steps are taken to manage the areas to provide desirable recreation resources. If one holds a more utilitarian view, it is easy to rationalize that most of the changes caused by irrigation are highly valued by people living in the last 20 years of the 20th century. For the most part, environmental amenities have been piggybacked either by accident or design onto existing projects. Obvious examples are permanent wetlands in desert climates, high quality recreation lakes resulting from overdesign of supply facilities, and vegetation at the edge of fields that results from overapplication of water. If water becomes limited, however, these amenities may be hard to keep.
― 380 ―
PART IV— STRATEGIES FOR MAINTAINING AGRICULTURAL VIABILITY WITH LIMITED WATER SUPPLIES Chapter 16— What Farmers Can Do for Themselves by Cecil Miller, Jr. and Bartley P. Cardon
Abstract Irrigation costs on some western farms are approaching half the total costs of production. These high and increasing water costs, plus some states' new laws about water rights, are forcing steps by individual farmers to conserve water. However, conservation measures must themselves be economical in order for farmers to adopt them, and many of the measures are expensive investments. The solutions for farmers are: (1) new irrigation technologies such as laser-leveling and drip systems; (2) management for high water efficiency in scheduling, crop choices, and other variables; and (3) support for desirable developments in the private and government sectors, such as inverse utility pricing, funding for research, and cost-sharing programs.
Motives for Conservation For western farmers, the conservation of water is not only a desirable goal for protecting a cherished resource, it has become an economic necessity. In this chapter some of the changes in production techniques and management methods happening "down on the farm" will be summarized. Some are well along, some are just beginning, and others are still problematical. Western agriculture faces the biggest change in its history. Water has become a bigger and bigger share of our production costs; individual farmers in Arizona and other states are making decisions to invest in ways to use less. Consider these cost figures from an area of central Arizona that uses groundwater. In the period from 1975 to 1980, the costs of water for growing wheat jumped from 46 percent of the total variable costs of production to 58 percent; for growing alfalfa, water's share of variable costs climbed from 54 percent to 65 percent; for cotton, water costs went from 35 to 40 percent.[1]
― 381 ― The dropping water table in many parts of the West is only one factor behind higher water costs. Electric rates for irrigation pumps, which had crept up from about 7 mills per kilowatt hour after World War II only to about 11 mills by 1973, then skyrocketed. In many areas, they have climbed in the past decade from about 11 mills to 55 mills, quintupling in 10 years. And farmers today hear predictions that these rates will continue to climb at a pace 3 to 4 percent greater than the inflation rate for the rest of this century.[2] There is, of course, an option to better water conservation on farms. Thousands of acres of abandoned farmland in Arizona help remind farmers of the consequences of not facing the facts. Much of this acreage was put into production when cotton prices were high in the 1950s. The land was abandoned as water tables and commodity prices descended together. Most farmers, however, have found ways to cut water losses enough to stay in business, through a variety of investments and adaptations. Before we discuss farmers' strategies, a brief note about a development in Arizona that may spread to other states: the Arizona 1980 Groundwater Management Act has added a legal compulsion to the pre-existing economic compulsion for farmers to reduce water use. Provisions of the Act are described in other chapters of this volume. We add two points. First, high water costs may still be a more severe restriction than the legal limits in many areas. Second, whatever the legal limits, the measures that a farmer
takes to meet those limits must still come out in black ink on his budget sheet.
Situation and Solutions The situation facing farmers is this: simple economics and, in some places, new laws are forcing steps to conserve water. However, conservation measures must pay for themselves, and many of them are expensive investments. The solutions for farmers are these: 1) new irrigation technologies, 2) management for high water efficiency in scheduling, crop selection, equipment maintenance and other variables, and 3) support for desirable changes in the private and government sectors.
― 382 ―
Irrigation: Preparation Concern for reducing water in irrigation systems is nothing new. Early irrigation canals in the West were earthen. Too much of the water they carried leaked out of the canals instead of reaching the fields. Lining the ditches with concrete began in the first half of this century, then accelerated with better technology for the job in the 1950s. Today, about 90 percent of onfarm irrigation ditches in Arizona are lined.[3] This step prevents seepage losses that can reach 10 to 50 percent of the water for every half mile it travels in an unlined ditch. Concrete-lined ditches cost about three to five dollars per foot. Another adaptation many farmers have made is to shorten the length of furrows in their fields. Longer runs of water are inefficient because water at the uphill end begins to seep below the root zone by the time enough water reaches the downhill end of the run. There's a trade-off, however. Shorter runs can reduce efficiency in the use of land, work hours, and field machinery. For most soils, Arizona farmers have found quarter-mile runs to be a good balance between efficient use of water and efficient use of land and machinery. For sandy soils, many farmers have gone to runs of just one-eighth of a mile.
Another improvement in preparation of fields for irrigation is laser leveling. A rotating command post emits a laser beam at a fixed height. The beam hits a receiver mounted on a scraper, and the signal automatically keeps the scraper blade adjusted to level the field precisely. The system can be set for either a constant slope or a dead-level field. Either use of laser leveling cuts water waste by removing the irregular high and low spots that result in overwatering some areas in order to give other areas enough water. On dead-level fields, irrigation is applied over the whole 10-20 acre basin rather than in parallel furrows. The water application efficiency for dead-level fields can be 85 to 90 percent, compared to 50 to 65 percent for traditional slope-furrow systems. What's more, the more even watering can increase crop yields zero to 30 percent, depending on how uneven the field was before laser leveling.[4] The high benefits come with high costs. Converting from a traditional, slopefurrow field to a laser-leveled, level-basin system can cost five hundred to nine hundred dollars per acre at the start. To these costs must be added a lost growing season during the conversion, lost acreage used for dikes, plus extra expenses
― 383 ― for farm machinery and labor each year with a level-basin system. For some Arizona farms, the cost of dead-leveling is more than one fourth of the market value of the irrigated land being leveled. Still, since the mid-1970s, farmers have laser leveled about 125,000 acres of Arizona farmland. About 100,000 of that total are in level-basin systems, mostly in Yuma and Pinal counties.[5] Cost-benefit calculations for laser leveling are complicated. A new publication from the University of Arizona Agricultural Experiment Station helps farmers determine whether and when laser leveling would be profitable for their specific circumstances.[6]
Irrigation: Application Sprinkler and drip irrigation systems are other big investments that farmers can make to save water. Sprinklers give about 70 to 80 percent efficiency in application of water to the root zone, at initial costs of roughly $200 to $400 per acre. Drip systems can push application efficiency to 90 percent with initial costs of $650 and up per acre.[7] Farmers have invested in sprinkler systems for about 75,000 acres in
Arizona. Most of these are high-pressure systems installed before the rise on energy costs of the mid-1970s. Now, farmers are opting for newer, lowpressure sprinkler systems in areas where they can be used. Sprinkler systems have problems on soils with low infiltration rates and in windy areas. Drip systems are drawing lots of attention from Arizona farmers. Some promising results have come from a privately financed pilot project on Howard Wuertz's farms in Pinal County, an excellent example of the kind of initiative farmers are showing in water conservation. Wuertz and his assistant manager described their program at a field day in June 1982. Most of the 265 people who came were other farmers. They learned that, with an 11-acre drip system in 1981, Wuertz used about seven inches of water for each bale of cotton, compared to about 20 inches per bale in typical furrowirrigated fields. The drip plots outyielded furrow fields on a per-acre basis and needed only about half as much applied nitrogen because it could be applied more precisely with the drip system. The drip plots also had fewer problems with insects and weeds, probably due to a drier surface.[8] With drip systems scaled up to 180 acres in 1982, Wuertz invested about $950 per acre. If results like 1981 are typical, the payback period could be less than two years. This includes the $1100 that was spent in making field equipment for laying drip tape six rows at a time.
― 384 ― In 1982, drip irrigation systems in Arizona cotton fields grew from 11 acres to more than 1,000 acres on several farms in three counties. Hundreds of farmers will be looking closely at current results. The American Farm Bureau Federation conducts an annual Farm Bureau Energy Idea Search to identify some of the farmers who pioneer new systems. Last year, one such farmer was an Idaho potato grower who installed underground, aerated drip irrigation lines. His potato yield nearly doubled the county average, and the new system quadrupled his net income.[9] Plastic mulching is another new technology some farmers are already using, especially on vegetable crops. Covering seed beds with plastic covers reduces evaporation loss. The covering also helps keep the soil warm, so seeds germinate earlier. That extra benefit helps justify the cost of the plastic mulching. Water harvesting is an old irrigation technology that is beginning to draw interest again from some farmers in the West. Some of the land is used as a run-off surface to concentrate rainwater on a smaller area where crops are planted. Much of the interest so far has been on Indian reservations. A low ratio of land value to water and crop values is needed to make this system
pay.
Greenhouse Hydroponics On the other hand, greenhouse hydroponics may become a way to farm with high water efficiency even where land costs are high. Some see it as urban farming. Several major companies already have pilot projects, including Archer Daniels Midland in Illinois, Kraft in Arizona, and Whitaker in California. The Kraft project in Tucson, operated by the University of Arizona's Environmental Research Laboratory, is turning out 18,000 heads of lettuce a week from 50,000 square feet of greenhouse. Growing each kilogram of lettuce takes about 30 liters of water, less than one-third as much as used for producing a kilogram of lettuce in an open field. Some smaller-scale hydroponic tests have even cut water use to 19 liters per kilogram of lettuce. Losses due to deep seepage and evaporation are eliminated or greatly reduced. Next door to the lettuce greenhouse, another 6.9 acres of hydroponic greenhouses produce 9,600 pounds of cherry tomatoes and 4,800 pounds of European cucumbers a week. The tomatoes require only one-fourth the water as the same weight grown in open field conditions. The cucumbers use only one-tenth the water used as an open-field product. In smaller tests, even these low water requirements were halved (see Table 16.1).
― 385 ―
Table 16.1 Net Water Use in Vegetable Production Controlled Environment (Hydroponic Greenhouse) vs. Open Field (Liters of water used per kilogram of edible product) Controlled Environment
Open Field Conditions
Small Scale
Production Scale
Cherry tomatoes
13
30
125
European
10
20
205
cucumbers Lettuce
19
30
125
Source: Merle H. Jensen, "Growing Crops in a Controlled Environment," Standard Chartered Review, Standard Chartered Bank, Ltd., London, March 1979. (Productionscale controlled-environment figures on water use from personal communication, July 1982.)
For salad vegetables, these hydroponic greenhouses are still not a breakeven technology. Higher costs for water and transportation may change that. Meanwhile, similar methods used by Archer Daniels Midland look profitable for growing ornamental plants such as African violets.
Lower-Quality Water Besides looking for ways to use less water per unit of production, farmers are looking for ways to use lower-quality water. About one-twelfth of the United States lies over groundwater too saline for traditional crops. So far, farmers don't have much opportunity to use brackish water for irrigation, unless they can dilute it to higher quality. Some research on salt-tolerant plants looks promising. Treated sewage effluent is another story. Around Tucson, the political issue has been who gets the opportunity to use effluent, not who has to. The Cortaro-Marana Irrigation District figured that the 76 pounds of nitrogen and 37 pounds of phosphate in an acre-foot of effluent are worth $15 as fertilizer.[10] That value is discounted by the amount of nitrogen naturally in the district's groundwater. Other estimates peg the fertilizer value of treated effluent at $30 per acre-foot. Delivery of effluent piped basically by gravity flow from a nearby treatment plant can also save money compared to pumping deep groundwater. In most
― 386 ― applications, effluent needs to be diluted one-to-one or further with fresher water.
Irrigation Management Besides major changes in field preparation, irrigation systems, or water
source, better management of existing systems offers farmers several chances to cut water costs. A farmer needs to know exactly how much water he is using to grow a crop. For this, pumps should be metered. One part of Arizona's Groundwater Management Act will work to farmers' advantage: they can no longer put off installing the flow meters that can help save money. Every farmer knows how big his fields are, but with water costs approaching half of total production costs, it may be smarter to think about yields per acre-inch rather than just yields per acre. Flow meters can figure pump efficiency as well as water use. Pump companies in Arizona indicate that farmers are replacing pump bowls much more frequently than in the past.[11] This step toward efficient pumping reduces the cost of water, though not the amount of water used. To minimize water use, farm managers need to keep abreast of developments in irrigation systems and crop choices, and frequently calculate their options. Scheduling of irrigation will be fitted more precisely to the needs of the crop rather than to labor schedules. Center-pivot or linear-move sprinkler systems require less labor than open-furrow irrigation, but level-basin systems need more. For higher technology systems, labor must be skilled. Water application can be combined with application of fertilizer and pesticides. The high initial costs of high-technology irrigation weigh in favor of larger farm sizes. Farms using the deepest groundwater may face an insuperable disadvantage no matter what irrigation efficiencies they adopt.
Crop Selection What crops should farmers be growing to cope with high water costs? Some predict a shift away from field crops such as grains and cotton toward higher-value specialty crops such as vegetables, fruits, and nuts. The value of these crops is, however, highly sensitive to supply. Tomatoes and lemons can bring a good price when they hit the market at the right time, but if too many other growers have the same crop, it may not be even worth the cost of harvesting. Farmers considering high-value crops need to spot a market niche they can fit.
― 387 ― Though grapes, lettuce, and melons are all high-value crops that can be grown with efficient drip-irrigation systems, the acreage of each in Arizona has declined from 1965 to 1980 (see Table 16.2). Citrus acreage in the state dropped by one-fifth between 1975 and 1980. Near Yuma, a big wind machine now stands in the middle of an alfalfa field. The lemon trees have
been ripped out as unprofitable.
Table 16.2 Irrigated Crop Acreage in Arizona 1965
1980
Grapes
15,700
12,400
Lettuce
56,000
37,500
Melons
18,150
8,100
Source: Arizona Crop and Livestock Reporting Service, Phoenix.
Vegetables have shorter growing seasons than some other crops, hence use less water per season. Making use of slower evaporation rates in winter gives winter crops an advantage in water consumption. However, some higher value crops, especially tree crops, use no less water than field crops (see Table 16.3). Growers are finding markets for some specialty crops and that gives them an edge in covering high production costs due to expensive water. In the past 12 years, the certified seed industry has grown fourfold in Arizona, to more than 70,000 acres.
New and Improved Crops Several new crops are on the horizon as potential choices for western farmers. Guayule yields latex for rubber and grows with two to three feet of irrigation a year. Buffalo gourd grows with about half that much; it has seeds rich in oil and protein, plus a large, starchy root. Jojoba bushes need about a foot and a half of annual irrigation after they are established. The liquid wax pressed from jojoba seeds is useful in cosmetics and lubricants. Grain amaranth, once a major crop of the Aztecs, is among several other candidates for desert crops of the future.
― 388 ―
Table 16.3 Consumptive Use Totals in Acre-Inches for Some Arizona Crops
Crop
Seasonal Water Use Crop
Seasonal Water Use
Cotton
41
Sorghum
25
Sugarbeets
43
Grapefruit
48
Alfalfa
74
Late grapes
20
Bermuda grass lawn
44
Broccoli
20
Wheat
26
Late canteloupe
17
Barley
25
Lettuce
9
Source: L.J. Erie, O.F. French, D.A. Bucks, and K. Harris, Consumptive Use of Water by Major Crops in the Southwestern United States, Conservation Research Report 29, USDA Agricultural Research Service, May 1982.
Of these plants, only jojoba has been planted on a commercial scale. About 22,000 acres of it are growing in the West. Some farmers are following closely the development of markets and of production know-how for these potential crops. Halophytes draw interest as potential crops that thrive on salty water. They are in an even earlier stage of development than buffalo gourd or guayule. Researchers are developing salt-tolerant varieties of barley, tomatoes, alfalfa, and other traditional crop plants. They have even produced a barley that can grow in seawater, but yields are not yet sufficient economically. Barley-breeder Dr. R.T. Ramage puts the point concisely. "Right now, you could grow thousands of acres of barley on sand dunes with seawater, and lose money on every acre of it. Still, it's good to know that if we did have to depend on seawater sometime in the future, we could take these domesticated crops and have a usable production from them."[12]
Other Actions for Farm Groups What actions should be taken by western farmers? Not only do we need to reduce water use, we need to do it without going
― 389 ― broke. Besides exploring options on our own and practicing alert management, we can join with other farmers to encourage beneficial developments. First, we can seek public support for water-saving measures. Arizona's state legislators are granting tax credits for the installation of precise water measuring devices. The U.S. Agricultural Stabilization and Conservation Service offers a cost-sharing program for laser leveling. Accelerated depreciation allowances for private investment in laser leveling also encourage that technology. Similar incentive programs could be started for other ways to conserve water. Second, we can urge water suppliers to adopt inverse pricing policies. That is, the more gallons used per unit of production, the higher the price per gallon. This would reward efficiency more than flat rates do. Third, we can encourage conservation by other water users. Inverse pricing for home water bills would help cut urban use. In a more direct action, the Arizona Cotton Growers' Association has been distributing water-saving shower heads at cost as part of a public relations effort to encourage water conservation in cities. Fourth, we can give financial and political support to research. Development of better irrigation systems and of water-saving crop varieties deserves our backing. Similarly, we should support studies of potential new supplies of water, such as solar desalination, a delivery system from the Northwest, and containment of flood waters. Fifth, we can help educate young people about the importance of water to agriculture and the importance of agriculture to society. As one example, the American Farm Bureau Federation is working with a group called Water & Man, Incorporated, to develop a curriculum for fifth to twelfth graders about water and agriculture. Western agriculture can't survive unless individual farmers find ways to make a living while using less water. But individual farmers will have a better chance to do that if we join forces with other farmers and with other
water users.
Discussion: Russell Bean Miller and Cardon present a graphic picture of farming in Arizona today, and we who farm the High Plains of northwestern Texas share many of their problems. As the two regions are quite distinct in character, some differences in procedure will be discussed. While much of Southwest farming is located in the desert and is almost fully dependent on applied water, the High Plains can be dry farmed. Our soils and terrain generally are excellent, among the best in the world. Rainfall averages 20 inches annually on the east side, perhaps 14 inches on the west, and comes in two peaks of May-June and September-October. The early peak often is violent, thus shortening an already short growing season due to the altitude of 3,000 to 4,000 feet. Even so, cotton is the dominant crop of the southern part around Lubbock. In the northern part around Amarillo the dominant crops are wheat, feed grains, and some sugarbeets and vegetables. Soybeans are fairly common, often replacing cotton crops damaged by storms in late May and early June. Summers are hot and winters almost arctic. Irrigation began seriously to be a factor on the High Plains after World War II, and was aimed primarily toward
― 391 ― supplementing rainfall during the dry spell of July-August. Later, irrigation began to be aimed toward maximum growth and yield until the 1970s when escalating fuel costs and higher pump lifts caused us to begin to take another look at some of the dry farming techniques we once used. Most of the more obvious water-saving techniques such as underground pipe and tailwater pits have been put to use, and there has been a rapid increase in the number of sprinkler systems. Next there has been a shift to crops requiring less water—corn to milo to cotton, for example. The most widely used techniques in cotton culture have been the deliberate use of less water to create a smaller plant, and a skip-row system, usually two rows planted and one blank, where the blank area serves as a moisture reservoir. Irrigation, if done at all, usually goes only in the middle between the two rows. Thus only one middle in three is irrigated. The skip-row method generally has been confined to cotton areas, but it has been used for milo and soybeans. Corn and sugarbeets generally are grown
where the soils are not too sandy and the irrigation wells are strong. In the corn growing area are two interesting specialty crops, white corn for the tortilla trade and popcorn for the movie trade. Vegetable and fruit crops have not been too successful on the High Plains due to unpredictable weather and lack of hand labor. Efforts to move into higher value crops have been taking place as long as most of us can remember. Onions and potatoes are the most widely grown vegetables while about the only tree crop to survive is the pecan. Wine grapes are being grown on a small scale and seem to show some promise. Pecans and grapes work well with drip systems of irrigation, and thus fit well into the trend toward conservation of water and energy. Subirrigation systems would seem to be the approach to an ideal, but so far such systems have had maintenance problems and costs such as to preclude their ready acceptance. Furrow irrigation is, admittedly, an inefficient system. Dead-level basins are a near-ultimate in efficient use of irrigation water, but economics, soils, and water supply do not encourage use of the system on the High Plains. The trend has been toward sprinkler systems instead. At first glance, sprinklers don't appear to be very efficient as they spray water into the wind to be evaporated, but most farmers saw the advantages over furrow irrigation very quickly. Even application was the difference. Later, many sprinkler
― 392 ― systems were modified to emit a low, coarse spray, or even to emit water at ground level through a sock with an efficiency about on par with a drip system. Even rice farmers on the Texas Gulf coast are experimenting with sprinklers to replace the flood borders traditional to rice culture since the beginning of history. Use of effluent water for irrigation has a long history on the High Plains, going back at least to 1930 when Lubbock's effluent irrigated a 320-acre field of alfalfa. Today several thousand acres are irrigated from a much larger Lubbock, and electric utilities and industries compete to use the effluent. Although the High Plains traditionally has produced bulk crops of relatively low value, soaring costs are forcing us to look toward crops of higher value, or toward crops which can be grown more economically. Our agricultural experiment stations have done a good job of exposing us to new crops and new ideas. We have tried sesame, sunflowers, castor beans, safflower, various millets—the list goes on and on. One of the best crops to come along was hybrid sorghum seed, introduced in the 1930s, and many thousands of
acres of land are devoted to this crop. We are fully aware of how greenhouses can turn out crops with low water use. Tomato greenhouses were very common on the High Plains a few years ago, but most of them either have gone out of business or have switched to growing ornamental plants. The vast feedyards for cattle on the High Plains help our farmers with a nearby market for our grain, and we appreciate the price advantage thus established. Our grain used to suffer heavy shipping discounts. Many of us are aware of desert crops such as jojoba, guayule, and some of the others, but we don't know much about their adaptation and practicability. One of our animal husbandry professors at Texas Tech is a strong promoter of the common weed, Kochia scoparia, as being about as good as alfalfa when handled and harvested properly. It grows rapidly and easily without irrigation and with little care. Its progress will be observed. Our area has little if any work going on in use of low quality water other than effluent. Generally we have either good quality water or none. In closing, we have been warned by the utility people that natural gas under deregulation may continue to escalate in price even if other petroleum products tend to stabilize in cost, all based on energy equivalents. The implications are obvious for farmers who use natural gas, directly or by way of the power plant, to pump irrigation water.
― 393 ―
Discussion: Marc Faye With the vast array of crops produced in California, no single system of irrigation is suitable for all use, regardless of its efficiency. Even so, minimizing the use of water consistent with the maximizing of yields is going to be necessary for the very survival of many of our California farming operations. Computer analysis of water needs is in the farmer's future. The dairy and livestock industries in their computerized ration analysis are teaching us the techniques we will need to know. A number of problems are associated with the various alternative means of minimizing water use discussed in the Miller-Cardon paper; my comments follow.
Conservation. Probably the cheapest approach to water conservation a farmer has is to shift to drought-tolerant crops or to set aside land in fallow. Unfortunately, those opportunities are severely limited by economic considerations. Farmers should certainly consider options in this regard; it does raise the question of producing for world markets in view of national or regional needs. Of course, wide swings in world prices and political influences may be an even more important factor in cropping patterns. Drip and Sprinkler. The use of new irrigation systems, including drip and sprinkler, may be comparatively energy-inefficient, and both are expensive to install. For example, a farmer with riparian rights along a river may pump water once and irrigate his entire farm with a gravity system. Any other system will require additional purchased energy and high capital investment. Moreover, water quality must be such as to avoid salt buildup in soils and clogging of tubing and emitters. Besides, what do we do with abandoned hose systems when we change to another crop? Does anyone know the halflife of polypropylene? Some of the sprinkler systems in current use require high water pressure and may be costly in terms of energy use and evaporation losses. As the authors point out, we are in a transition phase between high and low pressure sprinkler systems, and conversions will occur favoring the most cost-effective systems. Plastic Mulch. California producers have used plastic mulches for some crops for a number of years, particularly for such high value crops as strawberries. The cost must be recovered from water conservation, reduction in tillage, enhancement of yields, and also from earlier production which increases the value of the crop. The use of plastic mulch purely to conserve water is not
― 394 ― likely to be cost-effective within the foreseeable future in large-scale applications in California. Greenhouses. While California has a large acreage of floral and some vegetable production in greenhouses, the greenhouses have not been used principally as a means of water conservation. The scale of operation, the cost of the facilities, and the intense nature of the business, tend to discourage any rush into hydroponics on a commercial scale, unless justified on grounds other than merely water conservation. It may, however, be a way to return specialized crops to urban areas to avoid transportation costs and to reduce urban unemployment. Reclaimed Wastewater. California has been conducting experiments in the use of reclaimed sewage effluent for a number of years. Virtually all of our
dairy operations are designed to collect water used in the dairy barns and apply it to forage and field crops as a combination program of irrigation and fertilization. Water which was formerly a disposal problem has thus become an asset. Treated sewage or other wastewater also can be pumped back underground, especially where existing quality underground is undesirable for drinking anyway. In fact, the quality could actually be improved, aquifers would be maintained, and intrusion from adjoining aquifers could be challenged. Effluent, particularly industrial effluent, may contain dissolved heavy metals or levels of nitrates, making it unacceptable for general irrigation purposes. For purposes of acceptance and safety, the use of sewage effluent has been largely confined to irrigation of forage crops, golf courses, parks, and similar public and private areas. Someday, however, the public will likely accept the idea—after all, didn't Erma Bombeck observe that the garden is always greenest over the septic tank? Agricultural Load Management. Experimental work is being done by California's Public Utilities Commission, in cooperation with the two major utilities, Pacific Gas and Electric and Southern California Edison, in the area of Agricultural Load Management (A.L.M.). A.L.M. is a program allowing a lower electric rate for farmers who are willing to confine their use of electricity for irrigation to off-peak hours. Peak hours for electricity use are 1:00 to 6:00 p.m., which coincide with the high heat hours of the summer. A spinoff of this experiment may be a discovery that avoiding irrigation water application during the heat of the day results in reduced evaporation, thus saving water as well as power costs to farmers. This practice is limited, of course, by many elements, such as the source of the water, whether it is
― 395 ― used in open ditches or sprinklers, and whether it requires labor to monitor its use. Crop Selection. The problem of which crops a farmer can grow is determined not by one factor like saving of water, but by the entire mix of factors which influence his farming operation. Soil limitations may dictate that a farmer grow rice, for example, even though other crops might use less water. Rice, incidentally, is not as big a water user as many other irrigated crops with high evapotranspiration rates, such as walnuts. The farmer's decision on crop selection must be based on prospective yields, price expectations, and production costs, coupled with available land, equipment, and financing resources, as well as his ability to produce the given crop.
Inverse Pricing. Inverse pricing of water, as suggested by Miller and Cardon, may be entirely appropriate in the urban setting, but the economics of agriculture and the complexity of such a system make the concept difficult to apply to farmers. It would have to take into account such diverse factors as crop rotation, world food supply, and annual rainfall. Besides, one farmer's tailwater may be his neighbor's main supply. Soil Modification. Soil modification s a means toward increased irrigation efficiency also should be recognized as a developing tool. The emergence of laser-controlled leveling equipment has resulted n substantially improved water efficiency through precise modification of soil grading. Deep ripping of some soils has permitted better water use. In a relatively free-market economy, such as we like to think we have, economics is the guiding force. In the semiarid West, water availability and water costs may well be the axle upon which the farm's economy rotates or comes to a grinding halt. There is much that farmers can do for themselves, but the variables are so many (as are the farmers), that the best we can do is to record the changes as they happen and avoid being surprised. It is doubtful that we can predict the end results very well, or manipulate the process even if we predict accurately.
― 396 ―
Chapter 17— What Financial and Business Interests Can Do by A.L. Black
Abstract Opportunities for improved soil and water conservation, increased water and energy use efficiencies are dependent upon further advances in agricultural research. Without an adequate profit margin, farmers and ranchers cannot justify soil and water conservation. Financial institutions must be aware of current research, development, and demonstration in order to assist the farmer in financing. Consumers must be willing to support public funding for water conservation research and for water supply development. Farmer, banker, and businessman are interdependent upon each other; the general public is dependent upon the agricultural community. The public can greatly influence the viability of agriculture.
The estimated annual farm-gate value of crops produced and marketed from irrigated land in the 17 western states in recent years has been about $17 billion, ranging from $15 billion in 1978 to $19 billion in 1980. According to estimates for Texas, 54 percent of the value of irrigated production is used to pay for inputs and services purchased from the agricultural supply sectors.[1] Yields from irrigated crop production provide inputs as raw materials for the livestock, food processing, fiber processing, and export sectors of the economy. Although specific estimates are not available as to the increment of production throughout the 17 western states that is due to the application of irrigation water (i.e., that part of total yield above the value of yield which could be produced on the same land if it were farmed dryland), it would appear that at least 70 percent of the value of production on irrigated lands can be attributable to irrigation and irrigation-associated inputs. Thus, without irrigation, $12 billion of unprocessed agricultural produce would not be available to the livestock, agricultural processing, and agricultural trades sectors of
― 397 ― local, regional, state, national, and international economies. This amounts to 19 percent of the annual farm value of total national production of all crops. Thus, it should be clear that agricultural processing, trade, transportation, and input supply sectors, as well as consumers, have a significant stake in irrigated agriculture, and consequently should be concerned about maintaining agricultural viability in the face of declining water available for irrigation.
Research and Development[en2]Research and Development[2] Wide ranging opportunities for improved soil and water conservation, increased water and energy use efficiencies, and increased agricultural productivity are dependent upon further advances in agricultural research and technology development. A significant correlation exists between the level of investment in agricultural research and the gains in productivity and efficiency which exemplified U.S. agriculture until recent years. Reductions in federal funding for agricultural research and development have only partially been offset by increased state and private research investments. A renewed and continuing priority for agricultural research and development, with emphasis on more water-efficient crops, cultural methods, irrigation technologies, soil and water conservation and related advances, is needed if U.S. agricultural productivity is to meet projected future demands for food and fiber. Improved coordination and cooperation is needed among private and public
sources of research support. Private support for research through colleges, universities, and experiment stations should be increased and continued. The business community can contribute through the continued in-house development of agricultural tools, products, and technologies both on its own and in cooperation with public research programs. A significant research emphasis should be placed upon the development of more water-efficient varieties of principal crops and intensive investigation of new crops for adaptation to irrigated and dryland production conditions. As locally adapted plants with commercial potential are identified in the research phase, a market development strategy should be used to insure marketing success. In addition to increased research and development to improve water management efficiency, a need exists for more large-scale
― 398 ― and on-farm demonstrations of improved techniques and systems in order to accelerate their early and widespread adoption. Examples of conservation and resource use efficiency improvements that need to be emphasized are advances in water application methods and equipment, water-stress-tolerant crops and cropping systems, and conservation tillage practices. The private sector can assist in this effort by providing equipment, manpower, services, and publicity to conduct demonstrations. An effective information capability at the local level is necessary to translate agricultural research and development advances into widespread use on farms. In addition, the local dissemination of relevant management information such as weather conditions and forecasts, soil moisture, and moisture requirements of crops for irrigation scheduling is needed. Networks in use now in some parts of the Midwest (Nebraska for example) have proven to be effective in disseminating information needed for farm operation. More direct private and public participation in identifying resource management techniques with best potential for solving local problems will result in earlier acceptance and use of new methods, crops, and other research results. The private sector's news and information media should more adequately cover water conservation topics and explain the potential of new research. It's hard to compete with Hollywood, sensational war and murder stories, and sports, but the news media are letting the American people down in the half-hearted way water conservation, water development, and agricultural research are covered. Agricultural research and technology development do not need a change in
direction. However, a change in emphasis would be appropriate—toward greater yield per unit of input (water, fertilizer or energy), instead of maximum production volume. Continued funding by both private and public sectors is also essential. The job is not done.
Financing Continued agricultural productivity is dependent upon economically strong and stable farms and ranches which return reasonable rates on invested capital and give fair returns to labor and management. Recent economic indicators reveal a dangerous national trend toward narrow margins of agricultural returns over costs. Without an adequate profit margin, farmers and
― 399 ― ranchers cannot justify soil and water conservation. Financial incentives are necessary to facilitate the availability of investment capital and to encourage its use for purposes of soil, water, and energy conservation measures, and the long-term protection and maintenance of agricultural land and water.
Financial Institutions Many conservation methods and facilities have complex technical requirements, high costs, and high risks. Financial institutions can increase the availability of investment capital by ensuring that loan officers, personal service bankers, and other decision makers are informed of state-of-the-art conservation and efficiency technology. New attitudes toward risk and investment are needed. For example, a tailwater recovery system does not provide the same collateral security as a piece of farm machinery, but can serve as a valuable and profitable water conservation practice. The same requirements for state-of-the-art information are relevant for operational financing. A farmer may need to purchase more chemicals than usual in order to adopt a successful minimum tillage operation which may conserve both water and energy. Financial institutions must be aware of current research and development in order to assist the farmer in financing early adoption of effective soil and water conservation equipment, materials, and management technology.
Business Community Agricultural service and supply businesses can also cooperate with the farmer to accelerate adoption of operational improvements. These
businesses must stay informed about products, equipment, and methods which have the best potential for improving efficiency of resource use at the lowest costs. While businesses cannot be expected to invest in unproven technology, early and widespread adoption of proven products and methods is contingent, to some extent, upon availability. Financing practices such as deferred payments and minimal-interest charges are already available from some farm equipment dealers. These types of assistance need to be made available for new water conservation management tools as they become marketable. Businesses reap benefits when aiding the farmer, in the longer term. If the farmer doesn't have a dollar, no salesman is going to have a chance to get it.
― 400 ―
Consumers In a specialized economy, the food supply of the nation, and to some extent foreign markets, is somewhat contingent upon a dependable, long-term supply of water for irrigation. About 19 percent of crops produced and sold in the United States come from irrigated land. Without irrigation water this production would not occur, and the price of commodities would be much higher. Thus it behooves the general public as consumers to understand that irrigation water and water conservation are extremely important to their own interests. Consumers must be willing to support public funding for water conservation research and for water supply development. The public must understand more about agricultural water problems and more about the processes for solving them.
Conclusions The farmer, banker, and businessman are interdependent upon each other in an agricultural community. There should be greater communication among the groups in a cooperative long-range plan to maintain economic viability in the community. It is also apparent that the general public is dependent upon the agricultural community. Through communication with legislators and other elected officials, the public can greatly influence the viability of agriculture and the wise and efficient use of the nation's soil and water.
Discussion: Marvin Duncan (The views expressed herein are solely those of the author and do not necessarily represent the views of the Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City
or the Federal Reserve System.) Black has written a paper which effectively presents the viewpoint of farmers. While I find much in that viewpoint to agree with, I will also try to broaden the perspective to include more macro-level considerations. The perspective of the paper seems to be that because of the importance of farm production to the nation's food supply and to its economic activity, water should continue to be available for irrigation. In the first instance—the importance of irrigation water to the nation's food supply—it is increasingly difficult to convince consumers and policy makers that the nation's food supply is in any jeopardy as a result of marginal shifts of irrigated land out of crop production or into more extensive production. Nowhere is this more evident than in the production of food and feed grains, where carryover stocks are the largest since the early 1960s. With current policy emphasizing reductions in the acreages devoted to such crops in order to reduce the burdensome supply, the loss of water to irrigate such crops is primarily a micro-policy question relating to the economic well-being of the producers affected and the community infrastructure supporting them. Consumers have also become aware at times of excess supply problems among vegetable and fruit producers. Television news programs showing oranges being destroyed in an effort to support prices of frozen orange juice make indelible imprints on consumer audiences. To be mounted successfully, the food supply argument must be cast in terms of future decades. In that context, a case might be made for strategic irrigation investment, both public and private. In the second instance—the importance of food production to the nation's economy—the argument is a weak reed if the reference is to the efficiency of resource use in the national economy. Cash receipts from the sale of farm products average only about 5 percent of the final sale of goods and services in the United States each year. Indeed, the reallocation of water resources to higher value uses often enhance economic growth, at national, state, and local levels. This frequently means a partial shift of water resources away from agriculture to industrial and urban uses.
― 402 ― An institutional framework for reallocating water is, of course, necessary. A market system that compensates losers and charges gainers the value of use of the water moves the economy to higher levels of economic performance. If, however, the economic argument is directed toward a region, such as the Texas High Plains, it is on more solid ground. For without irrigation water,
that area may see less economic activity as its agriculture shifts to dryland crop production or reverts to pasture land. The adjustment from intensive agriculture with high land values and a large supporting community infrastructure to extensive agriculture under dryland conditions could be painful. But it is during the adjustment period that the trauma is experienced. Most economists and policy makers might agree that the transition could require some public investment and policy attention. It is less clear that the need for public investment in water transfer would be indicated. If such a transfer were proposed in the present environment, users would be expected to bear a significant, if not major, share of the cost. Where interbasin transfers of water might be involved, the problems facing water users would be particularly difficult. The cost of the transfer and the institutional barriers involved are likely to be insurmountable. Those giving up the water, moreover, would have to be compensated somehow. The battle over water sales from South Dakota's Oahe Reservoir for use in coal slurry transportation in Wyoming is, I think, only an initial indication of the economic and legal problems to be resolved. Black has emphasized the importance of agricultural research in improving the efficiency of water use and increasing agricultural production. This point is an important one. The benefits of previous investment in research have been great and are apparently cumulative, each new technological development building on previous developments. Similarly, it can be argued that reductions in public and private investment in agricultural research will, over time, have an increasingly deleterious impact on the competitive position of agriculture and on its profitability. The emphasis Black places on making more efficient use of water and on developing crops adapted to lower quality water or smaller quantities of it is also excellent. Finally, he correctly emphasizes the importance of public and private roles in technology transfer. The public-private partnership in support of agricultural research, development, and technology transfer has been highly productive. We would ignore that record at considerable
― 403 ― long-term risk to agriculture and to the American economy. Companion to this point is the need for continued investment in education. Education is the impetus for both research and technology transfer. Several relevant issues are not addressed in Black's paper. I will now turn to some of the more important of these. The economic and the financial environment in which agricultural production occurs has changed
significantly in recent years. As a result of the deregulation of financial institutions and innovations in financial markets, agricultural borrowers and lenders have been thrust rapidly and firmly into the broader U.S. financial market. Moreover, U.S. capital markets have become increasingly integrated into world capital markets. As a consequence, agriculture must now pay competitive rates for capital. In combination with national macro-economic policy and procedural changes, this new environment has resulted in more volatile and somewhat higher interest rates to farmers and to other borrowers. The Federal Reserve System's pursuit of a monetary policy directed toward restoring price stability combines with the likely prospect of very large federal budget deficits to suggest upward pressure on interest rates throughout the 1980s. In addition to the stubborn problem of cyclical deficits that had existed previously, recent taxing and spending policies by the federal government may have created a secular deficit problem of significant size. The competition for credit from all sources may be strong enough in this decade to cause real interest rates to remain at or above the top end of their historical range of 3 to 5 percent. This would be far higher than the near-zero real interest rates of the 1970s. Moreover, austere government budgets at all levels will likely result in federal government loan funds to individuals and government units being priced at or near the cost of money to the federal government. If these conditions prevail, public and private investment in agriculture and water development may differ from that of past decades when large longterm projects were undertaken. Public funding will be more scarce, and greater emphasis will be on private funding of projects or full payback of any public investment involved. All else equal, higher discount rates favor projects with short useful lives or those with payouts concentrated in the early years of operation. Projects with rapid payout are also more consistent with the lending activities by most private financial institutions.
― 404 ― A disparity between the market discount rate and a socially desirable discount rate designed to encourage long-term investment in water development projects—or other infrastructure investments—may prevail under the circumstances outlined. Such a disparity could present a problem for public resource development policy. Resolving the problem could involve increased public investment in such infrastructure at all levels of government. However, without such a change in public policy, it seems clear that private investment in water projects, as well as investment by state and local governments, will grow as a proportion of total project costs. At a micro-level, effective managers of borrowed capital can expect more access to agricultural loan funds in the future, partly because of the finance
industry changes outlined. Lenders are apt to be aggressive in serving the credit needs of farmers, but they expect their loans to be serviced in a predictable manner. Moreover, confidence in collateral lending has been shaken by recent declines in farmland values. Thus, greater emphasis will be placed on cash flow lending. For farmers, this likely means: 1) More attention to cash flow analysis in evaluating loan proposals; 2) More performance-oriented evaluation of loan customers; 3) More knowledgeable lenders with increased specialization in institutions and in staff; 4) A greater understanding of long-term trends in agriculture by lenders and farmers; and 5) A more knowledgeable, specialized, and innovative support sector for agriculture. On balance, farmers can look forward to ready access to credit from an increasingly efficient and sophisticated rural finance market.
Discussion: W.D. Farr Whatever expertise I have as a discussant of Blake's chapter comes from a practical knowledge of water and irrigation. I live in the State of Colorado where irrigated agriculture first developed. My experience comes from ownership of intensively
― 405 ― cropped irrigated farms, plus cattle ranches producing hay and pasture for beef production. Our subject is the impacts of limited water for agriculture in the semiarid West. This is not a new subject or a new problem; we westerners have faced it for a hundred years. Water for agriculture has always been limited by agriculture's ability to pay. Some areas in several states have had Bureau of Reclamation projects. These projects all had repayment contracts without interest, which was a small subsidy. However, the original farmer who signed the repayment contract had to develop raw land, build
improvements, and suffer through those pioneering years. These Bureau of Reclamation projects have developed large areas into high tax-producing segments of our western economy. The nonfederal water projects in the western states were built by mutual ditch and reservoir systems with blood, sweat, and tears and, because of a shortage of capital, always at a minimum. Eventually, if they were successful and if additional water was available, enlargements to the systems were made. Now, as we approach the year 2000, millions of people want to move west and enjoy the climate and living conditions. These additional millions of people have direct impact on our limited water. The impacts are many and varied and differ in each state and every river drainage. There is no uniform solution. One basic law of western water is "It must be put to beneficial use." The question finally gets down to "What is the most beneficial use?" In some areas, irrigated agriculture is not especially productive and has seldom been very financially rewarding. In that situation, the water should move to cities and industry because that is the most beneficial use. In many places the urbanization of large areas increases runoff substantially, which adds to the water supply for downstream agricultural users. This runoff water, plus the increased volume from city wastewater treatment plants, may add nearly as many irrigated acres downstream as was lost due to urbanization upstream. The climates of our western states vary dramatically. A few states have mild climates; others have fairly short growing seasons. Agriculture does not use water constantly the year around. Cities and industry need uniform supplies every day. With new and additional uses the whole water supply of any given river drainage must be restudied and developed to assure maximum
― 406 ― use. In areas where underground water from a rechargeable aquifer is part of the supply, then the studies and developments need to combine total available water supplies. Business and financial interests need to be very much involved in plans of this kind. Most of the water that has been developed in the western states was developed for agricultural use and hydro-power production. Now there are additional new needs for water. Most areas have some additional water that can be developed for the increased demands of industrial and urban use.
These projects usually have been considered as feasible but too expensive for agricultural use. This is an area where financial and business interests can use their influence and financial resources to see that these remaining water resources be built first before agricultural water is removed from the land for other purposes. Another area where business and financial interests can be extremely helpful is to insist that the water supplies of each area be better managed in order to assure the best usage of every acre-foot of water available each year. In my judgment, time and economic values will settle most agricultural problems. Farmers growing high priced fruit and vegetable crops on a year around basis can pay more for water than a farmer in Colorado growing corn silage for cattle feeding. Agriculture and irrigation helped build the West. Crops that filled the need of eastern consumers were produced. Large industries such as the beet sugar industry developed and prospered. Today it is a declining industry because food demands have changed, transportation costs have increased, and cane and fructose sugars are cheaper. Sugarbeets were a great irrigated crop, but are being forced out because of world food and money problems. Sugar is, however, just one example of the changes being forced on agriculture that actually have little to do with water. It is obvious that every country of the world and certainly each state in the United States is being forced to study what agricultural crops can be grown in their areas to yield the best financial return. Economic barriers will influence greatly the impact of limited water. In many areas and under differing conditions, people, cities, and industry may be the better use for limited water. Banks and other financial and business interests need to be well informed of the problems ahead, as well as committed to be part of the solution.
― 407 ― Water is finite in the West. Every community, county, and state will have to make their own judgments as to how their water supply is best divided and utilized. In some areas those decisions are already on the horizon. In other areas they are still one or two generations away. But in the planning and development or redevelopment of our water resources, that is not much time. We must face these challenges and proceed in implementing programs or projects that will be in the best total interests of the citizens of our respective states.
― 408 ―
Chapter 18— Water Rights and Market Transfers[*] by F. Lee Brown and Charles T. DuMars
Abstract Western water institutions are moving from a period of water development into an era of water management in which water reallocation, water conservation, and water quality enhancement will play increasingly greater roles relative to traditional development projects. Faced with new tasks to be performed, existing institutions are changing and new ones developing. Economic considerations are forging marketlike institutions, and the courts are expediting this evolutionary process by broadening the spectrum of persons who have a stake in water rights transfers and insisting on more efficient use of water. However, it is unlikely that society will accept an unbridled marketplace allocation of water; it will instead choose between increased regulation at the state level or increased ownership at the local level, with the former assigned the higher probability.
The Nature and Extent of Water Rights Transfers Although systematic data is sparse or nonexistent in most water basins in the West, there can be little doubt that the number and extent of water rights transfers away from irrigated agriculture has been increasing within the last ten to twenty years. In some cases the increase has been dramatic.[1] It is likely, though again the reported evidence is scanty, that the shift of [*] Research on this paper was supported in part by a grant from the Ford Foundation to the Center for Natural Resource Studies, Berkeley, California.
― 409 ― ownership is even more substantial than it appears, because many minerals or energy companies have formed subsidiaries which purchase water rights
but leave them in irrigation use until they are needed subsequently for mining or power production. In some basins water rights transactions have become so frequent that specialists have developed and rudimentary water markets can be said to exist.[2] The prices paid for water rights vary substantially from basin to basin and through time in a given basin, though generally they are higher in those basins in which water is relatively more scarce compared to the competing demands for its use. In basins with little growth, or in which unappropriated water still remains, prices may be as low as $50-$100 per right to a consumptive acre-foot; while in highly developed and growing basins prices in excess of $10,000 per right to a consumptive acre-foot have been reported.[3] The recent agreement between Energy Transportation Systems, Inc. (ETSI) and the state of South Dakota appears to be substantially in excess of this $10,000 figure, though the details of the agreement are somewhat clouded.[4] The explanation for the increasing number of transfers is not difficult to discern, and rests on the conjunction of several factors. First, virtually all basins in the West have reached, or are nearing, full appropriation, in which it is no longer legally possible to obtain new water by sinking a well or diverting a streamflow. Yet new water uses continue to arise, spurred particularly by the continuing migration to the West and Southwest and the growth in energy and industrial development. Because historically irrigated agriculture has been the dominant consumer of water in the region, it is the most obvious source for transfers. Finally, when the considerably greater ability to pay[5] for water on the part of energy companies, mining companies, and municipalities confronts willing sellers in farmers, whose water rights have become their most valuable asset, the conclusion to sell and transfer becomes clear.
Future Prospects In keeping with this explanation, future prospects for a further expansion, leveling off, or contraction in the extent of transfers depends on a variety of factors. These include the growth in demand by new water users, the availability of alternatives to transfers in meeting the new demands, the relative value of water in agricultural uses when compared to its value in other uses, and the degree to which the institutions governing water allocation and use allow transfers to occur.
― 410 ― Because other chapters in this volume concentrate more heavily on many of these factors, they will not be examined in any depth here. Suffice it to say that most projections of new demands, particularly by energy, have been
high. Short of a new oil embargo or other disruption, the growth in new uses will probably be less dramatic than some have predicted, though as long as westward migration continues, new uses will steadily arise. This chapter focuses, instead, on the institutional structures which govern water in the West and even more specifically on the role of the marketplace and the courts in facilitating or retarding water rights transfer and water reallocation.
The Water Management Era For most of this century and part of the last, the dominant force infusing water affairs in the West was the drive to "make the desert bloom" by developing and applying the native water resources of the region to productive use, most notably in irrigated agriculture.[6] The region's water institutions were largely formed and matured simultaneously with the development of the water itself. Yet with the nearing of full appropriation this development phase is ending and being replaced by an era of water management, in which other management techniques such as conservation, reallocation, and water quality enhancement are increasingly important. Chapter 2 describes in some detail the advent of this management era. Fundamentally, the advent of a new era requires answers to questions which the region's water institutions have not had to answer heretofore. As long as there was unappropriated water, the basic question was, "Is a given use beneficial and under what condition?" Now that there is more than one potential user for each portion of water, the question has become, "Which use is more beneficial and under what condition?" The modern questions are much more complex, particularly for a collection of water institutions to which the questions are unlike anything that has been asked in a hundred or so years of practice. It is little wonder that legislatures, governors, and presidents are having to deal directly with the problems; the water bureaucracies themselves are not suited to make the decisions. Moreover, the decisions will not be easy even in the highest councils. In the next section we examine the capacity and limitations of one type of institution— the marketplace—in performing the water management function.
― 411 ―
The Role of the Marketplace The Management Function of Institutions Peter Drucker has described an institution as "an organ of society, existing to make specific contributions and to discharge specific social functions."[7] Although Drucker uses the term "institution" in a slightly more restricted sense than the authors, the essence of his statement is the same.
Institutions exist to perform specific social functions. Management, in turn, describes the activity of these institutions in matching the subject raw material—whether water, highways or otherwise—to the goals or objectives of the society being served. These descriptions suggest two conditions necessary to any examination of water management institutions. First, there must be some notion of the social objectives, and thereby the underlying social values, of the society to be served by the institutions. Second, there should be consideration of the alternative institutional "technologies" that are available for performing the management function. Both of these subjects are highly complex, and an exhaustive examination of either is beyond the scope of this chapter. However, some consideration must be given to certain aspects of both subjects in order to adequately assess the role of the marketplace in managing western water.
Social Goals Maass and Anderson[8] have identified six common goals of irrigation communities that they studied in both Spain and the United States. These are (1) orderly conflict resolution, (2) popular participation, (3) local control, (4) increased income, (5) justice in income distribution, and (6) equity or fairness. This exact list need not be considered all-inclusive of social objectives for water, or constant throughout all water management situations, in order to illustrate two propositions that will be the basis for the institutional analysis that follows.
Proposition 1 Some degree of material (economic) improvement is an important social value to all societies, and the allocational institutions for all scarce resources, including water, must fulfill that objective to a degree determined by each society.
― 412 ―
Proposition 2 There are values other than total material improvement that are as important, and usually more important, to all societies. Accordingly, allocational institutions must also conform to these values. The Maass and Anderson analysis provides support for these propositions. Whatever disagreement might arise about the second proposition would likely relate to the relative importance attached to material improvement and potentially competing values. And it is precisely this relative ranking that is critical to the role that market institutions can play in managing the
allocation of water. How does material improvement compare with other social goals, particularly with regard to water? Consider the following quote from the Maass and Anderson study. . . . farmers typically refuse to treat water as a regular economic good, like fertilizer, for example. It is, they say, a special product and should be removed from ordinary market transactions so that farmers can control conflict, maintain popular influence and control, and realize equity and social justice.[9] The thrust of their assessment of a number of irrigation communities in two countries appears to support proposition two, though not without qualification. It might be argued, however, that such tempering of material goals is confined to irrigation communities and in the larger context of allocating water over all uses, material improvement is less likely to be constrained by competing goals. Certainly this alternative hypothesis is arguable, and ultimately the relative descriptive power of proposition two or its alternatives is an empirical question, which may be answered differently in different social and physical environments for water. However, having briefly considered the possibility of alternatives to proposition two, the subsequent analysis will nevertheless use it as a second postulate. This short discussion of the societal goals for water may be summarized in the following way. Most societies are ambivalent about water. On the one hand they wish to treat it as a commodity in commerce, and accordingly desire that it move to its highest valued use, thereby maximizing, or tending to maximize, the material well-being of the society served by a given physical supply of water. On the other hand, most of these same societies are concerned about meeting a number of other social goals with respect to water allocation which may, in fact, temper the
― 413 ― material gain that would otherwise be possible if water were treated exclusively as a commodity. For some societies, such as various Indian tribes, water appears to have even a religious significance. Kenneth Boulding, an economist, has described water as "the object of a very complex structure of evaluations, rituals, superstitions, and attitudes. It has been the subject of sacred observances from very early times in human history."[10] For these reasons, socially acceptable institutional arrangements for water management must innovatively combine procedures which support the movement of water toward its highest material usage, while at the same time providing ample means for ensuring that social goals other than material enhancement can also be met.
Market Technologies for Water Management There are a large number of ways that organizations, rules, procedures, customs, and other forms of institutions can be arranged to perform the management tasks of meeting social objectives for water. At polar extremes, both pure laissez faire and pure centralized planning institutional technologies can be conceptualized, though neither would prove socially acceptable on one count or another. The discussion here, however, will be restricted to market-type institutional technologies and their serviceability in meeting the social goals as described by the two propositions given above. There is obviously an immense literature on the general functioning of markets, which does not need to be recounted here. Suffice it to say that under strict conditions and according to definite criteria of well-being, markets perform well in moving a given resource to uses that will produce the greatest amount of the most desired material products. Moreover, when judged against a number of social goals, markets may measure up well also. In their perfectly competitive form they can provide a vehicle for popular participation, can be localized to individual communities and provide a means of orderly conflict resolution as to who gets what when. They may be less serviceable with respect to justice in income distribution or in achieving equity or fairness. They are not inherently incompatible with the latter two goals, but there is no reason to expect that they will necessarily produce allocational outcomes that conform to a society's criteria relative to these two goals. In short summary, markets offer attractive institutional technologies for meeting the material goal described in proposition one, and are not necessarily inconsistent with other social goals
― 414 ― as set forth in proposition two, though they are limited in their ability to fulfill the full set of goals that may be desired by a society. Moreover, attention must be paid in any specific allocational situation to whether the conditions required for markets to perform well their material functions are actually met. Consideration will first be given to the general limitation on the efficacy of markets in meeting the full set of social goals. Then specific problems in the water arena will be examined more closely.
General Limitations on the Efficacy of Markets As a general statement, there is no compelling reason to expect that water markets will succeed in meeting a community's social goals other than the objective of material improvement as discussed above. Of even greater
concern, however, are significant possibilities that unrestrained markets may actually prevent the attainment of the other social goals that may have been set. Consider again for illustrative purposes the set of goals described by Maass and Anderson, and imagine a water context in which the principal water use in a particular subbasin A has been irrigated agriculture. Now suppose that a large water-using enterprise in an adjacent subbasin B purchases the water rights from individual farmers in A and transfers the water to B. The transaction presumably has been concluded on a voluntary basis, and there is at least a good possibility that the material well-being of the individual farmers in A has been enhanced, else why would they have sold their rights. However, what has become of the other social goals to which the entire community in A originally subscribed? No longer is there local control over water nor popular participation in the allocative decisions about water. In fact, if the water rights were held by individuals, there need not have been any local, popular participation in the basic transfer transaction at all. As for the other goals, there is no assurance that "justice" in the distribution of income will have been achieved. In fact, if there were no compensation to the nonright-holding public, then it is possible that there may have been a significant deterioration in the distribution of material well-being of the community. Conflict resolution may no longer be a problem, since there may be little or no reason for water conflicts to arise if most of the water has departed. On the other hand, what water remains may be the focal point for even greater conflicts. Finally, equity or fairness is a kind of blanket goal—if negative consequences have occurred with respect to the other
― 415 ― goals, then it is unlikely that the resulting situation would be considered equitable. Market forces, then, however valuable they may be in moving a resource such as water to its highest material location and use, may have substantial adverse consequences for other social goals of communities. At least two reasons underlie this potentially adverse performance of markets. First, the fundamental assumption underlying the theory of markets is maximization of self-interest. While self-interest must be recognized as a strong force in human affairs and even on moral grounds its free expression should be countenanced, unrestrained self-interest as reflected in the fundamental descriptive assumption of neoclassical economics is generally not acceptable to most societies. Instead, again quoting Kenneth Boulding: A very important question in social policy, which certainly applies to water policy as much as it does to any other, is whether the distributional impacts from the price structures that are desirable from the point of view of allocation can be modified sufficiently to make them politically acceptable without destroying the necessary
motivation for allocation change. (Emphasis added)[11] In short, society seeks institutional means for achieving its goals which generally involve some constraint on material self-aggrandizement. Second, markets function by means of a dollar metric. That is to say, whatever is sold to the highest bidder has been measured in the exchange process by a common currency agreed to by both buyer and seller. For most tangible commodities and even services, this valuation process may work well because the characteristics of the item subject to exchange are readily quantifiable and valued in dollar terms. However, for some items and some transactions, a dollar measure is inherently inapplicable. Generally these items possess deep emotional value for individuals, and are considered "beyond measure," meaning dollar measure. These cannot be allocated by the market, for it is simply impossible to transfer emotions in exchange for dollars. Ultimately the "fabric" which holds communities together and produces constructive collective action is comprised of the emotions that are felt by and actuate the individuals within the community. For all of its power in performing the material allocation function, markets do not provide the cohesive emotions necessary to meet these other social goals. Again, however, it should be stressed that markets are not necessarily at odds with
― 416 ― those goals. The task is to find successful ways to integrate markets and their capabilities with broader social needs.
Specific Features of Western Water Institutions Several specific features of western water institutions bear upon the suitability of market mechanisms for reallocating water.
The Problem of Imperfect Competition Markets most satisfactorily perform their allocational function when there exists what is termed "perfect competition." There is evidence that the budding water markets of the West are developing significant deviations from this perfectly competitive condition. Although current data is fragmentary, circumstantial evidence indicates that imperfectly competitive conditions—specifically bilateral monopolies—may be developing in some basins of the West. A bilateral monopoly exists when there are only one buyer and one seller. Although bilateral monopolies do not of necessity
produce economically inefficient allocations, such outcomes are more likely due to the absence of sufficient competitive forces in the marketplace. The existence of bilaterial monopolies or oligopolies further suggests that the community goals of local control and popular participation may be completely ignored by the two parties to the water market transaction.
The Return Flow and Capital Preservation Problem Surface and groundwater in the West are almost always interconnected. As a result, the water diversion works or pump facility of a particular appropriator may rely extensively on the use pattern of his neighbors. For example, appropriator B may have positioned his well and established its depth so that he effectively relies on percolation of water into subsurface aquifers from the irrigated fields on his neighbor A's property, or even more likely, from a sink at the edge of his neighbor's field where surplus irrigation water percolates downward. In this example, a change in use by party A, or a transfer of A's water right to a new location, may substantially affect the quantity of water readily available to B. A shallow well that was at a sufficient depth given the groundwater recharge produced by A may no longer reach the water table in the absence of A's existing pattern of use. The occurrence of these hydrological interconnections among users is the basis for the nonimpairment provisions of western water law. In most jurisdictions, transfers of rights are not
― 417 ― allowed if there is an impairment of another's water right. In certain states, however, compensation may be paid to the other rightholders who would be affected when the transfer was completed. The complexity of these hydrological interdependencies—the so-called "return flow problem"—has led some economists and others to question the ability of water markets to produce an economically efficient outcome. It is indeed possible, maybe probable, that a single organization is better suited for the management of water at the basin level than are markets with their numerous autonomous, but hydrologically interdependent, parties. However, there has been some misconception regarding the nature of the return flow problem which, when clarified, puts the problem in a different light. If a water right is a legal entitlement to a consumptive use of water, then the protection provided by nonimpairment statutes or rules is actually for the capital investment of the individual rightholders in coffer dams, pumps, sprinkler equipment, or other water acquisition, transport, and application facilities, rather than for access to the water itself. Two implications of this reformulation are important. If a given water user's capital investment is protected against a change in a
neighbor's use or transfer of that use, then the status quo in existing water use practices is favored over the need to adopt more water-conserving technologies as water becomes more valuable. Secondly, the legal protection given to the capital investment of other rightholders by nonimpairment provisions does not extend to the capital investments of other entrepreneurs whose livelihoods may be equally dependent on maintenance of the existing pattern of water use. For example, farm implement and seed dealers' economic welfare may be predicated on a continuation of existing agricultural uses of water, yet their investments are not protected against damage through transfers of water rights away from these uses. In essence, society has established institutional rules that may provide too much protection for an inefficient water use practice, while not protecting other capital investments related to water at all. These rules were put in place during the water development era. The prospects for expansion or contraction of these doctrines by the courts is discussed below. Each of the above water market characteristics will likely have a significant bearing upon the ultimate social acceptability of market-type institutions for reallocating water in the West. As
― 418 ― new demands for water develop in the West and water becomes relatively more scarce, there will be increasing demands for institutional changes which enable the true opportunity cost of water to be more accurately reflected in the price of water and therefore more effectively impact on all water users. The thrust of this conclusion is toward marketlike structures which more openly provide measures of the opportunity cost associated with given water uses. However, it is unlikely that society will allow an unrestricted market allocation of water, but will instead evolve some mechanism for tempering its outcome. The successful weaving of these two threads into a functional set of water management institutions will not be easy. In the next section we demonstrate how the courts have begun to recognize the need for protection of these varied political and economic interests.
The Role of Courts in Implementation of Institutional Changes The Historical Role of Courts as Social and Economic Decision Makers Courts at all levels of society, while purporting to "find" the law in the
written word, have of necessity built their legal results based upon perceived views of economics and politics. The role of the Supreme Court in fostering a free interstate market is stated most elaborately by Justice Jackson: While the Constitution vests in Congress the power to regulate commerce among the states, it does not say what the states may or may not do in the absence of congressional action. [Perhaps] even more than by interpretation of its written word, this Court has advanced the solidarity and prosperity of this nation by the meaning it has given to these great silences of the Constitution. . . . Every consumer may look to the full competition from every producing area in this nation to protect him from exploitation by any. Such was the vision of the founders; such has been the doctrine of this Court which has given it reality . . . (Emphasis added)[12] The notion that court-made judicial doctrine is based on promotion of certain economic principles such as the obligation of the state to protect investment of private capital has been followed with equal force in the area of water law.[13] In its early origins court-made water law doctrine had as its main focus the promotion of the interests of the earliest appropriators and the
― 419 ― protection of their capital investments. As the kinds of conflicting demands for water have increased, a number of changes in water law doctrine have come about—all of which have an effect on the potential supply of water for agriculture and the capacity to transfer water out of agriculture.
Changes in the Law Relating to the Necessity of Diversions Traditionally, to acquire a water right in the western states a diversion of the water has been necessary.[14] This principle was grounded in the notion that investors in water rights should have to invest some capital. In addition, actual diversions from the stream put people on notice of the existence of diversionary rights already in place. This requirement of a diversion eliminated a number of potential competitors for water who sought water for environmental purposes in the form of "in-stream" flow rights. The diversionary obligation was thought to be embedded in the constitutional provisions of most western states. However, in State of Idaho Department of Parks v. Idaho Department of Water Administration,[15] the Idaho Supreme Court followed the state legislature's lead in perceiving a need for water rights for in-stream flows without a physical diversion. There the Idaho constitution expressly stated: "[the] right to divert and appropriate the unappropriated waters of any natural stream to beneficial use shall never be denied." Notwithstanding this language, the court, in upholding a statutory water right for in-stream flows, concluded: "Our constitution does not
require actual physical diversion."[16] Thus, this opinion adds to the market another potential buyer for agricultural water rights.
New Limitations on the Right to Demand Water Otherwise Lost Traditionally, the prior appropriator had the right to make a "call on the river" for his water right even though this caused extensive evaporative losses. This is best exemplified by the Nebraska Supreme Court case of State ex. rel. Carry v. Cochran.[17] There, a prior right holder was seeking to enforce his right to delivery of water on the North Platte River. To deliver the river water to him involved extensive carriage loss. Notwithstanding, the water was ordered delivered. There has been state legislative reaction to this type of doctrine.[18] More recent cases have upheld replacement plans which protect senior rights by substituting groundwater and thereby reducing carriage loss.[19] This move toward maximum utilization by allowing substitution of groundwater may well satisfy the
― 420 ― need of the far downstream surface water user, but it may not meet the needs of others. For example, junior appropriators may have relied on the senior's call on the river to keep the river bed wet so that their water could be delivered with minimum seepage. Also, water that has seeped into the ground is not necessarily "lost." The senior's surface "loss" may, in fact, be the source of water for junior wells upstream.
The Introduction of Benefit-Cost Analysis The traditional method for acquisition of a water right involved only the question of whether there was a diversion of the water and application of it to a beneficial use.[20] Jurisdictions are changing. These changes have shown up with a movement toward economic and political balancing when a new appropriation is sought. The state of Washington is particularly explicit: Allocation of waters among potential uses and users shall be based generally on securing the maximum net benefits for the people of the state. Maximum net benefits shall constitute total benefits less costs, including opportunities lost.[21] A narrow material interpretation of this provision would ignore the myriad of social and nonquantifiable values attributable to water being used in agriculture. Also, it may provide a basis for reducing the protection of
minimal and inefficient capital investments by persons with early priority dates.
Evolving Conflicts with Federal Statutes and Their Implications Because much of the federal legislation affecting water rights was drafted in the early 1900s, these federal laws of necessity incorporated much of the water law of the time. They have not been amended. Thus, for example, the Reclamation Act of 1902 contains a requirement that all water in such projects be considered appurtenant to specific parcels of land.[22] This kind of federal legislation limited its transferability to other uses.[23] Notwithstanding the express language of these acts, the United States Supreme Court in recent decisions has leaned strongly toward an interpretation sensitive to the needs of changing state water laws. As stated most recently in California v. United States: The history of the relationship between the federal government and the states in the reclamation of the arid lands of the western states is both long and involved, but through it runs the consistent thread of purposeful and continued deference to state water law by Congress.[24]
― 421 ― This federal policy is also reflected in the language of Section 101(g) of the federal Water Pollution Control Act: "It is the policy of Congress that the authority of each state to allocate quantities of water within its jurisdiction shall not be superseded . . . " Finally, the reserved water rights of the federal government for enclaves such as national forests, while once thought to be expansive, have been held by the Supreme Court to be much more limited.[25] And, while some have argued that the reserved water rights of Indian reservations are not transferable[26] and can be used only for irrigation, the Supreme Court has held they can be used for other purposes,[27] and others argue they are transferable.[28] The outcome of this transferability issue may have great impact on agricultural uses. If, for example, Indian water rights are transferable, then they will provide substantial competition to the non-Indian seller of an agricultural water right. This is true because the priority dates of the reservations will generally antedate those of the non-Indian agricultural water users.
New Obligations to Improve the Method of Diversion and to Prevent Waste The general rule with respect to the need for efficiency in the means of diversion, and the irrigator's obligation to change his means of diversion to a more efficient one, was succinctly stated in an early Montana case: "When ditches and flumes are the usual and ordinary means of diverting water, parties who have made their appropriations by such means cannot be compelled to substitute iron pipes . . ."[29] That the law is also changing in this area is reflected in the landmark case of A and B Cattle Co. v. United States.[30] In a recent equitable apportionment case between New Mexico and Colorado, the special master demonstrated once more the concern for efficiency in evaluating senior agricultural water rights. He discredited the loss of water to a conservancy district in New Mexico and ruled in favor of industrial use in Colorado because of his view as to the "inefficiency" of the district.[31] Thus, the movement toward cost-benefit analysis on the issue of obligation to improve efficiency seems clear.
Protection of Groundwater Diversion Methods While a few jurisdictions have given no protection to groundwater rights[32] and groundwater was considered something of a mystery in the early 1900s, recent decisions have struggled with two basic questions: (1) how much protection should be given to
― 422 ― a well user who suddenly finds his well weakened or dried up by a new well owner, and (2) in aquifers that are being mined, how does a water administrator determine a proper rate of mining? While some early decisions afforded strict protection of a prior appropriator's well right irrespective of diversion method, a leading California case established the rule that the method of diversion must be reasonable.[33] In Colorado Springs v. Bender[34] the court clearly laid out the issue. It held that: The plaintiff cannot reasonably "command the whole" source of supply merely to facilitate the taking of a fraction of the entire flow to which the senior right entitles them. On the other hand, plaintiffs cannot be required to improve their extraction facilities beyond their economic reach.[35]
The court went on to conclude that if a senior well system fails because of the junior's activities, the junior should compensate the senior for the cost of substituting a new means of diversion. The issue of what is a reasonable means of diversion is becoming much more relevant, as jurisdictions become increasingly more aware of the hydrological connection between ground and surface water. Indeed, one New Mexico case suggests that if groundwater pumping reduces one's surface water diversion, the failure to seek a groundwater well permit may constitute forfeiture.[36] As to the issue of what is a reasonable rate of drawdown of a mined aquifer, the courts are having an understandable amount of difficulty. They must balance the interests of future resident domestic users of the area, present agricultural appropriators with existing capital investments, and future industrial appropriators. Courts have been mindful of the need for such a concept;[37] unfortunately it is still in its infancy. As a result, attempts at definition often result in tautologies: "The safe yield of a groundwater basin is the amount of water which can be withdrawn from it annually without producing an undesired result."[38] This problem of determining a "safe" rate of drawdown is complicated further as courts begin to give more protection from saline pollution due to aquifer withdrawals.[39] The agricultural water user who seeks to transfer a senior well right has to be concerned with these issues. If the salinity of a mined aquifer is steadily increasing, transfer to a potential agricultural buyer is extremely unlikely, because while the potential agricultural buyer may have access to a substantial quantity of water under the right, if it is of poor quality it has no value to him.
― 423 ― The "safe yield" formula also has a direct bearing on the market for agricultural water rights. An agricultural well water right only has value if there are a fixed number of wells that can be drilled in the basin. If an industrial user can drill his new well without impairing the administratively determined "safe yield," he will have no motivation to purchase an existing right.
The Potential for Unlimited Interstate Competition Many states have devised water plans and have emerging water markets based upon state statutes, which make appropriation for use out-of-state illegal.[40] The United States Supreme Court has decided that the limitation in Nebraska cannot withstand the constitutional challenges under the Commerce Clause. The United States Supreme Court in Sporhase et al. v.
Nebraska ex rel. Douglas, Attorney General, No. 81-613 (July 2, 1982), ruled that Nebraska cannot constitutionally embargo its groundwater solely for purposes of economic protectionism. In so holding, however, it left open the issue insofar as arid states are concerned: "A demonstrably arid state conceivably might be able to marshall evidence to establish a close meansend relationship between even a total ban on the exportation of water and a purpose to conserve and preserve water."[41] Hence this decision leaves a number of relevant policy questions unanswered. What is clear from the above discussion is that the courts are becoming increasingly aware of the existence of the economic variables in water law decision making; that the law is slowly changing to promote maximum utilization of water along with protection of vested rights; and that this change seems to be reasonably orderly. In the more difficult areas of protection of groundwater means of diversion, ensuring aquifer "safe yield," and the possible creation of interstate water markets, the directions and outcomes are much less clear.
Summary and Conclusions The Current Direction of Change With the advent of full appropriation in the face of continually increasing demands for water, the region's water institutions are beginning to change. In large measure it is the energy sector that is serving as a major force for this change, both directly as a major user of water in energy production and indirectly as the reason for much of the population growth that the West is experiencing. Moreover, there can be little doubt that the energy
― 424 ― industry can afford to pay the often large costs required to bring about change in the previously accepted rules governing water use. Water costs are such a small portion of the total capital investment necessary to produce usable energy from natural resources that energy firms are easily able to bid water rights away from less economically valuable uses such as irrigated agriculture. Given these large discrepancies between the economic value of water in agriculture and its value in energy, firms can not only afford to compensate existing right-holders for their rights, but they can also afford large expenditures to litigate, legislate, or lobby for whatever institutional change they desire. Associated with the increasing frequency of transfers of water rights from agriculture to energy and municipal uses, markets for these rights have begun to develop in the various basins of the West. Rudimentary as these
water markets generally are when compared to smoothly functioning markets for many other commodities, they nevertheless exist and serve to establish prices for water rights. Accompanying this evolution of markets for water rights, however, are several related developments which may not prove as socially acceptable. First, there is fragmentary evidence that conditions of imperfect competition are developing in some basins. Second, as water rights are moved away from irrigated agriculture through market transactions or by other means, the asset base for the rural communities that irrigated agriculture has heretofore served is diminished. While singleminded pursuit of material goals might dictate that such communities should simply contract if they no longer are economically sustainable, other social goals, discussed in connection with proposition two previously, may require that these communities at least be given the opportunity to find and develop a sustainable economic base. The distributional consequences of the loss of water rights to rural economies may be quite severe. A third probable consequence of the increasing dominance of economic factors in reallocating water is further exacerbation of the unsettled ownership question for water rights, particularly those disputes involving Indian tribes. As water becomes economically more valuable, the conflict over ownership will become more and more heated, with less and less flexibility on both sides in finding solutions. The courts are beginning to acknowledge these new demands on agricultural water rights and are handing down decisions that reflect a broad range of interests in water use and incorporate the notion of maximum utilization into western water law.
― 425 ―
Alternate Paths If the conclusions reached in the previous section are correct, while markets will continue to develop, it is unlikely that society will allow continued, unrestricted evolution of market reallocations; rather it will instead seek to temper the market outcome. If this assessment is accurate, two courses seem available. The first, and most probable, is that the regulatory structure imposed by states upon water affairs will be strengthened and extended. For example, the public interest provisions in water statutes will continue to be reinterpreted to include the welfare of other parties in addition to other rightholders. These modifications could include changes in statutes and rules that would provide incentives for existing private water users to find and adopt water-conserving innovations. This enhanced regulatory approach is the most likely course since it involves the least departure from the current course of events and basically only involves an expansion in the authority of existing institutions. It does not involve public acquisition and ownership. For societies accustomed to a large degree of individual freedom, some degree of increased collective regulation may be all that is tolerable.
The major alternative to this path is a more active assertion of collective interest by local governmental entities. For example, local communities at the basin or subbasin level could create a publicly owned corporation which acquires through purchase or condemnation most or all of the water rights in the hydrological area. This corporation would then allocate water among different users under some sort of water leasing procedure. Under a water leasing scheme, an allocation based exclusively on economic criteria could first be proposed, using markets as the allocational instrument. However, if the market-directed allocation was substantially at variance with other social goals for the community encompassed by the water corporation, then a political mechanism would exist for bringing the actual allocation into conformity with the full set of goals. This alternative institutional path would involve substantial change in existing institutions and for that reason must be judged as less probable. Still, it has attractive features and could evolve from the subbasin upwards, rather than being imposed by some central authority. The choice between alternative institutional paths will be important, and perhaps critical, to the future of irrigated agriculture in many parts of the West. When judged on strict economic criteria, some agricultural activity is unlikely to be able to
― 426 ― compete, and the continuing pressures are for institutional change in the direction of greater economic competition. The degree to which material goals are successfully integrated with nonmaterial values will vary with different societies and cultures in the West. In all cases, however, the forging of new institutions is almost certain to be a difficult task.
Discussion: Raymond L. Anderson Brown and DuMars comprehensively outline the major issues involved in transferring water from irrigated agriculture. They touch on the vexing problems of meeting water needs of a growing West with the increasing complex restraints placed on water supplies by various interest groups. In the abstract they say that economic considerations are forging water markets and that the courts are expediting the process by broadening the base of those who have a stake in water transfers and by insisting on more efficient water use. They assert that society is unlikely to accept an unbridled marketplace allocation of water resources. Because water rights are highly localized and site-specific, it is more
― 428 ― likely that each state will develop its own mechanisms for allowing water transfers. In Colorado, we have been looking at water transfers for over twenty years. One of the smoothest running water markets in the West has been in the Northern Colorado Water Conservancy District (NCWCD) for Colorado-Big Thompson (C-BT) water. C-BT is supplemental water developed by a Bureau of Reclamation project. When the project was started during the 1930s depression, the original allotment holders wanted an escape hatch in case payment for the supplemental water became a burden and threatened foreclosure of the farm for nonpayment of water assessments. Farmers wanted the right to sell the water or give it away if the water didn't pay its costs. This little gimmick paved the way for a source of water that could be purchased by rural-domestic systems, cities, and industries as growth came to the Front Range during the 1960s and 1970s. Within the NCWCD, the original allocation gave 14.5 percent of the water to nonirrigation users. By 1982, over 35 percent was owned by nonirrigators. This amounts to about 63,000 acre-feet of water. The price has risen from zero or $30 per unit to as high as $2,000. Because the rules allow only one use of the water, irrigated agriculture has not suffered as much as one might suppose. Return flows are available to agriculture. Up until the present, water transfer from agriculture, at least in Colorado, has always been the least preferred way to obtain water. When the need arises to find ways of obtaining water supply for newly developing uses, most new users prefer to develop additional water supplies, if such possibilities exist. They prefer to build reservoirs to capture unused flows. Denver, for instance, has long pursued a policy of developing water on the West Slope rather than competing for water from existing agricultural users on the South Platte. Some of the newly developing suburbs around Denver have chosen to invade agricultural water supplies through condemnation proceedings, but have discovered in the process that there are many pitfalls in taking currently employed water. Where cities overgrow irrigated lands, the transfer to urban uses is normally accepted and is accomplished with a minimum of controversy. It is the removal of water supply from existing irrigated agriculture that creates transfer problems. In certain instances, where new users (cities or industries) offer high prices for irrigation stock, they can induce some stockholders to sell water to them. As long as the proportion of water held by cities and industries does not place too large a drain on
― 429 ― an irrigation company's water supply, irrigators are willing to let nonfarmers own some of the irrigation system's water. In northern Colorado, the cities and industries buy water long before they intend to use it, so that much of the water is rented back to the farmers for some years. When the outside owners take large amounts of water out of the irrigation systems, this will undoubtedly lead to severe problems. So far, the bulk of the irrigation water taken for new users has come from formerly irrigated lands that have been converted to urban uses. The cities tend to grow best on irrigated lands in Colorado. We've done a preliminary survey of irrigation company stock ownership on four major streams north of Denver, and it appears that the bulk of irrigation water stock transferred was from land that had gone into urban development. Brown and DuMars refer to social goals that are held by irrigation communities with regard to the use of irrigation water. These six goals of irrigation communities are taken from the book authored by Professor Arthur Maass and myself, . . . and the Desert Shall Rejoice.[1] In our discussion, we were concerned mainly with how these goals related to the internal operation of irrigation companies or districts. In this case, the arena is sharply delineated. The goals apply mainly within the confines of a physical system, the service area of the company. The irrigation organization has good control of the critical resource and can distribute it according to rules that have the common consent of the interested people—the stockholderswater users. Once water moves into the larger economic and social sphere beyond the individual canal system, as described by Brown and DuMars, control by the local water users becomes much weaker. The community may retain these goals, but there is little they can do to achieve them once water has slipped beyond their grasp. The Milagro Beanfield War[2] is a case in point. In the case of northeastern Colorado, perhaps it is the larger geographic area covered by the NCWCD that makes the market for C-BT water successful. While an individual irrigation company loses control of C-BT water when it is sold out of a system, the water cannot pass beyond the boundary of the NCWCD, so that the Conservancy District, representing a larger community, maintains control of future use of all of its water. Thus the NCWCD can be concerned about the effect of transfer on the various goals of an irrigation community, whereas a small company would have no control over water use once it passes out of its canal system. It seems to be a matter of geographic scope
― 430 ― whether community goals will affect water use after sale and transfer.
At the end of their chapter, Brown and DuMars envision a dramatic change in institutions in which a water basin authority gains control of all water in a basin and allocates said water in a two-step process. The first step is an auction to see who will pay the most for water, followed by a second step where the directors of the water authority examine the auction bids to see if the uses square with community values. For those uses or portion of uses that do not meet community values, water stocks would be restricted and sent to community approved uses. This, as they admit, is rather improbable. A more probable course will be for the existing institutions governing water use and ownership to gradually loosen and evolve to provide for new uses. That is the traditional way institutions react. Institutions are made by people to serve people, and institutional rules are not set in concrete to be observed for all time. But institutions also have the very important characteristic of being stable, to provide a basis for secure expectations so that economic and other decisions can be made with some degree of assurance that the rules will not change precipitously. Therefore, I am not terribly pessimistic about current water institutions being able to handle the job. A pragmatic view of past performance of water institutions shows an accommodation to changing needs, and there is no reason to suppose those administering the water institutions or the courts settling legal contests over water will suddenly be unable to cope with change. The change will be slow, torturous, and expensive. This view, of course, will not be greeted with enthusiasm by certain groups pushing special interest programs such as Indian water rights, federally reserved water rights, or in-stream flow rights for various purposes. These advocates are anxious to push through their claims and are impatient with the slow change of institutions. But slow change is necessary to fully examine the impact of many of these proposed claims on the limited water of the semiarid West.
Discussion: Dallin W. Jensen The authors present an interesting and scholarly discussion of the water transfer process, and raise a number of perceptive legal, policy, and institutional issues for consideration. This discussion will focus only on certain aspects of this chapter. As the authors point out, unallocated water is virtually nil in many river basins, and offers no realistic hope of meeting future needs. Even if some water is available, it may not be in an area where new development is proposed. Also, a late priority application to appropriate may not offer the certainty of supply that would justify investment of capital. The only viable alternative to accommodate much of the new industrial and municipal development is to acquire and convert existing agricultural rights to satisfy the new uses. Thus, a sound and functional transfer process is critical to the continued vitality of the West.
With certain exceptions, most states have historically allowed the transfer of existing rights to satisfy new uses so long as other existing water rights on the same source are not impaired. Thus, if the return flow from an upstream irrigator returned to the natural watercourse and formed a portion of downstream rights, the upstream irrigator could not by transfer subsequently diminish the return flow to the downstream user without compensation. Subject to the caveat of nonimpairment of other rights, the majority of the western states have followed a policy with respect to proposed changes which has generally facilitated the marketability of water rights and has not unduly restricted their subsequent conversion to satisfy other uses. Some opportunity exists under such a system to accommodate new uses without materially disrupting existing agricultural uses. Such a result was recently accomplished in Utah, where the Intermountain Power Project (IPP) proposes to construct an electrical generating facility in the Sevier River Basin near Lynndyl, Utah. IPP needed to secure 45,000 acre-feet of water annually—but the Sevier River and its tributaries are fully appropriated. Thus, the only option available to IPP was to purchase existing irrigation rights and convert those rights to industrial use. The bulk of the water was acquired from stockholders in five mutual water companies under an agreement whereby each shareholder was limited in the amount of stock (water) he could sell. Change applications were then filed by the irrigation companies to convert the water represented by these shares from agricultural to industrial use. The individual users will retire
― 432 ― only their marginal lands from irrigation, and must make a more efficient use of their remaining agricultural water. The net effect is that there will be very little disruption to the existing agricultural industry. Admittedly, this project was accomplished with a maximum of voluntary cooperation from the parties involved, but nevertheless the legal and institutional machinery provided the basic framework. The foregoing discussion is not to suggest that improvements could not or should not be made in the legal and institutional framework governing water transfers. As the authors point out, some states have taken steps to allow for consideration of other factors in the decision-making process governing water transfers. However, it would appear that if there is going to be any major modification of state policy in this regard, such modification will have to come through the legislative process. It seems somewhat questionable that the courts will be the vehicle to impose significant public interest criteria upon such changes, as the authors suggest. The criteria governing such changes are reasonably well-established in most states, and have been the subject of both administrative and court review over the years. The result is that the courts in the various states have had occasion to define the limits on transfer procedures under existing law. This definition occurred at an
earlier time, when the public interest in water use was perceived primarily in an economic and developmental context. Thus, while there may be some opportunity to expand the change process in some states to include other factors, it seems doubtful that most courts are going to make major adjustments in this area as a policy matter without some further legislative expression on this subject. In this regard, a number of states have adopted legislation to recognize in-stream values, for example, and to provide some measure of protection to these values once they are identified. It is not the purpose of this discussion to identify or evaluate these programs, but simply to point out that once these strategies are in place, presumably any water transfer would be subject to them, and this would then form an additional constraint on future water transfers. It does appear that the institutional and regulatory structures governing change applications are likely to be the subject of some reevaluation in the future. As the size and number of water transfers continue to increase, so will efforts to broaden the traditional evaluation of such changes to include other public policy considerations. However, the states need to maintain a balanced and functional transfer process so that necessary and
― 433 ― desirable changes can be accomplished. Any institutional modifications in this area will depend largely upon the public policies of the various states as perceived by the state legislatures. The alternative path identified by the authors, more active involvement by local government entities, seems less likely. Legislation implementing such a program may be difficult to enact—particularly if it contains condemnation provisions. Further, as a practical matter, the prospect of a public corporation acquiring the needed capital and setting up a water purchase and leasing program for water rights in an area on a large scale basis seems doubtful.
Discussion: Ronald B. Robie Brown and DuMars provide an unusual perspective on water markets. Instead of the usual concerns about overcoming institutional barriers which inhibit the establishment of water markets, they emphasize the need for institutional arrangements capable of constraining market transfers of water between private individuals to protect the broader public interest from an unfettered water market. From the California experience, this perspective, emphasizing regulation at the local level of market transactions, confuses both the essential issue of the appropriate role for government in water markets and the efficiency and equity aspects of these transactions.
At the present time in California, there is little threat to the public interest, however broadly defined, from the allocation of water through unregulated water markets. There is essentially no private market for water. As for the future, I am less sanguine than the authors about the prospects for unregulated water markets becoming the dominant mechanism for allocating water, at least in California. Public agencies dominate the California water industry. The significance of this public dominance was noted in a study of Southern California's water industry: "The public character of most of its key organizations places buyers and sellers under constraints normally not found in the private sector."[1] Virtually every water transaction of significance within the state is scrutinized and subject to approval by some type of public organization. Under existing law, a holder of a post-1914 appropriative right must petition the State Water Resources Control Board for
― 434 ― approval of any water right transfers involving a change of place of use, point of diversion, or purpose of use. The federal government's Bureau of Reclamation has control over the allocation of over a quarter of the approximately 40 million acre-feet (MAF) per year of water used in California through the operation of the Central Valley Project (CVP) and the Bureau's Colorado River Project. The State of California, through the State Water Project (SWP), allocates some two to three MAF yearly. The Metropolitan Water District of Southern California alone allocates over half of Southern California's water supply. In irrigation districts the boards of directors have substantial authority to determine water allocations; even the State Treasurer can have a say, as California water districts must receive approval from the District Securities Advisory Commission for a lease of surplus water outside the district for more than one year. In effect, the public character of California's water industry guarantees that some notion of the public interest will be represented in any water transaction. The problem in California, then, is different from that described by Brown and DuMars for other western states—there is no problem in creating public overseers of private water markets; they already abound. One reason for so few transfers to date are too many overseers! The important question concerns what and whose interests these public agencies represent. How broadly or narrowly do these public entities define the public interest? Do they represent the state as a whole or a small client group? This points up a problem with the chapter's reliance on local agencies to solve the equity issue. Local public agencies are no more likely to represent broad public interest than the market. All of this suggests a role for government the reverse of that outlined by Brown and DuMars—namely,
government, at least at the state level, has a major role to play in promoting and fostering market transactions that move water to higher-valued uses. If public agencies are motivated to move water to higher-valued uses, the state government has a very clear role in promoting this behavior by reducing transaction costs, such as locating buyers and sellers, and monitoring the actual quantity exchanged to assure nonimpairment of return flow rights of such transfers. As the authors note, these transaction costs are presently substantial. Reducing transaction costs may also help overcome the problem of monopoly distortions in water markets.
― 435 ― Finally, what about the concern stressed in the chapter that the public has an interest in protecting irrigated agriculture and the rural society it supports? While legitimate, the problem is to some extent exaggerated. Accompanying the increasing frequency of transfer of water rights from agriculture to industrial and municipal uses in the West is the belief that there are some "bad" economic consequences which will occur if this process continues. Brown and DuMars share this belief. While discussing the return flow problem, they point out that the nonimpairment provision applies only to other rightholders and does not extend to protect the capital investment of other secondary entrepreneurs. They also state their concern with the distributional consequences of the loss of water rights to rural economies. The issue involved here is that of efficiency versus equity. Although the outcome of a market transaction is efficient, it may not be socially acceptable. Let us examine how justified this concern is for deterioration of rural communities due to the transfer of water rights from agriculture to industrial uses. In 1978, industrial, residential, and governmental water uses in California amounted to about 14 percent of the total. The remaining 86 percent went to agriculture. Industrial uses accounted for no more than 6 percent of the total. While using only 6 percent of the water, industry generated 84 percent of gross state income and 78 percent of total employment.[2] As for the use of water in production of energy, fresh water used in producing energy (thermal electric generation; extracting and processing oil and natural gas) amounted to about 1.1 MAF or 3 percent of developed water supplies in 1976. For comparison, in 1975, a total of about 31.7 MAF was used for irrigated agriculture. Of this amount, about 13.5 MAF or 37 percent of developed supplies was used to produce livestock feed. Water requirements for energy will not increase significantly in the near future. Since the anticipated increases in energy demand have not
developed, the forecasts of future increases have been lowered and major utility companies of the state have cancelled or postponed plans for major new in-state power plants.[3] Nor has the shift from foreign to domestic oil and gas sources been as strong as anticipated. In summary, under a less restricted intertransfer situation, some water might move out of agriculture, but since the demand for water in domestic, commercial, and industrial uses is relatively price-inelastic and there are few unsatisfied demands, the
― 436 ― amount of water transferred may not be very great. Those nonagricultural users who anticipate future growth might buy up water, but might lease it back to agriculture until the growth occurred. Most of the water exchanges would be expected within agriculture, from low value to high value crops.[4]
Chapter 19— One State's Strategy for Putting Water to Beneficial Use by Ted Schwinden
Abstract Increased use and competition for water have made shortages and conflicts today's realities in many of Montana's drainages. Montana has begun the implementation of a water resource management program to ensure adequate water supplies for Montanans, both now and in the future. The program has four basic elements: 1) A water adjudication system to document water rights acquired before 1973. Another objective of the adjudication program is to quantify Indian and non-Indian federal reserved water rights. 2) A study authorized by the legislature to determine how much water will be needed for future beneficial use in Montana. The study also examines how potential future water development in Montana may be constrained by downstream water claims. 3) A water reservation system that allows agencies to apply to the state to reserve water for anticipated diversionary future uses or to maintain a
minimum flow, level, or quantity of water instream. 4) A water development program which makes state funding available for water projects. Funds for the projects come from several sources, including the Resource Indemnity Trust and revenues from existing state water projects. The program also authorizes low-interest loans and grants to fund public and private water projects, and provides a $250 million bonding authority to implement water projects developed by the state and approved by the legislature.
Few issues are more important to Montana than water and agriculture. If it's safe to say that agriculture is the wheel on which Montana's economy turns, then water is the hub of that wheel.
― 438 ― In the United States, our limited fresh water supplies cannot satisfy our national thirst forever, if that thirst keeps doubling every twenty years. In some cities, water problems have reached critical proportions; and in some areas, particularly the Southwest, water shortages are threatening agricultural productivity. Not long ago, Gerald D. Seinwill, of the U.S. Water Resources Council, said that "water is the most serious long-range problem now confronting the nation . . . " Seinwell and other reputable, knowledgeable individuals warn of a water crisis of international dimensions in the 1980s and 90s, of a magnitude comparable to the oil crisis of the 1970s. I was invited to discuss state and local public policy with regard to strategies and tactics for maintaining agricultural viability in the face of declining water available for irrigation. Accordingly, I will explain in some detail the approach being followed in my own state of Montana. In Montana, only about 2.6 million acres now are irrigated, but another 10.6 million acres are classified as irrigable. The amount of irrigated land has increased at a very modest pace of about one percent per year, and projections indicate a continued modest growth into the future. That is not to say that all is well with water and agriculture in Montana. The problems that occur are no longer entirely traceable to the vagaries of precipitation patterns. Instead, increased use and competition for water have made shortages and
conflicts today's realities in many of our drainages. In the Milk River, in northern Montana and Canada, for example, the state was forced to impose a moratorium on the issuance of new water use permits. On the Powder River, in southeastern Montana, two companies are in court battling to claim remaining flows—flows clearly insufficient to satisfy their energy-related demands. In other areas of our state, water quality has become a major concern. Along the Poplar River near my home in northeastern Montana, irrigators fear pollution originating from a Canadian coal-fired generating complex just across the border. In the Tongue River Basin (heart of the Powder River coal area), return flows contribute to a degree of salinity that makes the expansion of irrigation from that source questionable. Storage frequently offers a solution, but Montana irrigators now pay $5 to $10 for an acre-foot of water. They will not be able to afford the $100 to $200 per acre-foot price tag calculated for some yet-to-be-developed facilities.
― 439 ― Beyond physical supplies, quality, and economics, another category of issues stem from institutional questions. Hydroelectric claims, for example, appear to pose a limit to new upstream irrigation on the Clark Fork drainage of the Columbia and the headwaters of the Missouri. Federal and Indian reserved rights have not been quantified—although major amounts have been filed— nor have the interstate tributaries been allocated between Montana and Wyoming by the Yellowstone River Compact. Disagreements between upper and lower basin states and skirmishes over prospective interbasin transfers are catapulting Montana's water concerns into the national arena. Governor Janklow of South Dakota got the attention of states all the way from Missouri and Nebraska to Arkansas and the desert Southwest with South Dakota's sale of water for the ETSI pipeline. Benjamin Franklin said, "When the well's dry, we know the worth of the water." In Montana, we can't afford to wait to find out the real worth of water. Our challenge and our goal is to ensure adequate water supplies for Montanans, not just for irrigation, but for other beneficial uses, both now and in the future. We have therefore begun the implementation of a water resource management program which has four basic elements. The first is our state's adjudication system, a process which has been appropriately called a way to put a "handle" on Montana's water pump. Since 1973 the Montana Water Use Act has provided an exclusive permit-andcertificate method of acquiring a water right. Before 1973, water rights could be acquired in a number of ways, some of which involved no written documentation of any kind. Consequently, as of today, no one knows exactly
how much water is being legally claimed and used in Montana. Under a recently established program, we have finally begun to quantify and confirm pre-1973 rights. The deadline for filing such claims was April 30, 1982; the Montana Department of Natural Resources and Conservation has begun processing more than 200,000 claims received by that date, and Montana's water courts are setting up the adjudication processes. It is critical to have an accurate quantification of how much water is actually being put to beneficial use in Montana. As a major state newspaper put it, "The best offense against those who might want Montana water is a good defense. What better defense than detailed records of our water and its claimants?"
― 440 ― Another objective of the adjudication program is the quantification of Indian and non-Indian federal reserved rights. To avoid endless litigation with tribes, the 1979 Montana Legislature established the Reserved Water Rights Compact Commission, which was given the authority to negotiate and conclude compacts with willing tribes. The second part of our state's water management approach is a so-called "Use It or Lose It" study authorized by the state legislature to determine how much water will be needed for future beneficial use in Montana. Irrigation currently accounts for 95 percent of the water consumed in our state. Industrial, municipal, livestock, rural domestic, and other uses total less than five percent. The study will also examine how potential future water development in Montana may be constrained by downstream water claims, such as South Dakota's sale. We are reviewing the legal, institutional, and economic incentives and restraints to future water development within Montana and the other Missouri River Basin states. And, finally, the study will examine the options available to resolve conflicting demands: interstate compacts, equitable apportionment suits, and Congressional apportionment. A third element of Montana's water plan is our water reservation system, authorized by the unique provisions of the 1973 Montana Water Use Act. Under this law, federal and state agencies, as well as political subdivisions of the state, may apply to the state to reserve water for anticipated future diversionary uses, or to maintain a minimum flow, level, or quantity of water instream. The decision-making body is our State Board of Natural Resources, a seven-member citizen board, which now has a planning tool to allocate present supplies, as well as to evaluate and provide for anticipated future needs.
The reservation process, which is lengthy and complex, has been completed only in the Yellowstone Basin, where water has been reserved for agricultural, municipal, multi-purpose storage, and other uses. Fourteen local conservation districts and two irrigation districts sought irrigation water, along with three state and federal agencies; 655,000 acre-feet per year was specifically reserved for that purpose, and additional supplies are to be made available from four planned state and federal storage projects. The state is doing all it can to support irrigation. The conservation districts received substantial assistance from the state in preparing documented reservation requests and in
― 441 ― representation during the complicated hearings process. Two full-time state employees are helping the conservation districts develop the detailed plans and the administrative processes necessary to put the reserved water to work. The state is moving to establish reservations in other drainages as well, and I am hopeful that adequate future supplies for irrigation and other beneficial uses can be guaranteed. The fourth and final element of Montana's water management effort provides state financing for water projects. It's no secret that federal funding for water projects has faltered under President Reagan's economic recovery program. For example, the Land and Water Conservation Fund, which had made $3 million available in Montana for water projects annually, has been cut to literally nothing. The Small Loan Program of the Bureau of Reclamation historically provided low-interest loans for irrigation projects, but all of its approved projects have been shelved for the past two years. The Farmer's Home Administration has only one-half of its normal allotment, and the five-state Old West Regional Commission, which provided planning funds for water projects, went out of business a year ago. At the same time, increased competition for (and pressure on) our water resources have made it clear that additional storage, conservation measures, and increased irrigation efficiencies are essential. In that context the Montana State Legislature unanimously approved my first major proposal as Governor in 1981: Senate Bill 409. This was a bold measure, putting state government into a leadership role in the development of the state's water resources. The 1981 legislation supplies funds for water development from several sources. About $1 million a year comes from the earnings of the Resource Indemnity Trust, funded by a severance tax on all minerals. About $300,000 in annual revenues from our state-owned water projects are being used to: (1) plan the rehabilitation of state-owned projects and develop their hydropower potential, (2) assist conservation districts in implementing their water reservations, (3) encourage the development of offstream and tributary storage, and (4) promote joint state, tribal, and federal projects.
SB 409 also authorized low-interest loan and grant programs to fund public and private projects or activities associated with water. That loan/grant program is funded by coal severance taxes to the amount of about $2.5 million annually. An additional $5 million can be made available for loans through general obligation bonding authority (requests to date exceed $27 million).
― 442 ― Finally, SB 409 provides a $250 million bonding authority, which can be used to implement water projects developed by the state and approved by the legislature. I consider the passage of the 1981 water development program to be the major accomplishment of my administration. Clearly, it is one of the most important acts in Montana's water history. Nevertheless, there is much work to do in the area of water project financing if Montana's irrigation potential is to be realized. One approach to funding is through the cooperation of federal, state, and local entities. That approach is used on the Tongue River Dam, a state-owned project in southeastern Montana, where the Northern Cheyenne Tribe, the U.S. Bureau of Reclamation, the U.S. Bureau of Indian Affairs, and the State of Montana are cooperatively funding a feasibility study aimed at an equitable allocation of water, and determining the cost for that water. We are trying to reach a "good-neighbor" agreement with Wyoming on how much Tongue River water can be stored in an enlarged project under the provisions of the Yellowstone Compact—the Tongue River being one of the interstate tributaries governed by that document. Industry can directly assist agriculture. In Utah, for example, a dam proposed to meet the needs of oil shale interests will also provide for the irrigation of Indian lands. In Wyoming, an energy company paid to enlarge and rehabilitate an existing dam to correct safety problems and to protect agricultural supplies, while providing water for its own uses. In Montana, the state might act as an intermediary in the sale of industrial water now available from the Fort Peck, Yellowtail, and Tongue River reservoirs, where proceeds could be used to help offset the cost of irrigation. On the other hand, the development of heavy oil, tar sands, oil shale, coal generation, gasification and liquefaction plants could seriously disrupt water use by agricultural users. Perhaps energy-rich, but water-short, states should export raw energy resources to more water-abundant demand centers for processing and conversion. In any event, when energy conversion takes place in the semiarid West, we must encourage the use of the most water-conservative technologies, even if those technologies are more expensive. State governments can employ three other approaches to expand irrigated
land, to maintain it at its current level, or to slow the progress of its decline. The relative importance of agriculture in each state will dictate the selection and application of the remedies.
― 443 ― One avenue is to use tax incentives to keep land and water in agricultural production—or, conversely, to impose penalties for converting them to other uses. A second approach is to utilize water law. Montana, for example, prohibits an appropriator of more than 15 cubic feet per second (cfs) from changing an agricultural water right to an industrial right. Other statutory approaches could include a preference system to establish agriculture as a preferred use, allowing municipalities to condemn agricultural water rights, or prohibiting the severance or sale of water rights once they have been perfected for agricultural purposes. The third approach involves land use controls—ranging from the purchase of development rights, to subdivision regulation, to the type of state-level landuse planning done in Oregon. Government banking of agricultural land for future lease or sale to individuals, as practiced in Saskatchewan, is an innovative land-use concept that deserves review and evaluation. With respect to local government's role in maintaining agricultural viability, I will mention only two points. The first relates to soil and water conservation districts. In Montana, these districts have evolved into responsible, effective organizations. Conservation districts along the Yellowstone have reserved water for future irrigation, are making plans to develop that water, and in the process, are becoming a significant water management force in the basin. Conservation districts in northcentral Montana have been conducting an effective saline seep control demonstration project for several years, and are a major force in combating that epidemic problem. Enabling legislation in Montana authorizes conservation districts to levy taxes, to initiate projects, and to create and enforce regulations with the effect of law. Those powers have generally been unexercised in the past, but that is beginning to change. Conservation districts have the potential to become major agricultural and natural resource entities in the future. States cannot expect local government to continually shoulder an increasing share of water development responsibilities without providing them adequate funding. Under the New Federalism, state governments are getting a crash lesson in learning the limits of their abilities to assume the provisions of federal programs—but it's easy to forget that lesson. That's why, in Montana, I'm proposing a new method of distributing funds to local government through a block grant system. Cities and counties will receive, with greatly expanded flexibility, all the present
― 444 ― taxes and fees, and we will ask for an additional state General Fund appropriation and a specific percentage of the state oil severance tax to go to local governments. The "bottom line" is that it will take more than the initiative and cooperation of local and state governments to resolve the problems facing irrigated agriculture. There must be a responsible federal role. And money!
― 445 ―
Chapter 20— Federal Water Policies and Irrigated Agriculture by Garrey E. Carruthers, Thomas G. Bahr, Herbert H. Fullerton, and Norman H. Starler
Abstract The cornerstone of this administration's water policy is that control of this nation's water resources is a state's right. Primacy in water allocation and management decisions should continue to rest with the states. Federal water policy should emphasize the importance of strengthening partnerships between federal and nonfederal interests in water development and use. The introduction to this chapter offers the hypothesis that overregulation and distortion of water markets impair the ability of irrigated agriculture in the semiarid West to respond to changing economic conditions. The second section introduces a working concept of maintaining long-run agricultural viability through application of market incentives; the third section addresses water allocation decisions and economic development as related to long-run adjustments to resource scarcity; the fourth section briefly reviews historic federal policies on supply augmentation, cost recovery, feasibility determination, and expenditure priorities; and the fifth section outlines an opinion on what direction emerging federal policy should take. A discussion of recent federal actions provides a preview of opportunities for joint ventures and cost sharing while placing greater reliance on market transactions and water transfers. The chapter concludes with reference to the need for balance in federal and nonfederal roles in the development of agricultural water supplies in the semiarid West. Emphasis is placed on deregulation of water markets which
heretofore may have limited the ability of nonfederal entities to make full use of the market in resolving water scarcity problems.
Historically, the development of water resources has been crucial to settlement, expansion, and diversification of the economic base of the semiarid western United States. For more than 100
― 446 ― years, individuals, businesses, states, and the federal government have worked with demonstrable success in implanting technologies and creating institutions within these regions which have led to development, control, and utilization of scarce water supplies. Testimony to the success of these efforts is the 20 million acres currently under irrigation in the United States, and the fact that cost-efficient project development opportunities have become less plentiful. Since the late 1930s, many semiarid regions of the West have experienced very rapid nonagricultural expansion and concurrent large increases in water demand. Continued growth of similar magnitude suggests a future with increasing competition and higher cost for water. Because irrigated agriculture is currently a majority user of relatively low-cost water supplies, projections of continued growth cause some to question agriculture's longrun ability to remain competitive with other users. Clearly the emerging physical, economic, and political realities surrounding the supply and demand for water resources will have significant bearing on water cost and availability to agriculture, and ultimately on the shape of federal water policy.[1] The central theme for this chapter is that the long-run ability of irrigated agriculture to remain economically viable and thus to compete without subsidy for limited water supplies will be enhanced by placing greater reliance on markets to guide water allocation and investment decisions. The relative wealth and long-run economic viability of irrigated agriculture are inextricably woven into the question of who pays the cost of access to water, and what conditions, if any, are attached to transfer of water service to other users. The basic assumption which underlies this assertion is that traditional federal water policies have followed a pattern of emphasizing developmental objectives (settlement, cheap food, economic stability, foreign exchange) and federal financial responsibility for water development, without sufficient regard for their market-distorting effects which reduce resource use efficiency, economic efficiency, and water resource value. Such an emphasis facilitates maintenance of institutions, contractual arrangements, and water pricing which discourage further definition of transferable property rights to water and water service, thus foreclosing
opportunities for state water laws to function as designed. It also encourages capital-intensive solutions to water problems, and a continuing expectation that leadership in solving water problems rests primarily with the federal government.
― 447 ― The current administration places primacy in water allocation and management with the states, and seeks a true partnership with states and other nonfederal water interests in the planning, finance, and development of water projects. Greater reliance on private water markets will also require (1) recognition of private property interests in federal water service, including third party interests, (2) selective removal of federal distortions to water markets, (3) further definition of conditions for transfer of water use, and (4) encouragement of projects which overcome physical barriers to market transfers.
Agricultural Viability In keeping with the general theme of this volume on the impacts of limited new (emphasis added) water for agriculture in the semiarid West, the question of agricultural viability is addressed within the context of increasing competition and higher real prices for existing water. In farming, just as in any other business, the market provides the ultimate test of long-run viability. Long run viability requires the ability to turn a normal profit after paying for all those inputs needed in a farm operation, including payment for labor, equipment, the use of money, fertilizers, fuel, pesticides, and water. Although the prices and quantities of water used vary significantly among crops and service systems, water as an input to agricultural production averages from 5 to 30 percent of total input costs. When the price and availability of these inputs change, it is reasonable to expect that the nature, limit, and the location of farm activities might also change. The difference between water and most other farm inputs is that water, especially in cases which involve change in point of diversion and/or use, is restricted administratively through public institutions rather than by the market. The federal government, rather than acting as a financially rational lien holder, acts as an owner without market incentives. Although state laws contain certain administrative restrictions, in many cases they do provide for financially rational behavior. To the extent that the priorities guiding administrative allocations are coincident with those that would be assigned by a functioning market, economic viability will not be arbitrarily affected. Fortunately, the water laws and administrative procedures of most arid states have allowed, if not encouraged, transfers of water in response to market incentives. Such transfers
― 448 ― encourage efficient water use and increase the availability of existing supplies. With the addition of federal projects, these market incentives may be seriously distorted by subsidies, and restriction on transfers embodied in contract terms. A central question is what would happen if competition for water supplies caused the supply of water for agriculture to be diminished; the further question is what adjustments in agriculture might be expected when water becomes more expensive. Given an increase in price or cost of water, farmers would likely respond by substituting other inputs for the more expensive water, and by adjusting cropping patterns to reduce acreage or to discontinue producing crops with low value return to water. Moreover, farmers would become highly receptive to management practices and technologies which use water more efficiently. These adjustments are already happening on a large scale throughout the western states. Ultimately, one would expect that crops which are no longer profitable in a given area will either be produced elsewhere or possibly not all. Thus, the economic realities of increasing competition for water will continue to change the character of agriculture in the semiarid West. The type of agriculture which remains profitable and is competitive with other industries for water and other scarce resources will remain viable.[2]
Water Resource Allocation and Economic Development Economic development is enhanced by efficient use of water. In rapidly growing areas such as the western United States, decisions to allocate and transfer water among competing uses will have to be made whether water markets are allowed to operate effectively or not. What is important is the question of whether or not these decisions lead to efficient use of water. Some observations in this regard are: 1) Competition for water and other scarce resources is a fact of life. 2) If water is scarce and marketable, it will move in the direction of the highest value use as reflected by the highest bid. 3) Voluntary transfer of existing and new water supplies in response to market prices enhances economic
― 449 ― efficiency, encourages economic growth, and increases the value of the nation's water resources. 4) Unnecessary restrictions on water transfer (market distortions) inhibit economic growth, reduce economic efficiency, and reduce the value of the nation's water resources.[3] 5) Removal of market distortions, including assurance that current users and third parties are compensated for any reduction in their use of water, will increase the availability of water to high value users. Market-based reallocations will most likely result in an economy in which a larger fraction of water is used in the nonagricultural sector. Given an initial 85/15 agriculture/nonagricultural water distribution, a twofold expansion of nonagricultural use would reduce this ratio to 70/30. Numerous studies have demonstrated that adjustments in this range would not seriously affect agricultural viability, i.e., a total economy on a state or regional basis. However, this is not to say that some small areas with a history of groundwater mining and very rapid nonagricultural growth would not be seriously affected. In the long run, alternatives for resolving these scarcity problems should not emphasize federal regulation of use and further subsidization of water price when there is potential for making the necessary adjustments in resource use with voluntary transfer of ownership between willing buyers and sellers.
Historic Federal Water Policies Supply Augmentation An historical look at federal water policies may be useful to demonstrate the potential of moving toward a market emphasis. In the past, federal policy emphasized supply augmentation primarily through constructing storage and conveyance facilities. Major emphasis was on development of arid regions in the West. Under the Reclamation Act of 1902, the focus of the Bureau was to increase the supply of water available for irrigation. As the West was developed and as demand for water increased, supply augmentation served de facto as the primary means of solving the problem of getting water to those who did not have it. Supply augmentation picked up the slack, and little water was transferred from one use to another. As a result, a variety of institutions and contractual arrangements were created to
― 450 ―
administer these federally augmented water supplies. The primary purpose of these institutions and contracts was not to encourage market transfers, but to assure project repayment and to administer new water supplies.[4] Indirectly, water marketing among users and uses was discouraged because of overt restrictions or prohibitions on transfer.
Project Cost Recovery Gradually, as population and industrial activity expanded, the Bureau of Reclamation, as well as other federal water development agencies, added additional project purposes such as hydropower (beyond irrigation pumping needs), flood control, and municipal and industrial water supplies. From its inception, project cost recovery was a central feature of the Bureau of Reclamation programs. However, the extent of repayment varied by project purpose. Irrigation beneficiaries traditionally repaid allocated construction and operation and maintenance costs. Hydropower and municipal beneficiaries repaid construction cost plus interest. In contrast, flood control was provided by the federal government without requiring repayment from beneficiaries. However, extended repayment terms, transfer of power revenues to cover part of irrigation construction costs, and congressionally authorized exemption from interest charges significantly reduced agriculture's repayment obligation.[5] The Congress, in authorizing Bureau projects, chose to pursue developmental objectives which placed little emphasis on the implications of repayment arrangements on market incentives.[6]
Project Feasibility As the best project sites were developed, the cost for additional multipurpose projects increased, thus placing greater demands on the U.S. Treasury. Closer public scrutiny evolved quite naturally because project investments were evaluated at less than market rates and direct beneficiaries were not required to pay the full costs including interest. The combination of higher costs, public subsidy, and a call for closer scrutiny of public water projects stimulated attempts to provide more realistic preassessment of the economic efficiency of planned water supply projects using benefit/cost analysis. Although these analyses attempted to impose the discipline of the market in measuring project benefits from vendible and nonvendible project purposes against project costs, numerous problems have been encountered in their application and interpretation.
― 451 ― Three observations are relevant in this regard: (1) some analyses overestimated benefits by double counting,[7] (2) anticipated agricultural development did not take place in some project areas, resulting in
underutilized water presently in storage,[8] and (3) follow-up on past analyses and a survey of current analyses indicates that, given current economic indications, the number of economically feasible multipurpose project sites is somewhat limited.[9] A federal response which addresses the problem of declining and questionable benefit/cost ratios with sole emphasis on either new structural means, or on conservation and nonstructural solutions to water scarcity, is too narrowly drawn. Predictably, the singular emphasis on restricting demand, to the exclusion of the supply side, by the previous administration did not succeed.[10] The current administration advocates a balanced policy that recognizes both supply and demand—i.e., a market-oriented approach.
Examples of Market Distortions Despite the fact that the reclamation program was not intended to encourage markets but to settle and develop the semiarid West, some authors have taken the position that it has directly and/or indirectly prevented markets from functioning efficiently. For example, Rucker and Fishback argue that attempts to enforce the 160-acre limitation ignored economic realities of irrigated agriculture in the U.S. economy and distorted the market.[11] Typical land and water adjustments were precluded by the Act, creating the so-called "excess lands" problem for owners of more than 160 acres (320 acres for a couple). To obtain water, owners of excess land were required to sign a recordable contract in which they agreed to sell these lands within a specified time period. However, the sale price was restricted, by law, to the land value with improvements excluding water supply. This restriction of price on excess land removed incentives for landowners to sell to others who were or would be in compliance with the acreage limitation and thus eligible to receive reclamation water. At the same time, it provided strong incentive for the landowner to seek arrangements that provided legally defensible means for obtaining water service. Rational behavior on the part of reclamation administrators dictated that they would accept these arrangements and provide water service to the excess lands. This contractual arrangement ensured that the stated federal goal of obtaining project repayment was met.[11] When excess project capacity was present with all costs committed, there was strong incentive to supply water to potential users
― 452 ― who were willing to pay an amount in addition to operation and maintenance costs. Historically, water markets have evolved within and along small mutual
irrigation companies. Gisser and Johnson argue that the Bureau of Reclamation, in contracting with public irrigation districts to provide subsidized water, contributed to their dominance of water markets and imposed other distortions on these markets.[12] Districts considered it in their interest to restrict water exchanges for a variety of reasons, including the need to secure their repayment contracts and operations agreements with the Bureau. Gisser and Johnson also document an extension of this rationale wherein an irrigation district used the existence of a repayment contract with the Bureau of Reclamation to block transfer of water rights which predated formation of the district. Some authors have attributed the lack of reliance on markets, at least in part, to the structure and administration of state water law.[13] Water demand estimates have been systematically overstated by planners in states where the structure and administration of water law has discouraged voluntary transfers motivated by differential market value. There is general agreement, however, that the appropriation system of water rights used by the semiarid western states is more conducive to market allocation of water than the riparian system. In fact, potential transfers are permitted in some western states, subject only to reasonable protection of third parties. This requires application to the responsible state authority, such as a State Engineer or State Water Board, which has sufficient information and authority to execute water transactions. In other states, transfers require initial recourse to courts which may have access to limited information and be overly sensitive to potential third party damages. An example of this latter situation is cited, regarding court decisions in which users of irrigation water under the laws of Colorado attempted to sell their water rights to the cities of Denver and Ft. Collins.[14] Traditionally, the federal government has protected third party interests, including international treaty obligations and reserved rights. However, this role did not typically extend to other third party interests, except as they may have been reflected in water service or repayment contracts.
Incentives and Expectations The primary impact on water markets has been a public perception that the federal government will continue to provide new water supplies at less than full cost. Private investment has
― 453 ― been discouraged because of federal competition in water development and a continuing expectation among water users that the federal government will provide water services at subsidized rates. There has been very limited incentive to invest private funds in water development when public funds are or may be available.
Recent high rates of inflation and unemployment, combined with an escalating federal obligation for defense and entitlement programs, have increased the competition for federal money. Water development budgets have not been exempted. No new water project authorizations had cleared the Congress since the last omnibus bill in 1977 until the current session. A continuation of congressional trends will likely force adjustments in private sector expectations and consideration of alternative approaches to water resource development.
Emerging Federal Policy An Overview of Direction Federal policy regarding water supply should emphasize fuller reliance on water markets. This means that: 1) Institutional arrangements should be reviewed with the thought of encouraging voluntary market-based reallocation of water, both within fully utilized water systems and from currently underutilized water systems. 2) The extent of property interest in water on the part of current users should be unequivocally specified by the states. 3) Reductions in water use must be voluntary, with compensation mutually agreed by the contracting parties. 4) Development of new water supplies must involve joint ventures between nonfederal and federal entities to validate economic feasibility conclusions, to ensure financial feasibility, and to specify the federal role. At this time, the extent of voluntary exchanges where the federal government has involvement appears to be limited. In some instances, contractual arrangements between the Bureau of Reclamation and states or other contracting entities have been
― 454 ― cited as discouraging and in some cases prohibiting transfers between users, even within the same water service system. Such contractual arrangements create strong negative incentives for efficient reallocation of water supplies, because they prevent water users from seeking and receiving compensation for reducing water use. Sale of water is encumbered by uncertainty concerning repayment obligations to the federal government, maintenance
of what may be excessive protection of third party interests, and the absence of clearly defined property interests of current users in federally supplied water. Clearly, definition of property rights becomes the primary consideration. If the role of the public sector is restricted to that of financier, then a lien on water and associated facilities is all that is necessary to protect the public's investment. However, the traditional federal role has been that of developer as well as financier. Thus, there was strong incentive to establish and maintain control of water and water rights as well as facilities. The federal government has taken a first step in the clarification of ownership rights by renouncing the concept of nonreserved water rights for federal purposes, and reaffirming the supremacy of states in the management and control of water. The Interior solicitor concluded that a federal reserved water right was limited to the purpose for which Congress reserved the land, and that the federal government would have to apply to the states for other purposes.[15] Prior to this decision, the federal nonreserved water rights doctrine cast doubt on individual water rights granted by the states. Other steps directed to establishing a market orientation for water either already under way or which should be considered are: (1) encouraging sale of underutilized water and storage capacity; (2) encouraging more states to recognize rental or interim sale of water as a beneficial use, in a way that would not reduce the certainty of existing legal claims on water supply; (3) supporting development of institutions, such as water banking, which facilitate market-oriented groundwater and surface water transfers; (4) encouraging joint ventures for the development of new waters; (5) negotiation of new federal/nonfederal water service contracts based on current market value and past commitments; (6) implementing the new fullcost water charge provisions of the 1982 amendments to the Reclamation Act in such a way as to encourage efficient utilization and cost recovery; (7) quantification of federal water rights; and (8) settlement of Indian water claims. Further discussion is limited to the first four steps identified.
― 455 ―
Sale of Underutilized Water Under Bureau of Reclamation management, some water is not being utilized for the intended project purpose. In 1981 the Bureau adopted water marketing policy which encourages states to identify potential markets for underutilized water. An example of this is the attempt to implement an agreement between the state of South Dakota and Energy Transportation System, Inc. (ETSI), which was sanctioned by the Bureau. This would use water from the Oahe Reservoir for a coal slurry pipeline from Wyoming to the southern states. This represents a small portion of water for which
potential agricultural uses would be foregone. Nebraska, Iowa, and Missouri have taken exception to this proposal, indicating that their future utilization of Missouri River water would be impaired.[16] The ETSI contract appears to be a move in the direction of market incentives. However, it illustrates that such transfers can be accomplished only with adequate consideration of third party interests. Voluntary agreement among all parties affected by ETSI was not attained and therefore the courts must provide the decision. This decision will further define the extent of third party interests across state boundaries.
Sale of Storage Rights An example of a sale or use transfer is the June 1982 sale of conservation capacity in the Bureau of Reclamation's Bonny Reservoir to the state of Colorado. The state will use about 40,000 acre-feet for recreation, fish and wildlife purposes which were initially scheduled for use as irrigation storage. Flood control is the primary purpose of the facility and conservation storage was included for future development. Sale was made possible by the conclusion that irrigation was not a feasible addition. A more typical market situation would have provided the opportunity for other interests to be represented in a competitive bidding process. However, this transaction between public entities, although outside the usual definition of markets, encouraged more efficient use of reservoir storage capacity.
Water Banking During the drought of 1977, there was cooperation in California among local water districts, the state, and the Bureau of Reclamation Central Valley Project, in facilitating transfers of water via a banking system. Although it has been described as a banking system, it was primarily a system of brokering water. Some
― 456 ― users sold water and others bought it. Subsequently, water exchanges in nonemergency situations have been documented in California.[17] The interface of federal projects with these kinds of transfers will be carefully examined, and state suggestions for facilitating this process are welcomed on a case-by-case basis to determine if the federal role should extend beyond that of a lien holder to include developmental responsibility. Traditionally, reclamation investments were made in a developmental context to accomplish western settlement and to diversify the agricultural production base. If exchanges are encouraged, they will result in a de facto limitation of the federal role to that of lien holder rather than agricultural developer, because water service would not be restricted to irrigation. To the extent that current water users are allowed to capture the difference
between current use values and any higher value uses, their wealth position will be improved by placing greater reliance on markets.
Water as an Item of Commerce The High Plains (Ogallala Aquifer) studies have been completed and their findings are being reviewed.[18] In this context, the Bureau of Reclamation is assessing technical assistance to the states that might be made on integrated ground- and surface water utilization. Determining the extent of market opportunities is an important part of this review. Also, state and interstate concerns relating to potential market solutions are already being addressed in the courts. The recent Sporhase decision of the U.S. Supreme Court, along with follow-up actions, will clarify the potential for marketing water across state boundaries. In this case, an individual's farm straddles the border of Nebraska and Colorado. The farmer's right to pump water from an aquifer in Nebraska to provide a water supply to the portion of his land in Colorado was at issue, since Nebraska law prohibits out-of-state transfers to states that do not have reciprocal agreements. Colorado did not have such an agreement. In this litigative process, one question became that of determining whether groundwater was an article of interstate commerce which should not be restricted by another state. The Court ruled that groundwater was an item of commerce, but still allowed that a state may ban water exports if the ban is "narrowly tailored" to the goal of conserving water.[19]
― 457 ―
Joint Ventures for the Development of New Water Supplies In addition to facilitation of voluntary exchange of water supplies, the federal government will continue to have a role in new water augmentation plans. However, this role should be limited to joint federal/nonfederal partnerships where nonfederal entities (project beneficiaries and state and local governments) validate feasibility determinations by making a financial commitment to the project, thus diminishing the responsibility of the federal sector both as financier (lien holder) and as developer.[20] Given a feasible project plan that includes related economic, social, and environmental costs, a willingness on the part of nonfederal entities to participate in financing provides ultimate project validation. This is commonly referred to as cost sharing. These joint venture agreements should contain clear statements of ownership rights which make provision for transfer of water, repayment, and O&M responsibilities. The underlying assumption is if a potential project water user really believes he needs and can profit from the new water to be developed, he will pay for it either up front or over time or in some
combination. Looking into the future, new water development will likely emphasize catalytic projects, such as those which provide interconnections between existing units or support the optimization of conjunctive use of ground- and surface water systems. Furthermore, these projects will be modest in scale and of an intrastate scope. Therefore, nonfederal entities could more easily play the role of senior partner in a great number of such ventures, or better yet, the sole partner where no significant federal interests are identified. Joint ventures would be equally appropriate for investments involving the rehabilitation costs on existing water facilities. The long-term assignment of responsibility for these costs is not entirely clear and should be established. As a minimum, rehabilitation of all or parts of older multipurpose facilities should be addressed in the same way as new augmentation projects, because they require expenditure of new money and should be subjected to feasibility tests and cost sharing guidelines. Joint ventures impose a market test of economic feasibility. By extending greater responsibility for finance and repayment to states, the source of repayment beyond that provided by direct beneficiaries must be addressed by the state. Thus, the state becomes an active participant in determining if beneficiary repayment will be sufficient to support the investment. As such, state decision makers must assess the market for vendibles and impute a value for nonvendibles.
― 458 ―
Conclusions It is the policy of this administration that control of this nation's water resources is a state's right. Primacy in water allocation and management decisions will continue to rest with the states. It is the thesis of this chapter that some aspects of both state and federal water policy have resulted in market distortions and reduced use efficiency and value of water resources. The conclusion is that allocation of water resources, both new and those already developed, is best handled by markets which function without unnecessary interference from the public sector. To the extent possible, market distortions which are the responsibility of the federal sector should be identified and removed. Future water development should fully reflect state leadership in which the federal role is one of cost sharing in those cases where significant federal interests are present. In the absence of state leadership and nonfederal cost sharing, new multiobjective water projects will be limited and increasingly difficult to justify. Initiatives in nontraditional technologies for increasing water supply will also look toward state leadership and joint ventures for research and development.
If water markets operate effectively, the agricultural sector in the semiarid West will continue to be strong and viable. Price incentives and increases in water resource values will encourage individual adjustments in water resource use, with net movement toward high value uses both in agriculture and in the nonagricultural sector. In the longer term, higher water resource values in agriculture should provide an adequate asset base and appropriate incentive to employ the more efficient technologies, improved genetic materials, and a more efficient management which are most essential to the continued viability of the industry.
Discussion on Part IV Discussion: Henry P. Caulfield, Jr. The assumptions on which public policy strategies are based need to be examined, not taken for granted. I, along with others, took for granted certain assumptions in the 1960s and before, which time and experience have proven to be largely false. These false assumptions were: that there were many potential nationally justifiable and publicly salient water resource development projects beyond the substantial developments that had already been built or authorized, or were near authorization; that comprehensive river basin planning and authorizations were the best political means of realizing these potentials; and that water resource development would continue to be strong politically at the national level, through the efforts of key Congressional coalition leaders supported by active and strong interest groups. Other political factors were involved, but without validity of the foregoing assumptions some of the strategies embodied and implied in the Water Resources Planning Act of 1965 were doomed to failure. A major assumption of this volume seems to be that a western water crisis can be avoided if water transfers to municipal and industrial use are widely permitted, without substantial harm to agriculture, urban and rural social life, and the environment. By implication, a contrary assumption should be false: that the total
― 461 ― sector-by-sector projections of physical water requirements, compared to total supplies, as set forth in national water assessments for the semiarid West, make water crises inevitable. There appears to be some consensus among the participants in this volume that water use transfers are occurring, and that they will increasingly occur in the future constrained only by respect for third party private interests and necessary and/or desirable public interests. A water crisis, therefore, except in the context of severe drought, need not occur.
Miller and Cardon's analysis of "What Farmers Can Do for Themselves" clearly indicates that farmers have substantial means to avoid harm as water increases in value through market transfers to higher valued uses. Other chapters prepared from different perspectives generally support this conclusion. Also supportive is a fact widely understood that present agricultural use is so large in the semiarid West, compared to quantities likely to be demanded for urban and industrial growth, that such growth will not impinge greatly on agriculture, except in particular areas (e.g., in the Upper Colorado River Basin in Colorado and Utah if and when oil shale and coal production are greatly expanded). Likewise, urban and rural life, except in particular areas, will not be substantially affected. But lack of harm to instream environmental values, as offstream consumptive use of water is intensified, is not so clear. The implications of greatly intensified competitive use of water in the West need more thorough examination, in my opinion, as to the adequacy of existing environmental federal, state and local public policies. The major thrust of the policy chapter from the federal perspective by Carruthers et al. is that the control of the nation's water resources should largely be in the states and that "the long-run ability of irrigated agriculture to remain economically viable . . . will be enhanced by placing greater reliance on [economic] markets to guide water allocation and investment decisions." The authors appear to assume that the western states will increasingly want to exercise their water management responsibilities by fostering economic market transfers in water use, largely unconstrained except by third party and other equitable interests. Thus federal policy should be directed toward removal of restrictions in reclamation law and other regulations and contracts which inhibit market transfers, while, at the same time, making certain that nonfederal financial obligations to the federal government for reclamation projects continue to be met. No doubt much needs to be done to implement this policy, with which I fully agree.
― 462 ― "Unnecessary restrictions on water transfer (market distortions) inhibit economic growth, reduce economic efficiency, and reduce the value of the nation's water resources," Carruthers et al. declare, and by implication they assert an appropriate realm of necessary restrictions. However, they don't develop this implication that economic market failures can exist. In other words, political market places may be necessary to allocate values that are not, and cannot be, adequately represented in economic markets. Thus political instrumentalities of law, regulation, and public funds may be required to constrain economic markets in the interest of these values. More particularly, Carruthers et al. don't recognize present federal and state laws that now constrain economic markets in water rights. What I have in mind generally are environmental laws, including those that provide for wild and scenic rivers, maintenance of low river flow, reservoir recreation pools,
protection of endangered and threatened species of fish and wildlife, preservation of wetlands, etc. Within the context of these and other constraints the domain of appropriate federal policy and action is much larger than recognized by the authors. The assertion that "control of this nation's water resources is a state's right" calls for an enlargement of the administration's concept of federal-state water resources partnership. Governor Schwinden's remarks on state and local public water policy pertain directly only to Montana. At least two major points, however, are of widespread western concern. The first is his reference to "use it or lose it." Montana seems particularly concerned at this time that downstream out-ofstate use of water is going to preclude future consumptive use in Montana of that water, unless definite legal and developmental steps are taken now to preclude downstream claims. This is a widespread problem which, in many interstate river basins, has been settled by interstate water allocation compacts and judicial decrees. "Use it or lose it," however, represents a widespread intrastate problem in the semiarid West, which affects water conservation opportunities and the ability to make economic market transfers of conserved water and consequent economic gains. The problem is caused by the fact that water rights are most often expressed in cubic feet per second for a prescribed period of time—a flow right. The consumptively used part of that flow right, at least in Colorado, can be rented or sold. Thus a farmer attempts to own and keep flow rights equal to his maximum plant needs at particular times in the growing season; he tends to over-appropriate
― 463 ― and over-use early season water. If his water right were stated in terms of acre-feet per year and deliverable in specified quantities upon demand he could control his conserved water to the amount actually needed, and thus minimize his demands upon the system.[1] He could then transfer to others, with financial benefit to himself, the water he did not really need. Such a change, however, could affect present return flows upon which downstream junior rights are based and would be opposed by those otherwise adversely affected. Also, such a change could require increased water storage capacity to provide intrayear water releases upon demand, not to exceed the acrefoot right. The second major point in Governor Schwinden's remarks is further development of state water resources. In addition to Montana, several states have recently taken action to participate financially in proposed federal projects, or to develop further their water resources through state cooperation with local public bodies and private enterprise without federal financial involvement. Among states taking such action are Wyoming and Colorado. California and Texas, of course, have long had such programs.
At the National Water Resources Conference, Washington, D.C., in April 1975, I asserted that "the federal water development program (both in the East and in the West) is politically dying, if not already dead," and went on to explain why.[2] Several factors are involved in this decline, including what proved to be the invalid assumptions that I and others had made earlier. More generally, it can reasonably be asserted that the rationale for federal water resource development is no longer as convincing in Washington, D.C., as it was previously for over a hundred years. There is no longer a sufficient constituency for its support in a nation that is increasingly urban. The Carter Administration's well-known dissatisfaction with federal water projects became manifest through its "hit list," calls for reduced use to solve water supply problems, and "principles, standards and procedures" which very few, if any, proposed water projects could satisfy. President Reagan in his 1980 campaign strongly favored federal water projects, particularly in the West. His Administration has appeared to loosen "principles, standards and procedures" and has taken some steps to authorize projects, but very reluctantly in the face of federal budget problems. Both the Carter and Reagan Administrations have assumed that the key to new water projects is up-front cost sharing with states, local governments, and private interests. Both
― 464 ― have ignored the fact that the old political epithet of "pork barrel" now appears to signify widely to the public, particularly in the East, that no federal water project is ever valid. Both have ignored the more fundamental national political factors which are important regardless of reform in cost sharing policies. Instead of the type of technical and financial partnership set forth in the paper by Carruthers et al., why does the Reagan Administration not jettison much of the federal water resources development program as a manifestation of its New Federalism, and take widespread political credit for abolishing "pork barrel?" Its 1980 campaign commitment in the West to favor federal water projects could be one reason; but with skillful preparatory work and leadership, this hurdle surely could be overcome. Federal block grants could effectively aid water supply and water quality investments made by state and local governments. This financial aid could take the place of some nonreimbursable investment in federal water projects. It could also take the place of federal grants in connection with public sewage treatment projects; could be used in rehabilitation of urban and rural water supply systems, and rehabilitation of old, or investment in new, irrigation projects; and could be used to meet present standards of dam safety and to interconnect water systems to facilitate transfers of water
rights.[3] No doubt it would be a difficult problem to devise a formula for allocation of block grants among the states, but this problem, in principle, is no more difficult of solution than it has already been for the highway program, community development, social services, and others. States and local governments, with staff supplemented by private engineering organizations, are certainly technically capable of replacing staff of the Bureau of Reclamation and the Corps of Engineers. Also, state and local governments generally have authority (but differ somewhat among them) to finance investment costs by revenue and general obligation bonds, particularly where repayments can be met efficiently by user changes and property taxes. Financial aid via the federal block grant is often needed where investment costs cannot be so met (e.g., recreation and enhancement of fish and wildlife). This concept of partnership between federal, state, and local governments appears to me to be more politically feasible than the partnership proposal apparently now being developed within the Reagan Administration. Certainly it would implement more fully the Administration's philosophy of New Federalism. In any case, I hope that the assumptions underlying future federal
― 465 ― water policy will be thoroughly examined and prove to be more valid than those upon which most water policies were based at mid-century.
Discussion: Carole R. Cristiano I am pleased to provide some congressional perspective on this most important issue. In the past, the "congressional perspective" has consisted of an upbeat projection, promising increased availability of federal money to construct new projects and an optimistic estimate of project appropriations. This presentation is not in that grand old tradition. To understand why, it is important to first discuss the problems we confront with our national budget, especially the magnitude of the budget deficits. A few facts are very revealing. 1) In FY 1983, our budget deficit could be close to $180 million. That number is higher than the entire FY 1968 budget of Lyndon Johnson, reputed to be one of the biggest spenders in recent history. 2) The FY 1983 budget includes a line item for interest on the national debt. This payment alone will be higher than Johnson's entire FY 1965 budget.
3) The budgetary problems will be compounded in the coming years. By FY 1986, if we pay only for defense, entitlement programs, and interest on the national debt (in effect eliminating all other government expenditures), we will still have a deficit.
― 466 ― Clearly, Congress cannot eliminate all nondefense discretionary expenditures. But just as clearly, it cannot continue to budget such record deficits. To reduce the projected deficits, the administration and the Congress are confronted with three politically very distasteful options. They can: (1) reduce increases in entitlement programs, including price supports for agricultural commodities; (2) reduce projected increases in defense spending; or (3) increase taxes. Probably they will choose to do a little of each. But each of these decisions is going to take a great deal of time, political capital, and emotional energy. With fiscal problems of this magnitude, Congress will not collectively be predisposed to deal with many other issues, including water development. One can discuss this political reality in different ways. The chapter by Carruthers et al. took the subtle approach; the authors spoke in terms of new federal-state partnerships, increased cost sharing, and leaner, meaner, smaller, more cost-effective projects. Another, perhaps more western approach is somewhat more direct: blunt honesty. The federal money just isn't there. Maybe it should be, and maybe sometime in the distant future it will be again, but right now it is virtually nonexistent. Politicians are not generally known for their blunt honesty, so it is unlikely that there will be an official announcement of this new reality. Instead, there will be a stalemate in policy. Those who support a continued strong federal role in project development will block any programmatic legislation which seeks to reduce or eliminate the federal financial role. While there will continue to be laws on the books which require a strong federal presence, each year there will be less money available. Slowly, individual project sponsors willing to be substantially involved in planning and financing projects will obtain authorizations and construct those projects. But all other new projects will be placed on indefinite hold. The national economy's response to decreased availability of water will not be all that severe. It is not even apparent that the response will be negative. This is also true of decreased federal funding for project development. However, it would be shortsighted to be concerned only with the national economic response. The impacts on regions, on specific areas, and most certainly, on specific individuals, could be very negative and quite severe. We should remember this when we discuss public policy options.
― 467 ― There is another, less definable, but just as important impact. Agriculture is a significant environmental component of all western life. I myself was raised in Denver and lived a typically urban life, yet the attitudes and values I absorbed were much more typical of a rural agricultural environment than of the urban settings of the East. The ambiance of the West is important, and should be maintained. This may not be a federal goal, but state governments may appropriately consider it a high priority. The viewpoints in this volume are encouraging. They indicate that state and local governments, farmers, and financial institutions are taking more initiative and responsibility in resolving their problems. Some states have made basic changes in their water laws. Several authors describe a number of technological innovations in farming. Banks will be more aggressive and more responsive to the needs of agricultural borrowers. This kind of self-help will mitigate the negative impacts of declining water availability. Two areas of thought and activity are worth emphasizing: 1) It must be decided whether it is important to maintain agriculture at its current level. Clearly, in the past we as a nation made a conscious decision to subsidize western agricultural development. It is evident that it is no longer in the national interest to increase or maintain these subsidies. I would not be surprised if such subsidies were gradually decreased in coming years. In the future, the states will have to determine whether it is in their interest to continue these subsidies. If subsidy is deemed to be appropriate, the level must be decided, and how it should be administered. In Montana's case, severance tax revenues are used for water financing—a very appropriate response to the problem. There may be other available financing possibilities to consider. 2) Although the federal role will clearly decrease in the future, it will not be eliminated. While many legislators are concerned about the problems we have discussed, they are frustrated by their inability to determine which programs should have the highest priority. Deliberation should be given to programs of top priority. Research may be one. The Senate recently passed S. 2494, which provides funds for water research institutes and other water research. We are hopeful that it will also pass the House. Research is important, yet the top priority may be something else, perhaps limited impact assistance. Whatever it is,
― 468 ―
those concerned must decide what the program should accomplish, what a reasonable funding level is, and then work with Congress and the administration to address the legislation. The federal government is unlikely to determine which are the top priorities, or even how the program should work—congressmen are too worried about the impact of voting for decreases in Social Security programs. Finally, I would encourage the reader to be heartened. Our nation is going through rough times as we withdraw from our addiction to federal funds. But no other group will be better able to cope with changing times and opportunities than residents of the West. Our heritage of independence and frontier spirit has served us well in the past. It will continue to do so in the future.
Discussion: W. Don Maughan The country and the West will be best served if irrigated agriculture is maintained at a reasonable level. Expansion will be limited to a few places; there is no major dispute that, from a westwide perspective, water for agriculture is a diminishing resource. Groundwater supplies are being overdrafted, undeveloped surface water supplies are being reserved for environmental purposes, and developed surface and groundwater supplies are being syphoned off for urban and industrial growth. Since the West is blessed with ample good land, good climate, and good markets for irrigated agricultural products, the need for the best possible public policy for irrigated land cannot be overstressed. It must be updated periodically due to changing conditions. Nevertheless, public irrigation policy has floundered over the past thirty years. I have had firsthand participation in (a) commissions, councils, and interagency committees; (b) the development of multipurpose and multiobjective principles and standards; and (c) the execution of national, regional, and river basin planning. All these have contributed far too little towards adequate solutions to the vital western water need. They have filled books, reports, and auditoriums, have provided a livelihood for many planners and researchers, and have garnered the support of grassroot organizations and associations. But all together they have weighed but lightly upon decision making in both the public and private sectors. That has to change. We must have policies with substance, that decision makers will use.
― 469 ― We have reached the time when we should candidly categorize what won't work so that we avoid wasting future efforts. It is human nature to seek the
easy or well-traveled road. Too many hold out hope for just one more spectacular irrigated agricultural triumph. However, meeting the near and mid-distance water needs of irrigated agriculture will not accommodate those desires, and we should admit it. I would like to review some of these "dead ends." There is no room for waste of our best talents, energy, and money on promoting large scale interbasin transfer projects for irrigated agriculture. Even after three decades of strenuous efforts, all we have to show are plans for projects that would be too costly, impossible politically, and have major adverse impacts upon the environment. Because such schemes have unusual publicity value, many still insist that massive projects will be the solution for western agriculture. No way! At least not for several generations. Failures of post-World War II attempts to advance long distance importation projects for irrigated agriculture should be clear to all who seek the truth. There is no room for those who yearn for a return of water successes of the past. It is unfortunate, but nearly all the good dam sites, hydroelectric power sites, and man-made water recreation sites have been utilized. The availability of untapped groundwater resources has all but disappeared. There is little room for optimism about weather modification, watershed management, or desalination. Taxpayers have contributed hundreds of millions of dollars to basic and applied research and to a few prototype projects with only marginal success. Even those that have survived appear to be of limited value to the future of irrigated agriculture. Finally, there is no room for regrets. We must take what is available and make the most of it—reuse our treated wastewaters, artificially recharge our groundwater aquifers, conserve, build small- and medium-scale water regulation projects, transfer water supplies to accommodate higher and better uses. There is room to improve efforts to get the most effective persons elected and appointed to public office, to make and execute public water decisions over the next two decades. Water problems are incredibly complex. If those who decide upon public funding and governmental controls have only superficial understanding of the problems and potential solutions, it will not bode well for their decisions. Professional water people must try harder to speak an understandable, practical language of water needs and programs to those officials.
― 470 ― The realization has to sink in that we cannot afford to take any aspect of
water management for granted. We must be able to improve our use of available water supplies by considering basic changes in water allocations and rights. That is a challenging objective. Arizona's 1980 Groundwater Management Act is an outstanding example of a new, innovative direction, but it requires steps that are not easy to take. We have two years of experience since enactment and there are things yet to be learned. Even so, the legislation may be a bellwether for the ways in which agriculture in an extremely dry state can realistically prepare for its long-range future. In Arizona that will mean less acreage in irrigated agriculture, but the reduction will be on an orderly basis. There is room to concentrate more attention on the underlying forces for public funding and regulation. These forces determine whether there will be lasting water resources available for western agriculture. Let us brush away myths. We should not be persuaded that national economic development drives the Congress to provide money; national attention to social and environmental issues has been much more persuasive in the recent past. Local and regional economies are extremely important, however, and straightforward approaches to Congress are much more effective than seeking to put proposals in a so-called national perspective. Past water resources appropriations by the Congress demonstrate this fact. Regulation and management depend upon physical, political, and economic forces. Governmental control has to be based on those facts, and inflexible or impractical regional or river basin policies avoided. Many federal regulations have proven unacceptable over time. State officials must also fulfill their proper roles; federal intervention will not correct weaknesses found in state or local programs. At the same time all states and locals need not carry the same burdens. There is no need for federal involvement in water marketing and transfers. There is room to demand more useful results, not just promises, from investigations, research, data collection, etc. Planners, researchers, and data collectors jealously guard their domains, but their efforts should be graded by others in their fields, as well as decision makers and managers. There is room to borrow, adapt, and use successful water ideas originated by others, though there is sometimes great reluctance to do so. We can take lessons in this regard from Japan and other nations.
― 471 ― These ideas are based on experience and observation, not upon wishful thinking. People engaged in irrigated agriculture need to discern the truth about public water policy; it is important to their future.
― 472 ―
PART V— SUMMARY Chapter 21— Problems, Findings, and Issues by Gilbert F. White The chapters in this volume suggest a rough, and not entirely consistent, outline of how the problem of limited water and irrigation agriculture is viewed, and how its principal components may be related to each other. In appraising this array of evidence and opinion we are obliged to examine the assumptions made as to what constitutes the semiarid West, and to determine what time horizon is relevant, in the present state of shared human ignorance and prescience, to the likely course of events. Greater precision in these matters sharpens findings as well as disagreement. The chapters display substantial consensus on a number of the impacts and effects at local, regional, and national levels, although this is not to say that all that is agreed is valid. They also identify a series of points on which there are diverging views: a few of these are on evidence, more are on methods and inferences, and still more on evaluative judgments. Imbedded in the discussions are five issues that shape the manner of analysis and judgment. At first reading and with a few exceptions, the authors present a relatively sanguine picture of the future for western irrigated agriculture. Excluding those areas facing rapid groundwater exhaustion, the depletion of supply available to irrigation—whether because of economic competition or legal restraint or physical deterioration—seems likely to be slow and gradual. No immediate crisis looms. The opportunities for progressive readjustments therefore are large. The impacts do not promise to be sharp or massive in any one period. This means that there may be time to carry out in a deliberate fashion the several sets of remedial actions outlined in this volume. Is this impression unduly bland? Let us look at the way the problem has been stated, and the assumptions involved, and then enumerate points on which there has been agreement or disagreement or, perhaps, plain confusion.
― 473 ―
The Problem It is more common, and usually more cheering, to look at resource use in terms of development rather than retrenchment. The notion that, in view of physically limited water supplies, continued reduction in some ground reserves, growing population, and expansion of competing demand for other water uses, the volume of water allocated to irrigation is likely to decrease constitutes a relatively new trend in thinking. Indeed, it may be regarded in some circles as un-American. The evidence, however, suggests it is realistic. The direct impacts of such limitation may be identified fairly readily, but their effects upon various sectors and localities in the American economy are less easy to identify and quantify. An implicit assumption is that current trends in use of water will continue. One means of testing that assumption would be to ask whether or not we could envisage any combination of circumstances in which those trends might be halted or even reversed. We shall examine those possibilities in a later section. To the extent we cannot anticipate such a situation, the following questions and observations are the more pertinent.
Principal Components In a crude fashion the present state of irrigation agriculture in the western states is seen as a mosaic of farming systems, reflecting the local conditions of water, land, climate, transportation, and population as affected by the prevailing culture, technology, and social organization, and constrained by national economic conditions and policy. These are diagrammed in Table 21.1. A change in any one of these conditions might affect the character of agriculture. The focus here is on water availability in relation to agriculture, but that does not exclude the possibility that a shift in one or several of the others, such as energy or grain prices, might wholly mask or largely alter the role of water. A change in water availability is viewed as possibly stemming from: 1. Alteration in physical supply through: a. climate change, b. degradation of water quality, c. depletion of aquifer, or d. diversion or storage of surface water; or
2. Reallocation to another use (municipal, industrial, recreational) or place.
― 474 ―
Table 21.1 Types of Water Supply Climate Water sources
Arid Semiarid
Humid
Surface and rechargeable aquifers
A
B
C
D
E
F
Nonrechargeable aquifers
The direct impacts on agriculture of a reduction or shift in water availability are believed to include principally: 1. Reduction in cropped acreage, or 2. Change in cropping pattern and practices, and/or 3. Relocation of irrigation to another area. These impacts, then, are felt in agriculture, water quantity and quality, land quality, community well-being, social institutions, and commodity flows at local, national, and international levels. In certain instances the effects have a feedback relationship to local conditions. For example, a change in irrigation field practices may alter the economic efficiency of farm operation, and the quantity and quality of water available to other farmers. Most effects have significance to the farmers, and some are important for the immediate community, for a distant urban center, for the state or region, or for the nation. Insofar as these consequences are believed to be deleterious and would not be remedied readily over time by readjustments in the current markets for water, land or labor, there may be opportunities to reduce, buffer, or
compensate for them by executive, legislative or judicial actions. Each of these actions needs appraisal in order to judge how efficient, equitable, and practicable it may be. The primary challenge, then, is to identify, assess, and understand the nature of these multiple and diverse linkages among
― 475 ― the principal components as defined. But several dimensions need to be specified in considering the range of papers and comments embodied in this volume.
What is the Semiarid West? A variety of delimitations are implied: all the 17 western states; the semiarid and arid portions of those states; the closed basins and river basins rising in those states. The strict connotation of "arid" in the traditional climatological sense is not used. Probably the basin criterion is the one used by most of the authors, including humid and subhumid portions of drainage areas of the western states. While special attention is given by a number of authors to arid and semiarid areas, the needs for municipal and industrial water in more humid areas also are reviewed. But there is need to specify what area each author describes: a local area, a basin, a state, parts of several states, or the whole West? Generalizations that apply to one may not apply to another, and some of the apparent disagreement among authors springs from the varying connotations. Areas of the High Plains where dry farming is an alternative to irrigation farming are not to be confused with an Arizona desert basin where irrigation is essential to any crop growth. It is dangerous to speak of the semiarid West as though it were homogeneous for any parameter, and certainly not for water sources. The geographic realities need to be recognized.
What Is Water Supply? Most of the chapters deal with water from any source. However, a few concentrate on groundwater and, particularly, aquifers subject to relatively rapid depletion. The distinction between surface and nonrechargeable ground sources is fundamental in some places and not in others. In most instances it is important to recognize the differences among (1) surface water, (2) rechargeable groundwater, and (3) nonrechargeable groundwater. Taking account of both aridity and water source, and drawing on the picture
presented in Chapter 1, it is helpful to think of the semiarid West as containing at least six major types of land shown in Figure 21.1. For this purpose the surface sources are combined with rechargeable ground sources (A, B and C) because they have the common characteristic of being nonexhaustable under proper management, and because most areas with surface supply provide actual or potential opportunities for conjunctive use with ground supplies.
― 476 ―
Figure 21.1 Effects of Limited Water on Irrigated Agriculture
― 477 ― With only a few notable exceptions, the waters of the western states are drawn from basins of types A, B and C, and mostly from basins having all three types. The arid nonrechargeable aquifers of type D, such as those in southern Arizona, are relatively limited in extent, and in other places, such as central Arizona, are served also with surface supplies. The semiarid nonrechargeable aquifers of type E are most extensive, principally the
Ogallala formation. Inasmuch as nonrechargeable aquifers are associated with surface supply in many humid areas, the type F sources are relatively unimportant in setting limits for supply. Unless we speak about the political or economic systems of the 17 states as a whole, it may be profoundly misleading to refer to the water supply of the entire area.
What Is the Time Horizon? Ranging from long-term climatic swings to short-term community dislocation problems, different time horizons are used. They need not be uniform, and clearly the decades or centuries inherent in estimates of precipitation are inappropriate in considering social disruption. It is important, nevertheless, to note how each author specifies the period used. Some of the current popular discussion of western water problems treats the situation as one of impending crisis. In contrast, the chapters in this volume do not paint a picture of imminent disaster. Part of the apparent difference in viewpoint is to be traced to interpretation of the evidence as will be noted later, part to use of widely ranging time horizons, and part to the weight placed on the probability of possibly perturbing events. When the evidence of long-term trends in precipitation and temperature is marshalled in Chapter 1, it is apparent that shifts should be expected to take place gradually over decades or centuries. Depletion of the Ogallala is seen as proceeding for three to four decades in some areas of Texas, and over centuries in Nebraska. Movements of farm population to the cities and reductions in farm labor per unit of product have been continuing at a relatively constant rate. The estimates of time required for a small rural community to respond to a change in farm income flows are in periods of five to ten years. Prices for crops are seen as partly responsive to a slowly growing national demand. The buildup of salts in mismanaged soils may reach serious proportions in a few years, or only over decades, depending on local soil and drainage. The time required to complete a new river impoundment once preliminary planning has begun is of the order of fifteen to twenty years. A large number of the
― 478 ― components in the problem are subject to slow change over long periods. On the other hand, a few of the components might shift in a matter of a few years. These include a drought of severity unseen in 200 years, a sudden increase in energy prices affecting pumping costs, a drastic shift in foreign markets for farm products, the introduction of a new irrigation technology, and judicial recognition of reserved Indian water rights. Other sharp discontinuities in social or physical trends will come to mind. Any one or
several of these events in combination could alter the views of the future prevailing in these papers. Mark Twain liked to point out that reasonable people could differ either because they use the same words to describe different things or different words to describe the same things. Much of the disagreement about western water may be attributed to the differing meanings attached to the semiarid West and to the future.
Convergence and Divergence Having noted these cautions as to generalizations concerning the semiarid West and its future, we may ask wherein the evidence and judgments expressed in this volume converge or diverge. The general definition of the problem as presented above goes largely unchallenged. It appears to be sufficiently comprehensive to permit discussion of all the evidence deemed relevant. Insofar as there appears to be convergence of views they may be stated as propositions. Insofar as divergence of view arises they may be stated as questions.
Consensus Let us put down in short-hand fashion a few of the major propositions that seem to be supported so far. Whether there is anthropogenic or natural climate change beyond the great swings that are part of the dendrochronology record, it is likely to be in the direction of warmer, dryer conditions with possibly greater variability. More humid climatic conditions are not anticipated in appraising the western scene. There are few promising opportunities to increase available water by nonconventional means such as cloud seeding and desalting. No technological breakthroughs now appear to be in the wings.
― 479 ― Opportunities for additional storage may be economic in a few areas, but those for trans-basin diversions are severely limited, both politically and economically. The day of large water-storage projects is seen as waning.
Groundwater supply is moving toward exhaustion in several large aquifers and more small ones at radically different rates, ranging from decades to centuries. But the cost of pumping, exacerbated by mounting energy prices, may halt exploitation before the supplies are depleted. Reallocation of increasingly costly water from agriculture to municipal and industrial (including energy) uses is going forward through transfer of water rights in some areas. Municipalities are acquiring rights in connection with annexations and as part of new storage development. Industries are purchasing rights from farmers. Competition between irrigation and other uses increases rapidly in some areas, and to that extent "shortages" in supply may result for farmlands, although farmers may gain income from sales or leases of water. Salinization is a continuing problem on a substantial but unspecified proportion of irrigated land where drainage is inadequate or water application practices are unsuitable. Methods of managing salt in the soil and of cultivating plants with greater salt tolerance are advancing. Some municipal and many industrial users are decreasing their withdrawal per capita or per production unit, and are likely to continue to do so. The opportunities for using water more efficiently in agriculture in connection with changes in crop patterns and tillage practices are large and numerous, but their economic feasibility is in doubt in many areas. Improvement in production efficiency per unit of water withdrawn does not necessarily free water for other uses. Instream uses for maintenance of aquatic ecosystems are likely to suffer in quality from reduced flows and from more intensive cropping. Rapid abandonment of irrigated land may lead to wind erosion unless conservation measures are taken. Rural communities are likely to dwindle where irrigation activity is reduced, but in any event will probably suffer from migration to the city. More distant urban centers will not experience a measurable effect from decline in irrigation.
― 480 ―
The national economy is not expected to experience dislocations as a result of the likely reductions in irrigated acreage or in cropping patterns.
Doubts and Disagreements The points on which there is not plain consensus are harder to state. The more controversial ones are presented here as questions. In each case there is doubt either as to the methods or data used, or as to the conclusions reached. What is the rate at which pumping for irrigation in specific areas would become uneconomic at current (or future) energy and crop prices? It is recognized that changes in these prices could overshadow depletion as a factor in land abandonment. What factors affect the farmers' decisions to stop pumping and then either move away or change cropping patterns? This is especially relevant in the High Plains where agriculture has moved from dry farming to irrigation and is beginning to revert very slowly. What proportion of water would be saved if all economically feasible conservation measures were applied? These may affect production efficiency but may reduce seepage losses and return flows. What factors affect farmers' decisions to adopt conservation measures in the face of limited supplies and of prevailing water rights systems? Can agricultural water allocations be expected to move spatially so as to substitute high-value for low-value crops and in response to comparative advantages? It is easy to suggest that water should be applied where it will yield the largest net returns, but difficult to achieve this under legal and ownership constraints. Can land be expected to substitute for water as water prices increase? Is there social justification for attempting to stem or reverse the trends in "dying communities" where irrigation abandonment accelerates the outward flow of people and reduces net income, leading to local trauma? Is there need to institute some kind of regional market for water to expedite transfers? Or is the present system working well enough? As agricultural interests occupy a relatively smaller share of western population and income, will their political power wane?
What is likely to be the effect of the drive for assertion of federal reserved rights? Would this restrict reallocations?
― 481 ― What would be the consequences of further recognition of Indian water rights? Some observers think this would change the picture radically. To what extent would a program for selected removal of phreatophytes as a means of saving water be consistent with the maintenance of aquatic or riparian ecosystems? Does any state now have sufficient statutory authority and executive capability to facilitate a flexible management of water development and water reallocations to serve the public interest? Is the presently decreasing role of the federal government in water development likely to promote or retard the economic and political adjustments necessary to cope with reduced water?
Policies and Programs Although the appropriate direction of existing and possible new public policies is touched upon at a number of points, there is little clear agreement as to their desirability and priority. No single coherent program for action emerges. A few lines of action are stressed. Water rights should be refined and streamlined so that it will be practicable to transfer water to other users, where questions of the identity and quantity of the right and of the power to transfer are impediments. Statutes affecting groundwater depletion and pollution are regarded as especially archaic, and changes in them are in progress. Quite aside from the quantification of property rights, the reserved public and Indian rights need to be clarified. The data base on several fundamental parameters needs improvement: extent of irrigated land and salination rates are examples. Research is called for on a number of the topics noted as in doubt or disagreement. But some of the differences are judgmental and will be resolved only in the political arena as positions harden on issues of policy. The ambiguity and indecision characterizing much of the current federal government policy does not advance the resolution of these questions.
Underlying Issues Underlying much of the analytical discussion are five issues that occur in varying degrees of severity among the basins of the semiarid West. They are not addressed explicitly in most of the papers, but are approached implicitly or tangentially at many points. These are the questions of territorial identity, uncertainty, market and public action, emphasis on development or
― 482 ― management for conservation, and the roles of crisis and education. Throughout the semiarid West the disposition is strong to claim and develop water within the political jurisdictions of its origin. Officers of the state of Montana thinking about the waters of the Missouri Basin want the state to "use it or lose it." Representatives of the lower Missouri Basin states object to South Dakota diverting slurry water from the river even temporarily, because of rights they feel they have to its flow. Citizens of Colorado press to utilize waters of the Arkansas, Colorado, and Platte rivers to the full limit of their rights, so that it will not be diverted by downstream users. New Mexico doesn't want El Paso to transport groundwater across its border, nor does Nebraska approve of a farmer pumping from a Nebraska well to a Colorado field. Northern Californians seek to foreclose any further movement of water to the south. These upstream-downstream and trans-basin contentions occur between states and within states, and their existence colors any discussion of water transfer or water use efficiency. These political realities constrain the physical and economic situations, and in some instances they render moot calculations of economic efficiency. With water, as with most resource management, uncertainty has a large influence upon the mode of technical analysis and the choice of suitable public policy. It reminds us that the course of events could proceed quite differently than projections or scenarios anticipate. That recognition leads people to espouse prudent "minimax" strategies. Consider some of the events that might change the outlook for water in the western states within a short period of time. A very severe drought—as severe as in the 13th century—might persist for a dozen years: that could alter the perception of water availability. An announcement by internationally recognized scientific authorities that we were beginning a period of long-term climate change could trigger a frenetic reexamination of what constitutes a reliable limited supply: this might come before the end of the 1980s, or 2000 might find us still engaged in speculation. A marked decline in foreign markets for agricultural produce could alter the competitive position of western farmers. A continued drastic tilt of the national budget toward unproductive defense expenditures could raise the cost of capital and induce economic distress greater than anything experienced since the 1930s.
Any one of these or other events not appearing in the conventional projections could turn around the views of the water
― 483 ― future prevailing in this volume. Uneasiness about such trends lends support to the caution of some water administrators and users that additional storage should be provided in the near future to buffer possible later disruptions. In a broader sense it speaks for assuring a large latitude of flexibility in institutional arrangements so that they may be modified in the future as physical and social conditions change. A third issue relates to the weight given to market mechanisms in contrast to government regulation in response to community needs. We shall never have this fully resolved. Several chapters in this volume support a market allocation of water rights, subject in varying ways to consideration of the effects of private water use on land use, aquatic ecosystems, soil productivity, and the rights of others. The trend is toward greater reliance on the marketplace, but there is doubt as to its sensitivity to these effects, and as to its practicability in view of entrenched legal and administrative institutions and the societies they reflect. A fourth issue that applies to the country as a whole as well as other nations, but particularly to the semiarid West, is represented in the shifting of public emphasis from water development to water management for conservation. The federal and state agencies array themselves at different points along the spectrum, with the trend toward conservation. No big new projects are anticipated. No primarily federal financing is expected. In contrast to debates about Congressional appropriations and federal-state administrative roles, the question becomes how more sophisticated management, with only partial emphasis on development, at the level of substate areas may achieve efficient and equitable water use. The final issue concerns the speed and timing of action to bring about the revisions in policies and programs noted above as desirable. An observer would have a hard job on the basis of evidence in this volume asserting that there is a real and emerging water crisis in the semiarid West. It appears possible to satisfy other emerging needs and still preserve a viable irrigation agriculture serving the region and the nation. Skeptics nevertheless ask whether there will be adequate action along the lines seen as most needed and suitable at the present time unless a crisis situation is foreseen. We are, they say, a short-sighted, greedy society that will respond only to the threat of impending disaster. Until that is perceived as imminent, we will progressively worsen our situation without having made the kinds of adjustments in
― 484 ― systems of incentives, regulations, and educational and technical assistance to deal with the problems emerging today. This is a special challenge to those sharing the motivating concern of this volume. In modifying its methods of coping with resource scarcity, our society has not always responded solely to crisis. Droughts and floods can trigger rapid change, but society also sometimes responds to sane judgments slowly built up through consensus and regional conflict as to investment, administrative, and research priorities. The evidence suggests a problem that could be serious in local areas in terms of the livelihood, sense of identity, and direction of local groups, and it points up the need for continuing readjustment of institutions and policies to facilitate socially beneficial reallocation of supplies. Analysts see a worsening of conditions if appropriate actions are not taken. For the moment, we cannot rely upon a cry of crisis to make it easier for localities to work together, to reallocate rights, to speed up conservation measures, and to take other actions that seem to be indicated. Thereby, the response is more difficult than would be the case if disaster were looming just over the horizon. It calls for persistence, patience, and long-time education supported by research and technical assistance. It requires a new rhetoric in appealing to those concerned. Reliance cannot be placed on the forecast of a great climate change or the early running out of reserves. Education, technical assistance, and supporting research need to be brought to bear on the resolution of subregional and local problems, and steps in that direction need sustained and imaginative support. Unless our society continues to meet that challenge in a sober, careful way, we may expect worsening of the situation of irrigation agriculture in a few parts of the semiarid West.
― 485 ―
Notes Chapter 1— Physical Limitations of Water Resources 1. N.C. Matalas, J.M. Landwehr and M.G. Wolman, Prediction in Water Management, in Scientific Basis of Water-Resources Management: Studies in Geophysics, National Academy of Science, Washington, D.C., 1982, pp. 118127.
2. U.S. Water Resources Council, The Nation's Water Resources, 1975-2000: The Second National Water Assessment, (Washington, D.C., GPO, 1978) Vol. 1, Summary, p. 86. 3. C.W. Stockton and G.C. Jacoby, Jr., Long-Term Surface-Water Supply and Streamflow Trends in the Upper Colorado River Basin based on Tree-Ring Analysis, Lake Powell Res. Project Bulletin, No. 18, 1976, p. 70. 4. W.B. Langbein, Dams, Reservoirs and Withdrawals for Water Supply— Historic Trends, Open-file Report 82-256, U.S. Geological Survey, 1982, p. 9. 5. L.F. Konikow and J.D. Bredehoeft, "A Water Quality Model to Evaluate Water Management Practices in an Irrigated Stream-Aquifer System," in Salinity in Water Resources, J.E. Flack and C.W. Howe, editors (Boulder, Colorado: Merriman, 1974), pp. 36-59. 6. A.F. Pillsbury, "The Salinity of Rivers," Scientific American, 1981, pp. 5565. 7. N.K. Whittlesey and K.C. Gibbs, "Energy and Irrigation in Washington," Western Journal of Agricultural Economics, 3 (1978): 1, 1-9. 1. H.C. Fritts, Tree Rings and Climate, London: Academic Press, 1976. 1. H.C. Fritts, Tree Rings and Climate, London: Academic Press, 1976. 2. G.A. Gordon, "Verification of Dendroclimatic Reconstructions," in Climate from Tree Rings, M.K. Hughes, P.M. Kelly, J.R. Pilcher, and V.C. LaMarche Jr., eds., (Cambridge, England: Cambridge University Press, 1982), pp. 5861. 3. H.C. Fritts and G.A. Gordon, "Reconstructed Annual Precipitation for California," in Climate from Tree Rings, op. cit., pp. 185-91. 4. H.C. Fritts, Reconstructing North American Climate from Tree Rings: A Diagnostic Analysis (London: Academic Press, in preparation). 4. H.C. Fritts, Reconstructing North American Climate from Tree Rings: A Diagnostic Analysis (London: Academic Press, in preparation). 5. D.M. Ludlum, Early American Winters: Vol. 1, 1604-1820 and Vol. 2, 1821-1870. (Boston: AMS, 1966).
6. C.W. Stockton and D.M. Meko, "Drought Recurrence in the Great Plains as Reconstructed from Long-Term Tree-Ring Records," Journal of Climate and Applied Meteorology, in press, 1983. 7. C.W. Stockton and W.R. Boggess, "Geohydrological Implications of Climate Change on Water Resource Development," prepared for the U.S. Army Coastal Engineering Research Center, Fort Belvoir, Virginia, 1979. 8. National Defense University, "Climate Change to the Year 2000—A Survey of Expert Opinion," Defense Documentation Center, Alexandria, Virginia, 1978.
Chapter 2— Legal-Institutional Limitations on Water Use 1. For a history of U.S. irrigation, see Lawrence B. Lee, Reclaiming the American West (Santa Barbara, CA: ABC-Clio Press, 1980). 2. See, generally, Michael C. Nelson, The Winters Doctrine: Seventy Years of Application of 'Reserved' Water Rights to Indian Reservations (Tucson, AZ: University of Arizona, Office of Arid Lands Studies, 1977). 3. A fuller discussion of the material in this section can be found in Gary D. Weatherford and Gordon Jacoby, "Impact of Energy Development on the Law of the Colorado River," 15 Natural Resources Journal 171, 174-81 (January 1975). 4. The material in this section is drawn selectively from Gary Weatherford (ed.) et al., Acquiring Water for Energy: Institutional Aspects (Littleton, CO: Water Resources Publications, 1982), pp. 29-42. 5. The emergence of water markets in western irrigation states is analyzed by Lee Brown et al., "Water Reallocation, Market Proficiency, and Conflicting Social Values," in Gary Weatherford (ed.) et al., Water and Agriculture in the Western U.S.: Conservation, Reallocation and Markets (Boulder, CO: Westview Press, 1982), pp. 191-265. 6. Persons whose income depends on a continuance of agricultural production—such as farm implement dealers, feed and fertilizer suppliers and farm laborers—normally have no involvement in a farmer's decision to sell his water rights and quit farming. Water markets therefore pose equity issues. See, generally, ibid. break 7. Some of the material in this section is drawn from Gary Weatherford (ed.) et al., Acquiring Water for Energy: Institutional Aspects (Littleton, CO: Water Resources Publications, 1982), pp. 97-113.
8. For an interesting preview of rising pumping costs, see R. Schafer, "San Joaquin Valley Groundwater Pumping Costs," paper for conference of Association of California Water Agencies, November 1981, Pacific Grove, CA. 9. Dean E. Mann, "Political Incentives in U.S. Water Policy: Relationships between Distributive and Regulatory Politics," in What Government Does, eds. Matthew Holden, Jr. and Dennis L. Dresang, Volume I, Sage Yearbooks in Politics and Public Policy (Beverly Hills: Sage Publications, 1975). 10. Owen Stratton and Phillip Sirotkin, The Echo Park Controversy (University of Alabama: University of Alabama Press, 1959). 11. Dean Schooler and Helen Ingram, "Water Resource Management," in Public Studies Review, Vol. 1, No. 2 (Lawrence, Kansas: University of Kansas Center for Public Affairs, November 1981). 12. U.S. v. New Mexico, 438 U.S. 699 (1978). 13. California v. U.S., 438 U.S. 645 (1978). 14. Kenneth Rubin, "The Capacity of States to Manage Water Resources Given a Decreased Federal Role," prepared for the Symposium on Unified River Basin Management, Stage II, October 6, 1981. 15. Mont. Code Ann., Sec. 51-4-5, Suppl, 1978. 16. Henry P. Caulfield, Jr., "U.S. Water Resources Policy: Past, Present and Future," prepared for the Western Political Science Association Annual Meeting, San Diego, California, March 25, 1982. 17. Ibid. 16. Henry P. Caulfield, Jr., "U.S. Water Resources Policy: Past, Present and Future," prepared for the Western Political Science Association Annual Meeting, San Diego, California, March 25, 1982. 17. Ibid. 18. Ariz. Rev. Stat., Sec. 45-513 (1980). 19. Kenneth D. Frederick, "The Future Role of Western Irrigation," in The Southwestern Rev. of Management and Economics 19 (Spring 1981).
20. Ibid. 19. Kenneth D. Frederick, "The Future Role of Western Irrigation," in The Southwestern Rev. of Management and Economics 19 (Spring 1981). 20. Ibid. 21. Helen Ingram, William E. Martin, and Nancy K. Laney, "A Willingness to Play: Analysis of Water Resources Development in Arizona," in Gary D. Weatherford (ed.) et al., Water and Agriculture in the Western U.S.: Conservation, Reallocation, and Markets (Boulder, CO: Westview Press, 1982). 22. Helen Ingram, Nancy Laney, and John R. McCain, A Policy Approach to Political Representation: Lessons from the Four-Corners States (Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press for Resources for the Future, 1980). 23. Behavior Research Center, Consumer Division, Salt River Project Customer Attitude Survey (Report to Management), June 1977. 24. Henry P. Caulfield, Jr., supra, note 16. 25. Dale E. Pontius, "Groundwater Management in Arizona: A New Set of Rules," Arizona Bar Journal October 1980, pp. 28-52. 26. See Sporhase v. State of Nebraska, No. 81-613, U.S. Supreme Court, decided July 2, 1982 (October Term, 1981); also, City of El Paso v. Reynolds, Civil No. 80-730-HB, U.S. Dist. Court, Dist. of New Mexico, pending. 27. Henry P. Caulfield, supra, note 16. break 1. Testimony of Wesley Steiner, Director of the Arizona Department of Water Resources, before the Special Master in Arizona v. California, September 19, 1980. 2. Merrion v. Jicarilla Apache Tribe, 455 U.S. 130, 102 S.Ct. 894 (1982). break 3. Town of Chino Valley v. City of Prescott, 131 Ariz. 78, 638 P.2d 1324 (1981); Cherry v. Steiner, CIV-81-719, July 21, 1982. 4. Howard v. Perrin, 8 Ariz. 347, 76 P.460 (1904); Maricopa County Mun. Water Conservation Dist. No. 1 v. Southwest Cotton Co., 39 Ariz. 65, 4 P.2d
369 (1931), aff'd on rehearing, 39 Ariz. 367, 7 P.2d 254 (1932); Bristor v. Cheatham, 75 Ariz. 227, 255 P.2d 173 (1953); Jarvis v. State Land Dep't., 104 Ariz. 527, 456 P.2d 385 (1969); Jarvis v. State Land Dep't., 106 Ariz. 506, 479 P.2d 169 (1970); Neal v. Hunt, 11 Ariz. 307, 541 P.2d 559 (1975); Jarvis v. State Land Dep't., 113 Ariz. 230, 550 P.2d 227 (1976); Farmers Inv. Co. v. Bettwy, 133 Ariz. 520, 558 P.2d 14 (1976); Town of Chino Valley v. State Land Dep't., 119 Ariz. 243, 580 P.2d 704 (1978). 5. Four minor corrections to specific statements of the paper are suggested. First, when the Central Arizona Project begins delivering water in three or four years, most of the use reductions in California will be municipal (estimated reduction in Metropolitan Water District diversions of Colorado River water is 55 percent), not irrigation. Second, though state water laws provide the fabric for allocation of most water, they do not, of course, affect allocation of water such as the Colorado River Lower Basin rights, which, under the Boulder Canyon Project Act, 43 U.S.C. §§ 617-617t (1928) and Arizona v. California, 373 U.S. 546, 575-90 (1963), are determined by the Secretary of Interior. Third, this writer disputes the historical accuracy of the statement that two dams on the Colorado River were defeated on both economic and environmental grounds—they were defeated on environmental grounds. Finally, in the section on State Laws of Surface Water, it might be useful to note the extent to which "instream uses" have been recognized. The concept was dealt a significant set-back in U.S. v. New Mexico, 438 U.S. 696, 98 S.Ct. 3012 (1978). 6. For a discussion of the political forces that shaped the Arizona Act, Ariz. Rev. State. Ann. §§ 45-401 to 636 (Supp. 1981-82), see Kyl, "The 1980 Arizona Groundwater Management Act: From Inception to Current Constitutional Challenge," 53 Colorado Law Review, 471 (1982).
Chapter 3— Competition for Water 1. U.S. Water Resources Council, The Nation's Water Resources, 1975-2000: The Second National Water Assessment (Washington, D.C., GPO, 1978), Vol. 1, Summary, p. 18. 2. Calculated from data in the following U.S. Geological Survey circulars: 1950 data—Kenneth A. MacKichan, Estimated Use of Water in the United States in 1950, Circular 115 (Washington, D.C., May 1951); 1960 data— Kenneth A. MacKichan and J.C. Kammerer, Estimated Use of Water in the United States in 1960, Circular 456 (Washington, D.C., 1961); 1970 data—
C. Richard Murray and E. Bodette Reeves, Estimated Use of Water in the United States in 1970, Circular 676 (Washington, D.C., 1974). The 1980 data are based on preliminary copies (provided by Ken Reid, U.S.G.S. hydrologist) of Tables 7 and 10 of the forthcoming U.S. Geological Survey Circular on "Estimated Use of Water in the United States in 1980." The references are to water withdrawals (the amount of water taken from a surface or groundwater source for offstream use) rather than consumption (the portion of the water withdrawn which is not returned to a surface or groundwater source) since consumption data are not available for 1950. Subsequent references to water use will be limited to periods since 1960 and will focus on water consumption. 3. The range of estimates of irrigated acreage is wide. The data are examined critically in Kenneth D. Frederick, Water for Western Agriculture (Washington, D.C., Resources for the Future, 1982), Appendix II-A. Fifty million acres is a reasonable estimate of irrigated acreage in the seventeen western states in the late 1970s. 4. Calculated from data in the U.S. Geological Survey circulars on the estimated use of water in the United States. 5. Kenneth D. Frederick, Water for Western Agriculture (Washington, D.C., Resources for the Future, 1982), pp. 71-72. break 6. U.S. Water Resources Council, The Nation's Water Resources 1975-2000, Vol. 3, Appendix I, p. 8. 7. The Assessment data are for water resource regions and subregions. The data relating to water use and the underlying socioeconomic factors have been converted to state boundaries in Oak Ridge National Laboratory, State Water Use and Socioeconomic Data Related to the Second National Water Assessment, prepared for the U.S. Water Resources Council (Oak Ridge, Tenn., 1980). 8. Aerospace Corporation, Water Related Constraints on Energy Production, Aerospace Report No. ATR-78(9409)-1 (Germantown, Md., Aerospace Corporation, June 1978). 9. The seven subregions are Lahontan-South (1807) and Southern California (1806) in the California Region, Humboldt-Tonopah Desert (1603) and Central Lahontan (1604) in the Great Basin Region, Middle Rio Grande (1302) in the Rio Grande Region, and Brazos (1203) and Colorado (1204) in the Texas Gulf Region. 10. U.S. Water Resources Council, The Nation's Water Resources: The Second National Water Assessment, Vol. 3, Appendix 1, Tables 1-4.
11. The nine subregions are Western Dakotas (1005), Middle Missouri (1009), and Lower Missouri (1011) of the Missouri Region, Upper White (1101), Yellowstone (1004), North and South Platte (1007) of the ArkansasWhite-Red Region, Sabine-Neches (1201) and Nueces-Texas Coastal (1205) of the Texas-Gulf Region, and Green-White-Yampa (1401) of the Upper Colorado Region. 12. U.S. Water Resources Council, The Nation's Water Resources 19752000, Vol. 3, Appendix 1, p. 1. 13. U.S. Bureau of Census, Statistical Abstract of the United States (Washington, D.C., GPO, 1980). 14. For a detailed examination of the irrigation data problems, see Frederick, Water for Western Agriculture, Appendix 2-A. 15. U.S. Department of Agriculture, Soil Conservation Service, "Basic Statistics—1977 National Resources Inventory (NRI)," revised February 1980, in mimeograph. 16. This material is adapted from Allen V. Kneese and F. Lee Brown, The Southwest Region Under Stress: National Resource Development Issues in a Regional Setting (Baltimore, Johns Hopkins University Press for Resources for the Future, 1981). The original paper reporting the analysis is Thomas Maddock III and N. C. Matalas, "The Potential Impacts of Energy Development on Water Resources in the Yampa River Basin" in Walter O. Spofford, Jr., Alfred L. Parker, and Allen V. Kneese, eds., Energy Development in the Southwest: Problems of Water, Fish, and Wildlife in the Upper Colorado River Basin (Washington, D.C., Resources for the Future, 1980). 17. These conclusions draw on research by the authors reported in ibid., and Frederick, Water for Western Agriculture, as well as the analysis in this paper. 18. High Plains Associates, Six-State High Plains Ogallala Aquifer Regional Resources Study (a report to the U.S. Department of Commerce and the High Plains Study Council, March 1982), pp. A-17-24. break 1. David E. Burmaster, "The New Pollution—Groundwater Contamination," Environment, Vol. 24, March 1982, pp. 6-36. break
Chapter 4— Developing New Water Supplies 1. William G. Dunn, "Summary of Reports on Possible Water Import Plans from Canada," Woodside, California, June 1980 (unpublished paper). Also,
"The Rocky Mountain Plan," ASCE National Convention, Dallas, Texas, April 27, 1977. 2. Roland P. Kelly, NAWAPA Plan Can Work, Energy Report, National Energy Research and Information Institute, La Verne, California, June/July 1982. 3. Lewis Gordy Smith, Western States Water Augmentation Concept, Federation of Rocky Mountain States, Inc., Denver, Colorado, Monograph, 1967. 4. Joel Schwarz, "California Lifeline—A History of the State Water Project," Aqueduct, Vol. 48:2, Sacramento, California, 1982. 5. U.S. Army Corps of Engineers, Water Transfer Elements of High Plains Ogallala Aquifer Study, Dallas, Texas, January 1982. 6. Mississippi River Commission, West Texas and Eastern New Mexico Water Impact Study, Vicksburg, Miss., October 1973. break 7. Homer E. Newell, A Recommended National Program in Weather Modification, Federal Council for Science and Technology, Interdepartmental Committee for Atmospheric Sciences, Washington, D.C., 1976.
Chapter 5— Increasing Efficiency of Nonagricultural Water Use 1. H.J. Graeser, "Water Reuse: Resource of the Future," Journal of the American Water Works Association, Vol. 66, No. 10 (October 1974), pp. 575578. 2. J.G. Milliken and G.C. Taylor, Metropolitan Water Management, Water Resources Monograph Series #6, American Geophysical Union, Washington, D.C., 1981, p. 180. 3. J.N. English, E.R. Bennett, and K.D. Linstedt, "Research Required to Establish Confidence in the Potable Reuse of Wastewater," Journal of the American Water Works Association, Vol. 69, No. 3 (March 1977), pp. 131136. 4. C.J. Schmidt, I. Rugelman, and E.V. Clements III, "Municipal Reuse in the U.S.," Journal of the Water Pollution Control Federation, Vol. 47, No. 9 (September 1975), pp. 2229-2245. 5. W.J. Phillips, "The Direct Reuse of Reclaimed Wastewater: Pros, Cons and
Alternatives," Journal of the American Water Works Association, Vol. 66, No. 4 (April 1974), pp. 231-237. 6. A.W. Reinhardt, D.P. Spath, and W.F. Jopling, "Organics, Water and Health: A Reuse Problem," Journal of the American Water Works Association, Vol. 67, No. 9 (September 1975), pp. 477-480. 7. A.D. Pagorski, "Is the Public Ready for Recycled Water?" Water and Sewage Works, Vol. 121, No. 6 (June 1974), p. 108. 8. W.H. Bruvold, and H.J. Ongerth, "Public Use and Evaluation of Reclaimed Water," Journal of the American Water Works Association, Vol. 66, No. 5 (May 1974), pp. 294-297. break 9. R.L. Carley, "Wastewater Reuse and Public Opinion," Master of Science thesis, University of Colorado, Boulder, 1972, 121 pages. 10. Gallup Poll, "Water Quality and Public Opinion," Journal of the American Water Works Association, Vol. 67, No. 8 (August 1973), pp. 513-519. 11. J.H. Sims, and D.D. Baumann, "Renovated Waste Water: The Question of Public Acceptance." Water Resources Research, Vol. 10, No. 4, p. 659. 12. J.J. Greenberg, "Public Receptivity Toward Water Conservation in Northern Colorado Communities," Master of Science thesis, University of Colorado, Boulder, 1981, 127 pages. 13. J.R. Bailey, R.J. Benoit, J.L. Donson, J.M. Robb, and H. Wallman, A Study of Flow Reduction and Treatment of Waste Water from Households, Cincinnati, Ohio, December 1969. U.S. Government Printing Office, NTIS PB 197 599. 14. K. Ligman, N. Huzler, and W.C. Boyler, "Household Wastewater Characterization," Journal of the Environmental Engineering Division, American Society of Civil Engineers, Vol. 100, No. EE1 (February 1974), p. 201. 15. M. Milne, Residential Water Conservation, Report No. 35, Water Resources Center, University of California at Davis, CA, 1976. 16. E.R. McLaughlin, "A Recycle System for Conservation of Water in Residences," Proceedings, Conference on Water Conservation and Sewage Flow Reduction with Water Saving Devices, Pennsylvania State University, PB 250 999, OWRT, 1975, pp. 133-141.
17. Bailey, op. cit. 18. S. Cohen and H. Wallman, Demonstration of Waste Flow Reduction from Households, Environmental Protection Agency, 670/2-74-071 (September 1974), Cincinnati, Ohio. 19. P.D. Haney and C.L. Hamann, "Dual Water Systems," Journal of the American Water Works Association, Vol. 57, No. 9 (1976), p. 1073. 20. A.K. Deb and M.J. Ives, "Dual Water Supply," Paper presented at Second Annual Conference on Research, Development, and Design, Environmental Engineering Division, American Society of Civil Engineers, Gainesville, Florida, July 21-23, 1975. 21. J.R. DeLapp, "Water Reuse with a Dual Distribution System," Master of Science thesis, University of Colorado, Boulder, 1973. 22. National Water Commission, Water Policies for the Future, U.S. Government Printing Office, Washington, D.C., June 1973. 23. J.E. Flack, Urban Water Conservation, American Society of Civil Engineers, New York, NY, 1982, 99 pages. 15. M. Milne, Residential Water Conservation, Report No. 35, Water Resources Center, University of California at Davis, CA, 1976. 24. C.W. Howe and F.P. Linaweaver, Jr., "The Impact of Price on Residential Water Demand and Its Relation to System Design and Price Structure," Water Resources Research, Vol. 3, No. 1 (1967), p. 13. 25. D.R.J. Burns, J.H. Gerstle, O.J. Roussos, M.K. Whitaker, and R. Wemple, "The Effect of Price on Residential Water Demand," Econ. 691/CE539, University of Colorado (Fall Semester 1975), typewritten. 26. S.H. Hanke and A. Mehrz, "The Relationship Between Water Use Restrictions and Water Use," Water Supply and Management, Vol. 2 (Pergamon Press, 1979), pp. 001-007. break
Chapter 6— Coping with Salinity 1. Jewell Meyer, Extension Specialist, UC Riverside, estimates that 800,000 acre-feet/yr out of a total of 3,100,000 acre-feet of sewage plant effluent currently is reused in California.
2. I. Szabolcs, European Solonetz Soils and their Reclamation, Akademia Kiado, Budapest, 1971. 3. J. Shalhevet and J. Kamburov, Irrigation and Salinity: A WorldWide Survey, Int'l Commission on Irrigation and Drainage, 1976. 4. The estimates that are repeatedly found in the literature can almost always be traced to an estimate made many years ago at this Laboratory; it was based on an informal inquiry among colleagues. break 5. M.T. Kaddah and J.D. Rhoades, "Salt and Water Balance in Imperial Valley, California," Soil. Sci. Soc. Amer. J, 1976, 40:93-100. 6. E.V. Maas and G.J. Hoffman, "Crop Salt Tolerance—Current Assessment," J. Irrig. and Drainage Div., ASCE, 1977, 103(IR2):115-134. 7. J. van Schifgaarde, "The Wellton-Mohawk Dilemma," Int'l J. of Water Supply and Mgmt., 1982, 6:115-127. 8. U.S. Bureau of Reclamation, "Saline Water Use and Disposal Opportunities," Special Report, Colorado River Water Quality Improvement Program, 1981. 9. U.S. Bureau of Reclamation, "Palo Verde Irrigation District Unit and Colorado River Indian Reservation Unit—Status Report (Preliminary)," Colorado River Water Quality Improvement Program, 1978. 10. U.S. Bureau of Reclamation, "Stage One Development—Grand Valley Unit," Special Report, Colorado River Basin Salinity Control Project, 1979. 11. Alan P. Kleinman and F. Bruce Brown, "Colorado River Salinity: Economic Impacts on Agriculture, Municipal, and Industrial Users," Water and Power Resources Service, Denver, Colorado, 1980. 12. J.D. Rhoades, J.D. Oster, R.D. Ingvalsen, J.M. Tucker, and M. Clark, "Minimizing the Salt Burdens of Irrigation Drainage Waters," J. Environ. Qual., 1974, 3:311-316; J. van Schilfgaarde, L. Bernstein, J.D. Rhoades, and S.L. Rawlins, "Irrigation Management for Salt Control," J. Irrig. and Drainage Div., ASCE, 1974, 100(IR3):321-338. 13. J.D. Rhoades, and D.L. Suarez, "Reducing Water Quality Degradation Through Minimized Leaching Management," Agric. Water Manage., 1977, 1(2):127-142.
14. D.L. Suarez and M.Th. van Genuchten, "Leaching and Water-type Effects on Groundwater Quality," J. Irrig. and Drainage Div., ASCE, 1977, 107(IR1):35-52. 15. W.A. Jury, H. Frenkel, D. Devitt, and L.H. Stolzy, "Transient Changes in the Soil-water System from Irrigation with Saline Water: II. Analysis of Experimental Data," Soil Sci. Soc. Amer. J., 1978, 42:585-590. 16. D. Yaron, E. Bresler, and H. Bielorai, "A Model for Optimal Irrigation Scheduling with Saline Water," Water Resour. Res., 1980, 16:257-262. 17. Rhoades and Suarez, 1977, op. cit. (note 13.) 18. J.D. Rhoades, "Salinity Management and Monitoring," Proc., 12th Biennial Conf. on Ground Water, Sacramento, California, Sept. 1979. Water Resources Center #45:73-87; J.D. Rhoades and D.L. Corwin, "Determining Soil Electrical Conductivity-Depth Relations Using an Inductive Electromagnetic Soil Conductivity Meter," Soil Sci. Soc. Amer. J., 1981, 45:255-260. 19. U.S. Bureau of Reclamation, California Department of Water Resources, and California State Water Resources Control Board, "Agricultural Drainage and Salt Management in the San Joaquin Valley," San Joaquin Valley Interagency Drainage Program, Final Report, 1979. 20. J.D. Rhoades, "Potential for Using Saline Agricultural Drainage Waters for Irrigation," Proc., Water Mgmt. for Irrigation and Drainage, ASCE, Reno, Nevada, July 1977, pp. 85-116. 21. H. Boyko, "Saltwater Agriculture," Scientific American, 1967, 26(3):8996; E. Epstein and J.D. Norlyn, "Seawater-based Crop Production: A Feasibility Study," Science, 1977, 197:249-251. break 22. M.B. Bessler, "The Use of Saline Water for Irrigation in the U.S.S.R.," Final Report—U.S.-U.S.S.R. Joint Commission on Scientific and Technical Cooperation-Water Resources, 1979. See esp. p. 111. 23. K.V. Paliwal, "Irrigation with Saline Water," Water Technology Centre, Indian Agricultural Research Institute, New Delhi, 1972. 24. Shalhevet and Kamburov, 1976, op. cit. (note 3.) 25. R.D. Dhir, "Investigations into Use of Highly Saline Waters in an Arid Environment. I. Salinity and Alkali Hazard Conditions in Soil under a Cyclic Management System," Proc., Int'l Salinity Conf. on Managing Saline Water
for Irrigation, Texas Tech. Univ., Lubbock, Texas, August 1976, pp. 608-609. 26. Hardan, A. 1977, "Irrigation with Saline Water under Desert Conditions," Proc., Int'l Salinity Conf. on "Managing Saline Water for Irrigation," Texas Tech. Univ., Lubbock, Texas, August 1976, pp. 165-169. 27. H. Frenkel and I. Shainberg, "Irrigation with Brackish Water: Chemical and Hydraulic Changes in Soils Irrigated with Brackish Water under Cotton Production," Irrigation with Brackish Water, Int'l Symp., Beer Sheva, Israel, The Negev University Press, 1975, pp. 175-183. 28. R. Keren and I. Shainberg, "Irrigation with Sodic and Brackish Water and Its Effect on the Soil and on Cotton Fields," Hassade, 1978, 58:963-976. 29. D.L. Miles, "Salinity in the Arkansas Valley of Colorado," InterAgency Agreement Report EPA-IAG-D4-0544, 1977. 30. J. Moore and J.J. Hefner, "Irrigation with Saline Water in the Pecos Valley of West Texas," Proc., Int'l Salinity Conf. on Managing Saline Water for Irrigation, Texas Tech. Univ., Lubbock, Texas, August 1976, pp. 339-344. 31. W.A. Jury, H. Frenkel, H. Fluhler, D. Devitt, and L.H. Stolzy, "Use of Saline Irrigation Waters and Minimal Leaching for Crop Production," Hilgardia, 1978, 46(5):169-192. 32. A.D. Ayers, J.W. Brown, and C.H. Wadleigh, "Salt Tolerance of Barley and Wheat in Soil Plots Receiving Salinization Regimes," Agron J., 1952, 44:307-310. 33. J.D. Rhoades, S.L. Rawlins, and C.J. Phene, "Irrigation of Cotton with Saline Drainage Water," ASCE Conf. and Exposition, Portland, Oregon, April 1980, Preprint 80-119. 34. Joseph V. Hunter and Theresa Kotlayk, "Chemical and Biological Quality of Sewage Effluents," in Sopper, W.E. and L.T. Kardos (eds.), Conference on Recycling Treated Municipal Wastewater through Forest and Cropland, Environmental Protection Agency EPA, 1974, 660/Z-74-003; Richard Thomas and James P. Law, "Properties of Waste Water," in Eliott, L.F. and J.F. Stevenson (eds.), Soils for Management of Organic Wastes and Wastewaters, American Soc. of Agron., Madison, Wisconsin, 1977, pp. 4772. 35. Robert S. Ayers and Kenneth K. Tanji, "Agronomic Aspects of Crop Production with Wastewater," in Proc. ASCE Specialty Conference Water Forum '81, American Society of Civil Engineers, New York, 1981, pp. 578586.
36. A. Wallace, P.M. Patel, W.L. Berry, and O.R. Lunt, "Reclaimed Sewage Water: A Hydroponic Growth Medium for Plants," Resource Recovery and Conservation, 1978, 3:191-194. break 37. L. Kardos, T., C.E. Scarsbrook, and V.V. Volk, "Recycling Elements in Wastes through Soil-plant Systems," in Eliott, L.F. and J.F. Stevenson (eds.), Soils for Management of Organic Wastes and Wastewaters, American Society of Agronomy, Madison, Wisconsin, 1977, pp. 301-324; Herman Bouwer, R.C. Rice, T.C. Lance, and R.G. Gilbert, "Rapid Infiltration Research at Flushing Meadows Project, Arizona," J. Water Poll., Control Fed., 1980, 52:24572470; A.R. Overman and W.G. Leseman, "Soil and Groundwater Changes under Land Treatment of Wastewater," Trans. ASAE, 1982, 25(2):381-387. 38. A.D. Day, J.A. McFadyen, T.C. Tucker, and C.B. Cliff, "Effect of Municipal Wastewater on the Yield and Quality of Cotton," J. Environ. Qual., 1981, 10:47-49; A. Feign, H. Bielorai, Y. Dag, T. Kipnis, and M. Giskin, "The Nitrogen Factor in the Management of Effluent-Irrigated Soils," Soil Sci., 1981, 125:248-254; Boyle Engineering Corporation, "Evaluation of Agricultural Irrigation Projects using Reclaimed Water," Report for Office of Water Recycling, California State Water Resources Control Board, Sacramento, California, 1981. 39. Thomas and Law, 1972, op. cit. (note 34.) 40. Ayers and Tanji, 1981, op. cit. (note 35.) 41. Dwight Baier and Wilton B. Fryer, "Undesirable Plant Responses with Sewage Irrigation," J. Irrig. and Drainage Div., ASCE, 1973, 99(IR2):133141; Herman Bouwer and R.L. Chaney, "Land Treatment of Wastewater," Adv. in Agron., 1974, 26:133-141; Feign et al., 1978, op. cit.; Day et al., 1981, op. cit. (note 38.) 42. Feign et al., 1978, op. cit. (note 38.) 43. Boyle Engineering Corporation, 1981, op. cit. (note 38.) 44. Kurt L. Wassermann, James Crook and Robert P. Ghireli, "Health Aspects of Agricultural Irrigation with Reclaimed Municipal Wastewater," in Proc. ASCE Specialty Conference Water Forum '81. American Society of Civil Engineers, New York, 1981, pp. 587-595; J.C. Lance and Herman Bouwer, "Environmental Aspects of Irrigation with Sewage," in Proc. ASCE Specialty Conference Water Forum '81, American Society of Civil Engineers, New York, 1981, pp. 598-605; Perry L. McCarty, Paul V. Roberts and Edward J. Bouwer, "Transport and Fate of Organic Contaminants in Soils," in Proc. ASCE Specialty Conference Water Forum '81, American Society of Civil Engineers, New York, 1981, pp. 606-615; M. El-Nennah, T. El-Kobbia, A. Shehata and I. El-Gamal, "Effect of Irrigating Loamy Sand Soil by Sewage Effluents on its
Content of Some Nutrients and Heavy Metals," Plant and Soil, 1982, 65:289292. 45. T.G. Bahr, "Saline Water Resources and Future Development in New Mexico," Proc., Int'l Conf. Salinity and Water Management Technology, Texas A&M Research Center, El Paso, Texas, Dec. 13-14, 1979. 46. L.E. Francois, "Narrow Row Cotton under Saline Conditions" (submitted to Irrig. Sci. ), 1982. 47. M.C. Shannon, "Genetics of Salt Tolerance: New Challenges," in Anthony San Pietro (ed.), Biosaline Research, Plenum Publ. Corp., 1982, pp. 261282. 48. Jefferies (1980) cites a production rate for Spartia marshes of 500 to 700 g m -2 yr -1 between 38 N and 28 N latitude. In contrast, Loomis et al. (1971) refer to net primary production rates for various glycophytes that are ten times those figures. See R.S. Loomis, W.A. Williams, and continue A.E. Hall, "Agricultural Productivity," Ann. Review Plant Phys., 1971, 22:431-468; R.L. Jefferies, "The Role of Organic Solutes in Osmoregulation in Halophytic Higher Plants," in D.W. Rains, R.C. Valentine, and Alexander Hollaender (eds.), Genetic Engineering of Osmoregulation, Plenum Press, New York, 1980, pp. 135-154. 49. U.S. Bureau of Reclamation et al., 1979, op. cit. (note 19.) 50. D.J. Dudek and G.L. Horner, USDA, ERS, "Integrated Physical-Economic Resources Analysis: A Case Study of the San Joaquin Valley," Final Report to EPA, Robert S. Kerr ERL, Ada, Oklahoma, 1981. 1. Kenneth D. Frederick, "Irrigation and the Adequacy of Agricultural Land," in The Cropland Crisis, Myth or Reality?, P.R. Crosson, ed., (Baltimore, MD: Johns Hopkins University Press, 1982). 2. E.P. Glenn, M.R. Fontes, and N.P. Yensen, "Productivity of Halophytes Irrigated with Hypersaline Seawater in the Sonoran Desert," in Biosaline Research: A Look to the Future, A. San Pietro, ed., (New York, NY: Plenum Publishing Co., 1982). 3. USDA Agricultural Statistics, 1977.
Chapter 7— Improving Crop Management 1. Gordon Sloggett, "Prospects for Groundwater Irrigation: Declining Levels and Rising Energy Costs," U.S. Department of Agriculture, Economic Research Service, Agricultural Economic Report No. 478, 1981. 2. Kenneth D. Frederick and James C. Harrison, "Western Irrigation: Its Past and Future Growth," Trends in U.S. Irrigation: Three Regional Studies, Pierre Crosson (ed.), United States Environmental Protection Agency, 1981. 3. L.M. Hartman and Don Seastone, Water Transfers: Economic Efficiency and Alternative Institutions, published for Resources for the Future by The Johns Hopkins Press, Baltimore and London, 1970. 4. Technical article 17807 of the Texas Agricultural Experiment Station, College Station, Texas, 1983. Organizational and editorial suggestions of Ms. Kathy Kendall are gratefully acknowledged. 5. Glenn S. Collins, "An Econometric Simulation Model for Evaluating Aggregate Economic Impacts of Technological Change on Major U.S. Field Crops," unpublished Ph.D. dissertation, Texas A&M University, 1980. 6. United States Department of Agriculture, "FEDS Budgets," Economics, Statistics and Cooperative Service, Department of Agricultural Economics, Oklahoma State University, Stillwater, Oklahoma, 1981. 7. Bruce R. Beattie, Michael D. Frank, and Ronald D. Lacewell, "The Economic Value of Irrigation Water in the Western United States," Proceedings of Conference on Legal, Institutional and Social Aspects of Irrigational Drainage and Water Resources Planning and Management published by American Society of Civil Engineers, Virginia Polytechnic Institute and State University, July 26-28, 1978. 8. High Plains Associates, "Six-State High Plains Ogallala Aquifer Regional Resources Study," final report to the United States Department of Commerce, 1982. 9. Robert A. Young and S. L. Gray, "Economic Value of Water: Concepts and Empirical Estimates," Department of Economics PB-210356, Colorado State University, March 1972. 10. Ronald D. Lacewell, J. Michael Sprott, and Bruce Beattie, "Value of Irrigation Water with Alternative Input Prices, Product Prices and Yield Levels by Region in Texas," Texas Water Resources Institute TR-58, Texas Agricultural Experiment Station, Texas A&M University, September 1974.
11. Allan Highstreet, Carole Frank Nuckton, and Gerald L. Horner, "Agricultural Water Use and Costs in California," Giannini Foundation of Agricultural Economics Information Series 80-2, Division of Agricultural Sciences Bulletin 1896, University of California, July 1980. 12. Interview with Dr. Charlie Coble, Department of Agricultural Engineering, Texas A&M University, May 27, 1982. 13. James W. Richardson, Tom P. Zacharias, Gary D. Condra, and Donald D. Stebbins, "Economic Analysis of Alternative Farm Sizes in El Paso County, Texas," Department of Agricultural Economics TR-79-1, Texas Agricultural Experiment Station, Texas A&M University, 1979. break 14. P.S. George and G.A. King, "Consumer Demand for Food Commodities in the United States with Projection for 1980," Giannini Foundation Monograph No. 26, Berkeley, University of California Press, 1971. 15. Ellis G. Knox and Arthur A. Theisen, "Feasibility of Introducing New Crops: Production-Marketing-Consumption Systems," Soil and Land Use Technology, Inc., final report submitted to the National Science Foundation, 1981. 16. Kenneth E. Foster, William H. Brooks, Jean L. Mills, B. Kim Mortensen, and Jonathan G. Taylor, "Low Agricultural Water Use Scoping Study for the Four Corners Regional Committee," Office of Arid Lands Studies, University of Arizona, Tucson, Arizona, April 1980. 17. "Crop Residue Management Systems," Proceedings of a symposium in Houston, Texas, edited by W. R. Oschwald, published by American Society of Agronomy, Crop Science Society of America, and Soil Science Society of America, 1978. 18. Foster, Brooks, Mills, Mortensen and Taylor, op. cit. 19. B.W. Greb, "Reducing Drought Effects on Croplands in the West Central Great Plains," United States Department of Agriculture, Information Bulletin 410, 1979. 20. Paul W. Unger and Allen F. Wiese, "Managing Irrigated Winter Wheat Residue for Water Storage and Subsequent Dryland Grain Sorghum Production," American Journal of the Soil Science Society, Vol. 43 (1979), pp. 582-588. 21. W.M. Lewis, "No-Till Systems," North Carolina State University, Paper No. 134 of the journal series, Agricultural Extension Service, no date.
22. William M. Lyle, Charles R. Fenster, Hayden Ferguson, and Charles W. Wendt, "Water Related Technologies for Sustained Agriculture in U.S. Arid and Semi-Arid Lands," preliminary draft of a report prepared for the Office of Technology Assessment, U.S. Congress, July 1982. 23. C. Robert Taylor, Duane R. Reneau, and Richard Trimble, "Economics of Conservation Tillage Systems," published in Conservation Tillage in Texas (B.L. Harris and A.E. Colburn, editors), Texas Agricultural Extension Service B-1290, Texas A&M University, 1979. 24. Lyle, Fenster, Ferguson and Wendt, op. cit. 25. Norman K. Whittlesey, "Demand Response to Increasing Electricity Prices by Pacific Northwest Irrigated Agriculture," College of Agricultural Research Center, Bulletin 0897, Washington State University, 1981. 26. Neville P. Clarke, "Texas Agriculture in the 80's: The Critical Decade," Texas Agricultural Experiment Station B-1341, Texas A&M University, 1980. 27. Ibid. 26. Neville P. Clarke, "Texas Agriculture in the 80's: The Critical Decade," Texas Agricultural Experiment Station B-1341, Texas A&M University, 1980. 27. Ibid. 28. B.A. Steward, D.A. Dusek, and J.T. Musick, "A Management System for the Conjunctive Use of Rainfall and Limited Irrigation of Graded Furrows," Soil Science Society of America Journal, Vol. 42, No. 2 (1981), pp. 413-419. 29. Lyle, Fenster, Ferguson and Wendt., op. cit. break 1. Ronald H. Delaney and John Borrelli (eds.), "Proceedings of the Symposium on Management of Intermountain Meadows," University of Wyoming, June 7-9, 1979. 2. John Borrelli and Robert Burman, "Evapotranspiration from Heterogeneous Mountain Meadows," Water Resources Series No. 86, University of Wyoming, July 1982. 3. U.S. Department of Agriculture, Soil Conservation Service, Economic Research Service, and U.S. Forest Service, "Opportunities to Improve the Efficiency of Irrigation Water Distribution and Use. A Case Study, Upper Snake River Basin, Idaho," August 1977.
4. U.S. Department of the Interior, U.S. Department of Agriculture, Environmental Protection Agency, "Irrigation Water Use and Management," an Interagency Task Force Report, Washington, D.C., June 1979.
Chapter 8— Improving Land and Water Use Practices 1. Personal Communication, Professor R.O. Hoffman, Department of Industrial Engineering, University of Nebraska, Lincoln, May 25, 1982. 2. N.J. Rosenberg, ed., Drought in the Great Plains: Research on Impacts and Strategies (Littleton, CO: Water Resources Publications, 1980). 3. Harold E. Dregne, Chairman, "Report of the Task Group on Technology" in ibid., pp. 19-41. 4. M. Evenari, L. Shanon, and N.H. Tadmor, "Runoff Farming in the Desert. I. Experimental Layout," Agron.J. 60:29-32 (1968). 5. B.W. Greb, "Reducing Drought Effects on Croplands in the West-Central Great Plains," U.S.D.A. Information Bulletin No. 420, 1979. 6. H.D. Wittmuss, and A. Yazar, "Conservation Tillage Strategies for Increasing Crop Production with Limited Water," Agron. Abstracts, Amer. Soc. Agron. 1977 Annual Meeting. 7. N.J. Rosenberg, "Sown Windbreaks," SPAN 20:12-14 (1977). 8. J.K. Aase and F.H. Siddoway, "Influence of Tall Wheatgrass Wind Barriers and Soil Drying," Agron. J. 68:627-631 (1976). 9. W.L. Pelton and A.U. Earl, "The Influence of Field Shelter Belts on Wind Velocity and Evapotranspiration," Swift Current, Saskatchewan, Canada, Canada Dept. Agr. Exp. Farm Annual Report, mimeo, 1962. 8. J.K. Aase and F.H. Siddoway, "Influence of Tall Wheatgrass Wind Barriers and Soil Drying," Agron. J. 68:627-631 (1976). 10. S.R. Winter, "Suitability of Sugarbeets for Limited Irrigation in a Semiarid Climate," Agron. J. 72:118-123 (1981). 11. B.A. Stewart and J.T. Musick, "Conjunctive Use of Rainfall and Irrigation in Semi-arid Regions," in Vol. 1, Advances in Irrigation Science, Dan Hillel, ed. (New York: Academic Press, in press 1982). break
12. e.g. National Academy of Sciences, Underexploited Tropical Plants with Promising Economic Values, 1975. 13. J.W. Sturrock, "The Control of Wind in Crop Production," Chapter 52 in L.P. Smith, ed., Progress in Plant Biometeorology: The Effect of Weather and Climate on Plants (Swets and Zeitlinger, B.V. Amsterdam, 1975), pp. 349368. 14. J. Grace, Plant Response to Wind (New York: Academic Press, 1977). 7. N.J. Rosenberg, "Sown Windbreaks," SPAN 20:12-14 (1977). 8. J.K. Aase and F.H. Siddoway, "Influence of Tall Wheatgrass Wind Barriers and Soil Drying," Agron. J. 68:627-631 (1976). 15. e.g., K.W. Brown and N.J. Rosenberg, "Shelter Effects on Microclimate, Growth and Water Use by Irrigated Sugarbeets in the Great Plains," Agric. Meteorol. 9:241-263 (1972). 16. e.g. J.K. Radke, "The Use of Annual Wind Barriers for Protecting Row Crops," Proc. Symp. Shelterbelts on the Great Plains, R.W. Tinus, ed. Great Plains Agr. Council Pub. No. 78, 1976, pp. 79-87. 17. J. van Eimern, R. Karschon, L.A. Razumova, and G.W. Robertson, "Windbreaks and Shelterbelts," World Meteorol. Organ. Technical Note No. 59, 1964. 18. J.K. Marshall, "The Effect of Shelter on the Productivity of Grasslands and Field Crops," Field Crop Abstr. 20:1-14 (1967). 19. N.J. Rosenberg, "Windbreaks for Reducing Moisture Stress," Chapter 5.3 in Amer. Soc. Agr. Engin. Monograph on Modification of the Aerial Environment of Plants, B.J. Barfield and J.F. Gerber, eds., pp. 394-408. 14. J. Grace, Plant Response to Wind (New York: Academic Press, 1977). 20. General Accounting Office/Controller General of the United States, Report to the Congress: Action Needed to Discourage Removal of Trees that Shelter Cropland on the Great Plains, RED-75-375, 1975. 21. K.W. Brown and N.J. Rosenberg, "A Resistance Model to Predict Evapotranspiration and Its Application to a Sugarbeet Field," Agron J. 65:341-347 (1973).
15. e.g., K.W. Brown and N.J. Rosenberg, "Shelter Effects on Microclimate, Growth and Water Use by Irrigated Sugarbeets in the Great Plains," Agric. Meteorol. 9:241-263 (1972). 22. D.R. Miller, N.J. Rosenberg, and W.T. Bagley, "Soybean Water Use in the Shelter of a Slat-Fence Windbreak," Agr. Meteorol. 11:405-418 (1973). 7. N.J. Rosenberg, "Sown Windbreaks," SPAN 20:12-14 (1977). 23. I. Seginer, "The Effect of Albedo on Evapotranspiration Rate," Agr. Meteorol. 6:5-31 (1969). 24. A. Aboukhaled, R.M. Hagan, and D.C. Davenport, "Effect of Kaolinite as a Reflective and Transpirant on Leaf Temperature, Transpiration, Photosynthesis and Water Use Efficiency," Water Resources Res. 6:280-289 (1970). 25. N.J. Rosenberg and K.W. Brown,, "Measured and Modelled Effects of Microclimate Modification on Evapotranspiration by Irrigated Crops in a Region of Strong Sensible Heat Advection," Plant Response to Climatic Factors, Proc. Uppsala Symp. Ecology and Conservation, 5, UNESCO, 1973, pp. 539-546. 24. A. Aboukhaled, R.M. Hagan, and D.C. Davenport, "Effect of Kaolinite as a Reflective and Transpirant on Leaf Temperature, Transpiration, Photosynthesis and Water Use Efficiency," Water Resources Res. 6:280-289 (1970). 26. P.C. Doraiswamy and N.J. Rosenberg, "Reflectant Induced Modification of Soybean ( Glycine max L.) Canopy Radiation Balance. I. Preliminary Tests with a Kaolinite Reflectant," Agron. J., 66:224-228 (1974). 27. R. Lemeur and N.J. Rosenberg,, "Reflectant-Induced Modification of Soybean ( Glycine max L.) Canopy Radiation Balance. II. A Quantitative and Qualitative Analysis of Radiation Reflected by a Green Soybean Canopy," Agron. J. 67:301-306 (1975). break 28. M.W. Baradas, B.L. Blad, and N.J. Rosenberg, "Reflectant Induced Modification of Soybean ( Glycine max L.) Canopy Radiation Balance. IV. Leaf and Canopy Temperature," Agron. J. 68:843-848 (1976). 29. M.W. Baradas, B.L. Blad, and N.J. Rosenberg, "Reflectant Induced Modification of Soybean ( Glycine max L.) Canopy Radiation Balance. V. Longwave Radiation Balance," Agron. J. 68:848-852 (1976).
29. M.W. Baradas, B.L. Blad, and N.J. Rosenberg, "Reflectant Induced Modification of Soybean ( Glycine max L.) Canopy Radiation Balance. V. Longwave Radiation Balance," Agron. J. 68:848-852 (1976). 30. S. Moreshet, G. Stanhill, and M. Fuchs, "Effect of Increasing Foliage Reflectance on the CO 2 Uptake and Transpiration Resistance of a Grain Sorghum Crop," Agron. J. 69:246-250 (1977). 31. H. Ferguson, C.S. Cooper, J.H. Brown, and R.F. Eslick, "Effect of Leaf Color, Chlorophyll Concentration and Temperature on Photosynthetic Rates of Isogenic Barley Lines," Agron J. 64:671-673 (1972). 32. J.T. Wooley, "Water Relations of Soybean Leaf Hairs," Agron. J. 56:569571 (1964). 33. S.R. Ghorashy, J.W. Pendleton, D.B. Peters, J.S. Boyer, and J.E. Beuerlein, "Internal Water Stress and Apparent Photosynthesis with Soybeans Differing in Pubescence," Agron. J. 63:674-676 (1971). 34. H.W. Gausman and R. Cardenas, "Light Reflectance by Leaflets of Pubescent, Normal and Glaborous Soybean Lines," Agron J. 65:837-878 (1973). 32. J.T. Wooley, "Water Relations of Soybean Leaf Hairs," Agron. J. 56:569571 (1964). 33. S.R. Ghorashy, J.W. Pendleton, D.B. Peters, J.S. Boyer, and J.E. Beuerlein, "Internal Water Stress and Apparent Photosynthesis with Soybeans Differing in Pubescence," Agron. J. 63:674-676 (1971). 35. J.R. Ehleringer and O. Bjorkman, "Pubescence and Leaf Spectral Characteristics in a Desert Shrub, Encelia Farinosa," Oecologia 36:151-162 (1978). 36. J.R. Ehleringer and H.N. Mooney, "Leaf Hairs: Effects on Physiological Activity and Adaptive Value to a Desert Shrub," Oecologia 37:183-200 (1978). 33. S.R. Ghorashy, J.W. Pendleton, D.B. Peters, J.S. Boyer, and J.E. Beuerlein, "Internal Water Stress and Apparent Photosynthesis with Soybeans Differing in Pubescence," Agron. J. 63:674-676 (1971). 37. R.C. Hartung, J.E. Specht, and J.H. Williams, "Agronomic Performance of Selected Soybean Morphological Variants in Irrigation Culture with Two Row Spacings," Crop Sci. 20:604-609 (1980).
38. D.B. Baldocchi, S.B. Verma, N.J. Rosenberg, A. Garay, and J.E. Specht, "Influence of Leaf Pubescence on the Mass and Energy Exchange between Soybean Canopies and the Atmosphere," Agron. J. (submitted 1982). 39. D.B. Baldocchi, S.B. Verma, and N.J. Rosenberg, "Microclimate in the Soybean Canopy," Ag. Meteorol. (submitted 1982). 40. D.B. Baldocchi, S.B. Verma, and N.J. Rosenberg, "Characteristics of Air Flow Above and Within Soybean Canopies," Boundary Layer Meteorol. (submitted 1982). break 37. R.C. Hartung, J.E. Specht, and J.H. Williams, "Agronomic Performance of Selected Soybean Morphological Variants in Irrigation Culture with Two Row Spacings," Crop Sci. 20:604-609 (1980). 38. D.B. Baldocchi, S.B. Verma, N.J. Rosenberg, A. Garay, and J.E. Specht, "Influence of Leaf Pubescence on the Mass and Energy Exchange between Soybean Canopies and the Atmosphere," Agron. J. (submitted 1982). 39. D.B. Baldocchi, S.B. Verma, and N.J. Rosenberg, "Microclimate in the Soybean Canopy," Ag. Meteorol. (submitted 1982). 40. D.B. Baldocchi, S.B. Verma, and N.J. Rosenberg, "Characteristics of Air Flow Above and Within Soybean Canopies," Boundary Layer Meteorol. (submitted 1982). break
Chapter 9— Improving Irrigation Systems* 1. U.S. Water Resources Council, Synthetic Fuels Development in the Upper Colorado Region, Sect. 13(a), Water Assessment Report, July 1981. break 2. A. Wolman, Water Resources, National Academy of Science, NRC Publ. 1000-B, 1962. 3. U.S. Department of Agriculture, Soil Conservation Service, America's Soil and Water: Conditions and Trends, 1980. 4. California Dept. of Water Resources, Use of Water by Imperial Irrigation District, District Report, December 1981. 5. Ibid. 4. California Dept. of Water Resources, Use of Water by Imperial Irrigation
District, District Report, December 1981. 5. Ibid. 6. Interagency Task Force, Irrigation Water Use and Management, Task Force Report, USDI, USDA and EPA, June 1979. 7. J.T. Musick, ARS-USDA, Bushland, Texas, personal communication. 8. H.R. Duke, ARS-USDA, Fort Collins, Colorado, personal communication. 9. A.R. Dedrick, ARS-USDA, Phoenix, Arizona, personal communication. 10. D.F. Heermann, ARS-USDA, Fort Collins, Colorado, personal communication. 11. Data derived from research project "Water Requirements of Cotton," unpublished study. 12. R.R. Lansford, P.J. Wieringa, T.W. Sammis, and B.J. Creel, Demonstration of Irrigation Return Flow Water Quality Control in the Mesilla Valley, New Mexico, Project Summary, EPA-600/S2-82-071, 1982. 1. M.J. English and G.S. Nuss, "Designing for Deficit Irrigation," Proceedings ASCE, Vol. 108, No. IR-2 (June 1982). break
Chapter 10— Local and Regional Economic Impacts 1. Alan Randall, "Property Entitlements and Pricing Policies for a Maturing Water Economy," unpublished working paper, Department of Agricultural Economics, University of Kentucky, 1982. 2. The limited impact hypothesis is not new, being expressed in among others, Jack Hirshleifer et al., Water Supply: Economics, Technology and Policy, University of Chicago Press, 1960; J.S. Bain et al., Northern California's Water Industry, Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press, 1966; R.A. Young and W.E. Martin, "The Economics of Arizona's Water Problem," Arizona Review, March 1967; M.M. Kelso, W.E. Martin, and L.E. Mack, Water Supplies and Economic Growth: An Arizona Case Study, Tucson: University of Arizona Press, 1972. 3. K.E. Boulding, "The Implications of Improved Water Application," in Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City (sponsor), Western Water Resources,
Boulder: Westview Press, 1980. 4. For a detailed discussion, see R.A. Young and S.L. Gray, Economic Value of Water: Concepts and Empirical Estimates, Technical Report U.S. National Water Commission, National Technical Information Service, PB210356, March 1972. 5. B.R. Beattie, personal communication, Department of Agricultural Economics and Economics, Montana State University, Bozeman, 1980. 6. R.E. Howitt, D.E. Mann, and H.J. Vaux, Jr., "The Economics of Water Allocation," in Ernest A. Engelbert with Ann F. Scheuring (eds.), Competition for California Water: Alternative Resolutions, Berkeley: University of California Press, 1982. 7. N.R. Gollehon, R.R. Lansford, et al., "Impacts on Irrigated Agriculture for Energy Development in the Rocky Mountain Region," Southwestern Review of Management and Economics, 1(1:61-88), Spring 1981. break 8. L.R. Brown, "Conflicting Claims to Southwestern Water: The Equity and Management Issues," Southwestern Review of Management and Economics, 1(1:35-60), Spring 1981. 9. R.A. Young and S.L. Gray, op. cit. (note 4 above). 10. H. Gold et al., "Water Requirements for Steam-Electric Power Generation and Synthetic Fuel Plants in the Western United States," Environmental Protection Agency Report No. 600/7-77-037, February 1977. 11. David Abbey, "Energy Production and Water Resources in the Colorado River Basin," Natural Resources Journal, 19(2:275-314), 1979. 12. Marie Leigh, "Competition for Water: Energy vs. Agriculture," paper prepared for ASCE Conference, "Water and Energy: Technical and Policy Issues," Fort Collins, Colorado, June 1982. 13. C.W. Howe and F.P. Lineaweaver, "The Impact of Price on Residential Water Demand," Water Resources Research, 3(2) 1967. 14. R.E. Howitt et al., op. cit. (note 6 above). 15. R.L. Gardner and T.A. Miller, "An Explanation of Price Behavior in the Water Rights Market of Northeastern Colorado," Department of Economics, Colorado State University, Fort Collins (paper prepared for delivery to Annual
Conference, American Agricultural Economics Association, Logan, Utah, August 1982). 16. R.A. Young and S.L. Gray, op. cit., (note 4 above). 17. Norman Whittlesey and R. Gibbs, "Energy and Irrigation in Washington," Western Journal of Agricultural Economics, 3(1:1-11), 1978. 18. L.B. Merritt and B.W. Mar, "Marginal Values of Dilution Water," Water Resources Research, 5(6), December 1969. 19. R.A. Young and S.L. Gray, op. cit. (note 4 above). 20. J.T. Daubert and R.A. Young with S.L. Gray, Economic Benefits from Instream Flow in a Colorado Mountain Stream, Completion Report 91, Water Resources Research Center, Colorado State University, Fort Collins, June 1979. 21. R.G. Walsh, et al., An Empirical Application of a Model for Estimating the Recreation Value of Instream Flow, Completion Report 101, Water Resources Research Institute, Colorado State University, Fort Collins, October 1980. 22. C.J. Cicchetti et al., "An Economic Analysis of Water Resource Investment and Regional Economic Growth," Water Resources Research, 11(1:1-6), February 1975. 23. H. Fullerton et al., Regional Development: An Econometric Study of the Role of Water Development in Effectuating Population and Income Changes, Report PRRBE980-1, Utah State University Water Research Laboratory, Logan, 1975. 24. M.M. Kelso et al., op. cit. (note 2 above). 25. R.A. Young et al., Energy and Water Scarcity and the Irrigated Agriculture Economy of the Colorado High Plains: Direct EconomicHydrologic Impact Analysis, Technical Report 29, Colorado Water Resources Research Institute, Colorado State University, Fort Collins, February 1982; J.R. McKean, Projected Population, Employment and Economic Outlook on Colorado's Eastern Plains: 1979-2020, Technical Report 33, Colorado Water Resources Research Institute, Colorado State University, Fort Collins, February 1982. 26. N.R. Gollehon et al., op. cit. (note 7 above). break
1. R.E. Howitt, Dean E. Mann, and H.J. Vaux, "The Economics of Water Allocation," Ernest A. Engelbert with Ann F. Scheuring (eds.), Competition for California Water Berkeley: University of California Press, 1982, pp. 136162. 1. Jill Leslie Findeis and Norman K. Whittlesey, Competition Between Irrigation and Hydropower Water Use in Washington State, State of Washington Water Research Center, Washington State University, Report No. 44, 1982. break
Chapter 11— National and International Commodity Price Impacts 1. S.H. Boerma, "The World Could Be Fed," Journal of Soil and Water Conservation, Vol. 30, No. 1, 1975, pp. 4-11. Also, Food and Agricultural Organization, Agriculture Towards 2000, 20th Session, United Nations, Rome, 1979. 2. Douglas Christensen, Andrew Morton, and Earl O. Heady, Potential Effects of Increased Water Prices on U.S. Agriculture, CARD Report No. 101, Center for Agricultural and Rural Development, Iowa State University, Ames, 1981. Also, Ralph W. Cummings, Jr., "Food Production and the Energy Crisis," Working Papers of the Rockefeller Foundation, New York, 1974. 3. U.S. Department of Agriculture, Soil Conservation Service, 1977 National Resources Inventory, Washington, 1978. 4. Earl O. Heady, "The Adequacy of Agricultural Land," in Pierre Crosson, The Croplands Crisis: Myth or Reality (Baltimore: Johns Hopkins Press, 1982), pp. 23-56. 5. Ibid. 4. Earl O. Heady, "The Adequacy of Agricultural Land," in Pierre Crosson, The Croplands Crisis: Myth or Reality (Baltimore: Johns Hopkins Press, 1982), pp. 23-56. 5. Ibid. 6. Yoo-chi Lu, Philip Cline, and Leroy Quance, Prospects for Productivity Growth in U.S. Agriculture, U.S. Department of Agriculture, ESCS, Agricultural Economic Report No. 435, Washington, 1979. break 7. R. Fuller, "More and More Effort Yields Less and Less," Des Moines Register and Tribune, Sunday, February 17, 1980.
8. S.H. Wittwer, "Increased Crop Yields and Livestock Productivity," in Marilyn Chou (ed.), World Food Prospects and Agricultural Potential (New York: Praeger Publishers, 1977), pp. 66-135. 9. S.H. Wittwer, "New Technology, Agricultural Productivity and Conservation," in Halcrow, Heady, and Cotner (eds.), Soil Conservation Policies, Institutions and Incentives, Ch. 9, (Ankeny: Soil Conservation Society of America, 1982). 10. Earl O. Heady, "The Adequacy of Agricultural Land," and the U.S. Department of Agriculture Workshop on Emerging Technologies, Washington, D.C., October 1981, forthcoming. 11. Earl O. Heady, Howard C. Madsen, Kenneth J. Nicol, and Stanley H. Hargrove, Agricultural and Water Policies and the Environment: An Analysis of National Alternatives in Natural Resource Use, Food Supply Capacity and Environmental Quality, CARD Report No. 40, Center for Agricultural and Rural Development, Iowa State University, Ames, 1972. 12. Burton C. English, Earl O. Heady, and Klaus F. Alt, A Documentation of the Resources Conservation Act's Assessment Model of Regional Agricultural Production, Land and Water Use, and Soil Loss, CARD Report No. 107T, Center for Agricultural and Rural Development, Iowa State University, Ames, 1982. Also, Burton C. English, and Earl O. Heady, Short- and Long-Term Analysis of the Impacts of Several Soil Loss Control Measures on Agriculture, CARD Report No. 93, Center for Agricultural and Rural Development, Iowa State University, Ames, 1980. 13. USDA, Soil Conservation Service, 1977 National Resources Inventory. 14. Anton D. Meister, Earl O. Heady, Kenneth J. Nicol, and Roger W. Strohbehn, U.S. Agricultural Production in Relation to Alternative Water, Environmental and Export Policies, CARD Report No. 65, Center for Agricultural and Rural Development, Iowa State University, Ames, 1976. 15. Douglas Christensen, Earl O. Heady, and Andrew Morton, Potential Water Use and Agricultural Production Patterns Under Alternative Water Prices, American Water Bulletin, vol. 17, No. 2, 1981, pp. 844-850. Also, P.S. George, and G.A. King, Consumer Demand for Food Commodities in the United States With Projections for 1980, Giannini Foundation Monograph 26, University of California, 1971. 16. Kenneth D. Frederick estimates per acre-foot pumping costs at 200 feet by the year 2000 with costs of $35.52 by electricity, $50.40 by LP gas and $60.00 by diesel, in his mimeographed paper, "Irrigation and the Adequacy of Agricultural Land" (Resources for the Future, Washington, 1979).
17. The indicated quantity of water for the RCA maximum production might not be available if competition from other uses became overriding and larger than expected. 18. See Christensen, Morton, and Heady, note 2. 19. H.W. Ayer, and Paul G. Hoyt, Crop Water Production Functions: Economic Implications for Arizona, Technical Bulletin 242, Agricultural Experiment Station, University of Arizona, Tucson, 1981. 20. Des Moines Sunday Register, "Colorado Thirsts for Growth and Water," December 23, 1979, p. 2A. break 21. Earl O. Heady, and Roger W. Hexem, Water Production Functions in Irrigated Agriculture (Ames: Iowa State University Press, 1978). 22. Cameron Short, Earl O. Heady, Anthony F. Turhollow, Jr., and Kun Chol Lee, Regional Impacts of Groundwater Mining from the Ogallala Aquifer with Increasing Energy Prices, 1990 and 2000, CARD Report No. 98, Center for Agricultural and Rural Development, Iowa State University, Ames, 1981. 23. The 1977 NRI estimated 60.7 acres irrigated which are higher than the 1974 Census estimated. It is considered that the census underestimates irrigated acreage. See Frederick. 24. George E. Brandow, Interrelationships Among Demands for Farm Products and Implications for Control of Market Supply, Penn State University Station Bulletin 680, 1961. Also, Rex F. Daly, "Demand for Farm Products at Retail and Farm Level," Journal of the American Statistical Association, Vol. 53, 1958, pp. 656-668. Also, J. Mann and G. St. George, Estimates of Elasticities of Food Demand in the United States, Economics, Statistics, and Cooperatives Service, U.S. Department of Agriculture TB1580, March 1978. Also, P.S. George, and G.A. King, Consumer Demand for Food Commodities in the United States with Projections for 1980, Giannini Foundation Monograph 26, University of California, 1971. 25. R. Lamm, Aggregate Food Demand and the Supply of Agricultural Products, Economics and Statistics Service, U.S. Department of Agriculture Tech. Bul. 1658, Washington, 1981. Also, if we used Lamm's estimates, we more nearly set the price change at 10 percent. Currently, however, we are inclined to "go with the majority" of an elasticity around -.25. 26. Maury E. Bredahl, William H. Meyers, and Keith J. Collins, "The Elasticity of Foreign Demand for U.S. Agricultural Products: The Importance of the Price Transmission Elasticity," American Journal of Agricultural Economics, 61(1979):58-63. Also, Paul R. Johnson, "The Elasticity of Foreign Demand for U.S. Agricultural Products," American Journal of Agricultural Economics,
59(1977):735-36. 1. Kenneth D. Frederick and James C. Hudson, Water for Western Agriculture, Research Paper, Resources for the Future, 1982. 2. Six-State High Plains Ogallala Aquifer Regional Resources Study, A Report to the U.S. Department of Commerce and the High Plains Study Council by High Plains Associates: Camp Dresser and McKee Inc.; Black and Veatch; Arthur D. Little, Inc., 1982. 3. Pierre R. Crosson, ed., The Cropland Crisis: Myth or Reality?, Resources for the Future, 1982; Pierre R. Crosson and Sterling Brubaker, Resource and Environmental Effects of U.S. Agriculture, Resources for the Future, 1982. 4. Robert A. Young and S. Lee Gray, Economic Value of Water: Concepts and Empirical Estimates, Department of Economics, Colorado State University, Fort Collins, March, 1972. 1. High Plains Study Council, Congressional Briefing: Six-State High Plains: Ogallala Aquifer Regional Resources Study, February 1981. 2. High Plains Study Council, National and Regional Price Impact Assessment, Six-State High Plains Ogallala Aquifer Regional Resource Study, March 1982. break
Chapter 12— Impacts upon Business Communities 1. "Water Conservation: A National Priority," EPA Journal, March 1980, p. 17. break
Chapter 13— Social Impacts on Rural Communities 1. W.D. Rasmussen, "The Mechanization of Agriculture," Scientific American, 247 (September, 1982), pp. 76-89; N. Burns, "The Collapse of Small Towns on the Great Plains: A Bibliography," The Emporia State Research Studies, XXXI (Summer, 1982), pp. 5-36. 2. E. Shils, "The Integration of Society," in The Constitution of Society (Chicago: The University of Chicago Press, 1982), pp. 3-52. 3. Ibid. 4. Ibid.
2. E. Shils, "The Integration of Society," in The Constitution of Society (Chicago: The University of Chicago Press, 1982), pp. 3-52. 3. Ibid. 4. Ibid. 2. E. Shils, "The Integration of Society," in The Constitution of Society (Chicago: The University of Chicago Press, 1982), pp. 3-52. 3. Ibid. 4. Ibid. 5. R.M. Williams Jr., American Society: A Sociological Interpretation (New York: Alfred A. Knopf, 1970). 6. W.G. Matlock, Realistic Planning for Arid Lands: Natural Resources Limitations to Agricultural Development (London: Harwood Academic Publishers, 1981), p. 4. 7. T.W. Box, The Arid Lands Revisited—One Hundred Years Since John Wesley Powell (Logan, Utah: Utah State University, n.d.), pp. 4-7. break 8. C. Hodge, "Aridity and Man: An Interpretive Summary," in Carle Hodge, ed., Aridity and Man: The Challenge of the Arid Lands in the United States (Washington, D.C.: American Association for the Advancement of Science, 1963), pp. 1-19. 9. G. Sloggett, Prospects for Ground-Water Irrigation: Declining Levels and Rising Energy Costs (Washington, D.C.: National Resource Economics Division, Economic Research Service, U.S. Department of Agriculture, 1981), p. 9. 10. Ibid., p. 9. 11. Ibid., p. 20. 9. G. Sloggett, Prospects for Ground-Water Irrigation: Declining Levels and Rising Energy Costs (Washington, D.C.: National Resource Economics Division, Economic Research Service, U.S. Department of Agriculture, 1981), p. 9.
10. Ibid., p. 9. 11. Ibid., p. 20. 9. G. Sloggett, Prospects for Ground-Water Irrigation: Declining Levels and Rising Energy Costs (Washington, D.C.: National Resource Economics Division, Economic Research Service, U.S. Department of Agriculture, 1981), p. 9. 10. Ibid., p. 9. 11. Ibid., p. 20. 12. High Plains Study Council, Six-State High Plains Ogallala Aquifer Regional Resources Study, Preliminary First Draft (Spring 1982) II-3. Unpublished. 13. Ibid., V-4. 12. High Plains Study Council, Six-State High Plains Ogallala Aquifer Regional Resources Study, Preliminary First Draft (Spring 1982) II-3. Unpublished. 13. Ibid., V-4. 14. C.S. Fischer, The Urban Experience (New York: Harcourt Brace Jovanovch, 1976). 15. K.P. Wilkinson, "Consequences of Decline and Social Adjustment to It," in Communities Left Behind: Alternatives for Development, edited by Larry R. Whiting (Ames, Iowa: The Iowa State University Press, 1974), pp. 43-53. 16. B.N. Adams, "The Small Trade Center: Processes and Perceptions of Growth or Decline," in The Community: A Comparative Perspective, edited by Robert Mills French (Itasca, Ill.: F.E. Peacock, 1969), pp. 471-84. 17. Ibid., p. 481. 16. B.N. Adams, "The Small Trade Center: Processes and Perceptions of Growth or Decline," in The Community: A Comparative Perspective, edited by Robert Mills French (Itasca, Ill.: F.E. Peacock, 1969), pp. 471-84. 17. Ibid., p. 481.
18. R.C. Martin, et al., Decisions in Syracuse (Bloomington, Ind.: Indiana University Press, 1961). 19. M. Clawson, "The Dying Community: The Natural Resource Base," in The Dying Community, edited by Art Gallaher, Jr. and Harland Padfield (Albuquerque, N.M.: University of New Mexico Press, 1980), pp. 55-83. 20. Ibid. 19. M. Clawson, "The Dying Community: The Natural Resource Base," in The Dying Community, edited by Art Gallaher, Jr. and Harland Padfield (Albuquerque, N.M.: University of New Mexico Press, 1980), pp. 55-83. 20. Ibid. 21. B.N. Adams, op. cit. 22. H. Aldrich and D.A. Whetten, "Organization-sets, Action-sets and Networks: Making the Most of Simplicity," in Handbook of Organizational Design. I, edited by Paul C. Nystrom and William H. Starbuck (New York: Oxford University Press, 1981), pp. 385-408; J. Pfeffer and G.R. Salancik, The External Control of Organizations (New York: Harper & Row, 1978); J.D. Thompson, Organizations in Action (New York: McGraw Hill, 1967); H.E. Aldrich, Organizations & Environments (Englewood Cliffs, N.J.: Prentice-Hall, 1979). 23. A. Schaffer, R.C. Schaffer, and G.M. Halter, Social Impacts of McClellanKerr Navigation System: A Study of Public Sector Response to Water Resource Development (Fort Belvoir, Va.: U.S. Army Engineer Institute for Water Resources, 1981.) 24. M. Aiken and R.R. Alford, "Community Structure and Innovation: The Case of Public Housing," American Political Science Review (September, 1970), pp. 843-864. 25. H.L. Wilensky, "Careers, Life Style, and Social Integration," in Sigmund Nosow and William H. Form, eds., Man, Work & Society (New York: Basic Books, 1962), pp. 329-32. break 26. R. Blauner, Alienation and Freedom (Chicago: The University of Chicago Press, 1964); D. Yankelovich, "The Work Ethic is Underemployed," Psychology Today, 16 (May 1982), p. 8; C.M. Arensberg, "Work and the Changing American Scene," in Nosow and Form, eds., op cit., pp. 24-28; N.C. Morse, and R.S. Weiss, "The Function and Meaning of Work and the Job," in Nosow and Form, eds., op. cit., pp. 29-35.
27. E. Ginzberg, The Manpower Connection: Education and Work (Cambridge, Ma.: Harvard University Press, 1975). 28. D. Yankelovich, op. cit. 29. N.C. Morse, and R.S. Weiss, "The Function and Meaning of Work and the Job," in Nosow and Form, eds., op. cit., pp. 29-35. 30. R. Sennett and J. Cobb, The Hidden Injuries of Class (New York: Vintage Books, 1973). 31. M. Jahoda, P.F. Lazarsfeld, and H. Zeisel, Marienthal: The Sociography of an Unemployed Community (Chicago, Aldine-Atherton, 1971). 32. H.H. Hyman, "The Effects of Unemployment: A Neglected Problem in Modern Social Research," in Robert K. Merton, James S. Coleman, and Peter H. Rossi, eds., Qualitative and Quantitative Social Research: Papers in Honor of Paul F. Lazarsfeld (New York: Free Press, 1979), pp. 282-298. 33. Ibid., pp. 290-293. 32. H.H. Hyman, "The Effects of Unemployment: A Neglected Problem in Modern Social Research," in Robert K. Merton, James S. Coleman, and Peter H. Rossi, eds., Qualitative and Quantitative Social Research: Papers in Honor of Paul F. Lazarsfeld (New York: Free Press, 1979), pp. 282-298. 33. Ibid., pp. 290-293. 34. N. Krumholz and J. Cogger, "The Challenge of Contracting Municipalities," in George Sternlieb and James W. Hughes, eds., Revitalizing the Northeast (New Brunswick, N.J.: Center for Urban Policy Research, Rutgers University, 1978), pp. 371-377; R. Starr, "Making New York Smaller," in George Sternlieb and James W. Hughes, eds., op. cit., pp. 373389; G. Breckenfeld, "It's Up to Cities to Save Themselves," in Sternlieb and Hughes, eds., op. cit., pp. 390-404; M.J. Kasoff, "Public and Private Infrastructure in Mature Cities," in Edward W. Hanten, Mark J. Kasoff, and F. Redburn, eds., New Directions for the Mature Metropolis (Cambridge, Ma.: Schenkman, 1980), pp. 128-141; W. Thompson, "Toward a Strategy for Central City Depopulation," in Hanten, Kasoff and Redburn, eds., op. cit., pp. 142-153. 35. N. Krumholz, and J. Cogger, op. cit. 36. G. Breckenfeld, op. cit., pp. 392-393.
37. M. Clawson, op. cit. 38. High Plains Study Council, Six-State High Plains Ogallala Aquifer Regional Resources Study, Preliminary First Draft (Spring 1982), pp. 1-4. Unpublished. 1. William H. Friedland, "Seasonal Farm Laborers and Worker Consciousness," in R. and I. Simpson (eds.), Research in the Sociology of Work (Greenwich: JAI Press, 1981), pp. 351-380. 2. Bureau of the Census, U.S. Department of Commerce, Statistical Abstract of the United States 1981, Washington, Government Printing Office: Table 658, p. 390. 3. Space precludes expanding this point but the literature is detailed in describing the "thin," class-ridden societies characterized by enormous discrepancies in income and by the realization of wealth at geographical locations other than where the wealth is actually produced. See, for example, Walter Goldschmidt, As You Sow (Montclair, N.J.: Allanheld, Osmun, 1978). break
Chapter 15— Environmental Impacts 1. U.S. Water Resources Council, The Nation's Water Resources 1975-2000: The Second National Water Assessment (Washington, D.C.: U.S. G.P.O., 1978). See Vol. 2, Water Quantity, Quality and Related Land Considerations. 2. See: B.A. Stewart, D.A. Woolhiser, W.H. Wischmeier, J.H. Caro, and M.H. Frere, "Control of Water Pollution from Cropland," Vol. I, A Manual for Guideline Development (Agricultural Research Service, USDA, and Office of Research and Development, EPA, ARS-H-5-1, 1975); S.G. Unger, "Environmental Implications of Trends in Agriculture and Silviculture," in Best Management Practices for Agriculture and Silviculture, R.C. Loehr, D.A. Haith, M.F. Walter, and C.S. Martin, eds. (Ann Arbor, Mich.: Ann Arbor Science, 1979); G.W. Bailey, and T.E. Waddell, "Best Management Practices for Agriculture and Silviculture: An Integrated Review," in Best Management Practices for Agriculture and Silviculture; and W.C. White and H. Plate, "Best Management Practices for Fertilizer Use," in Best Management Practices for Agriculture and Silviculture. 3. National Agricultural Lands Study, United States Department of Agriculture and the Council on Environmental Quality, in cooperation with 10 other federal agencies, 1981. 4. No-Till Farmer, Frank Lessiter, ed., Waukesha, Wisc. 10(3):4-5 (1982). break
5. H.P. Mapp, "The Six-State Ogallala Aquifer Area Study: Baseline Results for the Agricultural Sector," Professional Paper No. P-1065, Oklahoma Agricultural Experiment Station, 1981. 6. Soil, Water, and Related Resources in the United States: Status, Condition, and Trends, 1980 Appraisal, Part 1, United States Department of Agriculture, 1981.
Chapter 16— What Farmers Can Do for Themselves 1. "Challenges and Responses," Progressive Agriculture in Arizona, 31:4 (Winter 1981), p. 8, University of Arizona, College of Agriculture, Tucson. break 2. Scott H. Hathorn, Jr., University of Arizona Agricultural Economics Dept., personal communication, July 1982. 3. Walt Parsons, U.S. Soil Conservation Service and Arizona Dept. of Water Resources, Phoenix, personal communication, July 1982. 4. John Daubert and Harry Ayer, Laser Leveling and Farm Profits, Technical Bulletin 244, University of Arizona Agricultural Experiment Station and USDA Economic Research Service, Tucson, June 1982. 5. Walt Parsons, personal communication (see note 3). 6. Daubert and Ayer, ibid. 5. Walt Parsons, personal communication (see note 3). 6. Daubert and Ayer, ibid. 7. "Challenges and Responses," Progressive Agriculture in Arizona. 8. M. Scott Tollefson, "Drip Irrigation on Cotton," Proceedings of Symposium Alternatives for On-Farm Energy Conservation, Production and Use, University of Arizona College of Agriculture and Arizona Energy Office, Phoenix, May 1982. 9. Will Anderson, "Aerated Drip Irrigation," Farm Bureau Energy Idea Search, American Farm Bureau Federation, November 1980. 10. Brad DeSpain, "Irrigation with Sewage Effluent," Cortaro-Marana
Irrigation District, Tucson, January 1981. 11. Scott H. Hathorn, Jr., personal communication. 12. Guy Webster, "High Salt, Low Water Barleys," Progressive Agriculture in Arizona, 31:1 (September 1981), p. 1, University of Arizona College of Agriculture, Tucson.
Chapter 17— What Financial and Business Interests Can Do 1. A.L. Stoeker, M.L. Wright, and D.A. Pyles, "An Input-Output Model of the Texas High Plains Economy in 1977," Department of Agricultural Economics, Texas Tech. University and Texas Department of Water Resources, Austin, Texas, August 1981. 2. Much of the information on research and development was taken from "A Summary of Results of the Ogallala Aquifer Regional Study, with Recommendations to the Secretary of Commerce and Congress," High Plains Study Council: Colorado, Kansas, Nebraska, New Mexico, Oklahoma and Texas, August 12, 1982. break
Chapter 18— Water Rights and Market Transfers* 1. See F. Lee Brown, et al., "Water Reallocation, Market Proficiency, and Conflicting Social Values," in Western Water Institutions in a Changing Environment, John Muir Institute, Napa, California, 1980. 2. R. Khoshaklagh, F.L. Brown, and C. DuMars, Forecasting Future Market Values of Water Rights in New Mexico, Report #92, New Mexico Water Resources Research Institute, Las Cruces, N.M. 3. Water rights prices in various basins at various times are reported in the studies mentioned in the preceding two footnotes. 4. Based on information in the San Francisco Chronicle, Oct. 14, 1981. 5. For a discussion of the energy industry's greater ability to pay, see David Abbey et al., "The Role of Water in Energy Development," paper presented at the annual meeting of the American Association for the Advancement of Science,, January 1982. Available from Los Alamos National Laboratory. 6. The vision of John Wesley Powell's Report on the Arid Region of the United States, The Belknap Press of Harvard University Press, Cambridge, Mass., is even more remarkable for its prescience when read in retrospect.
7. P.F. Drucker, Management: Tasks, Responsibilities, Practices, Harper & Row, 1973, 1974, p.37. 8. A. Maass, and R.L. Anderson, And the Desert Shall Rejoice: Conflict, Growth and Justice in Arid Environments, The MIT Press, Cambridge, Mass., 1978. 9. Ibid., p. 5 8. A. Maass, and R.L. Anderson, And the Desert Shall Rejoice: Conflict, Growth and Justice in Arid Environments, The MIT Press, Cambridge, Mass., 1978. 9. Ibid., p. 5 10. K. Boulding, in Western Water Resources: Coming Problems and the Policy Alternatives, Westview Press, Boulder, Colorado, 1980, p. 306. 11. Ibid., p. 306. 10. K. Boulding, in Western Water Resources: Coming Problems and the Policy Alternatives, Westview Press, Boulder, Colorado, 1980, p. 306. 11. Ibid., p. 306. 12. H.P. Hood and Sons v. DuMond, 336 U.S. 525 (1949). 13. Irvin v. Phillips, 5 Cal. 140 (1955). 14. Hardy v. Beaver County Irrigation, 65 Utah 28, 234 P. 524 (1924); Wash v. Wallace, 26 Nev. 299, 67 P. 914 (1920); State ex. rel. Reynolds v. Miranda, 83 N.M. 443, 493 P. 2d 409 (1972). 15. 530 P.2d 924 (Ida. 1974). 16. Id. Colorado and Washington are in accord. 17. 292 N.W. 2d 239 (Neb. 1940). 18. Colo. Rev. Stat. § 37-92-102(2)(d).
19. Cache LaPoudre Water Users Ass'n v. Glacier View Meadows, 550 P.2d 288 (Colo. 1976). 20. See Wyoming Hereford Ranch v. Hammond Packing Co., 236 P. 764 (Wyo. 1925). break 21. Wash. Rev. Code Ann. 90.54.020(2). See also Alaska Stat. 46.15.080 and Idaho Code § 43-203. 22. 32 Stat. 388, 43 U.S.C. § 12 (1978). 23. Ellis and DuMars, "The Two-Tiered Market in Western Water," 57 Neb. L. Rev. 333 (1978). 24. 438 U.S. 645, 653. 25. United States v. New Mexico, 238 U.S. 696 (1978). 26. See J. Palma, "Considerations and Conclusions Concerning the Transferability of Indian Water Rights," 20 Nat. Res. J. 91 (1980). 27. Arizona v. California, 373 U.S. 546 (1963), supplemental decree. 28. DuMars and Ingram, "Congressional Quantification of Indian Reserved Water Rights: A Definitive Solution or a Mirage?" 20 Nat. Res. J. 17 (1980). 29. State ex rel. Cromley v. District Court, 88 P.2d 23 (Mont. 1939). 30. 589 P.2d 57 (1978). 31. Special Masters Report at 10, Colorado v. New Mexico, origin no. 84. 32. See, for example, Texas. 33. Lodi v. East Bay Municipal District, 60 p.2d 439 (Cal. 1936). 34. 366 P.2d 552 (Colo. 1961). 35. 366 P.2d at 556. See also Baker v. Ore-Ida Foods, Inc., 513 P.2d 627 (Ida. 1973).
36. State ex rel. Reynolds v. South Springs Co., 452 P.2d 478 (N.M. 1969). 37. Mathers v. Texaco, 421 P.2d 771 (N.M. 1966), upholding state engineer conclusion that 40 years would be appropriate time because it corresponded to pay period on reclamation loans. 38. F. Trelease, Water Law, 3rd. ed., 1979, p. 463, quoting (Todd, 1959). 39. See Heine v. Reynolds, 367 P.2d 708 (1962). 40. See, for example, N.M. Stat. Ann. § 72-12-19 (1978). 41. Sporhase, slip op. at 16. 1. Arthur Maass, and Raymond L. Anderson, . . . and the Desert Shall Rejoice (Cambridge, Mass.: M.I.T. Press, 1978). 2. John Nichols, The Milagro Beanfield War (New York: Ballantine Books, 1974). break 1. Coply International Corporation, The Market Structure of the Southern California Water Industry. 2. Michael B. Teitz and Richard A. Walker, "Industry," in Competition for California Water: Alternative Resolutions, (University of California Press, 1982). 3. Mark N. Christensen, Glenn W. Harrison, and Larry J. Kimbell, "Energy," in Competition for California Water: Alternative Resolutions, (University of California Press, 1982). 4. B. Delworth Gardner, et al., "Agriculture," in Competition for California Water: Alternative Resolutions (University of California Press, 1982). break
Chapter 20— Federal Water Policies and Irrigated Agriculture 1. This view has had strong proponents, especially since 1958. A succinct statement appears in D.B. Gardner, "The Water Management Crunch: An Economic Perspective," in Walter Jeske (ed.), Economics, Ethics, Ecology: Costs of Productive Conservation (Ankeny, IA: Soil Conservation Society of America, 1981), pp. 67-77.
2. An indication of the kinds of shifts that can occur in part of the arid West can be found in the Six State High Plains-Ogallala Aquifer continue Regional Resources Study, in Camp, Dresser & McKee, Report of the High Plains Ogallala Study (Austin, Texas: High Plains Associates, 1982). 3. A somewhat dated but good summary of the relationship between water supply and competition within the region is found in Water Policies for the Future , Final Report to the President and te Congress of the United States by the National Water Commission (Washington, D.C.: 1973), pp. 48-61. 4. This is summarized in H.P. Caulfield, "Water Policy and Irrigated Agriculture," paper for Annual meeting, American Association for Advancement of Science, Washington, D.C., January 4, 1982, pp. 3-9. 5. See U.S. Water Resources Council, Planning and Cost Sharing Policy Options for Water and Related Land Programs , Part 5a (Washington, D.C.: 1975) pp. 61-68 and pp. B-7 and B-8. Care in interpretation of these findings is necessary due to divergence between project repayment rates and 1975 rate of 6-7/8 percent used in the analysis. 6. See J.L. Sax, "Selling Reclamation Water Rights: A Case Study in Federal Subsidy Policy, " Michigan Law Review , November 1965, pp. 13-32, and R.R. Rucker and P.V. Fishback, "The Federal Reclamation Program: An Analysis of Rent Seeking Behavior," in T.L. Anderson, Water Resources Bureaucracy, Property Rights and the Environment (Cambridge, Mass.: Ballinger Publishers, Inc. and the Pacific Institute, forthcoming). 7. For an example of the kinds of criticisms that have been offered, see General Accounting Office, CED 78-127, An Overview of Benefit Cost Analysis for Water Resources Projects—Improvements Still Needed (washington, D.C.: August 7, 1978). The responding bureaus found some factural errors in the report. 8. General Accounting Office "Millions of Acre-Feet of Underutilized Water in Federal Reservoirs Make Cost Reimbursement Difficult," CED-81-77, Changes in Federal Waer Project Repayment Policies Can Reduce Federal Costs (Washington, D.C.: August 7, 1981), pp. 7-29. The Bureau of Reclamation indicates the extent of underutilization is overstated, given project requirements. 9. This conversion represents a consensus of many writers in the field. See as an example, K.D. Frederick with J.C. Hanson, "Western Irrigation: Its Past and Future Growth," in Trends in U.S. Irrigation: Three Regional Studies (Washington, D.C., Resources for the Future, 1981). 10. President Carter's Message to Congress on Water Policy, June 6, 1978.
11. R.R. Rucker and P.V. Fishback, supra, note 6. 11. R.R. Rucker and P.V. Fishback, supra, note 6. 12. M. Gisser and R. Johnson, "Institutional Restrictions on the Transfer of Water Rights and the Survival of an Agency," in T. Anderson (ed.), supra, note 6, and Middle Rio Grande Conservancy District v. Cox, N.M., 13th JDC, Case no. 7147, filed August 4, 1977. 13. L.M. Hartman and D. Seaston, Water Transfers: Economic Effieicnecy and Alternative Institutions (Baltimore: Johns Hopkns University Press for Resources for the Future, 1970). 14. T. Tregarthen in T. Anderson (ed.), "Water in Colorado: Fear and Loathing of the Market Place," supra, note 6. break 15. W. Coldiron, "Non Reserved Water Rights—United States Compliance with State Law," Solicitor's Opinion, U.S. Dept. of the Interior, September 11, 1981. 16. The State of Missouri, Iowa and Nebraska vs. Andrews et al., U.S. D.C. for the District of Nebraska, Case no. CU 82L-442, filed August 18, 1982. 17. Assembly Office of Water Research, A Marketing Approach to Water Allocation, P. Schifferle, Project Manager (Sacramento, CA: February, 1982). 18. See note 2, supra. 19. See Sporhase v. State of Nebraska, Number 81-613, U.S. Supreme Court, July 2, 1982. 20. See P.J. Ognibene, "Selling Water Users in the West on Sharing Reclamation Project Costs," National Journal, August 14, 1982, pp. 14211425. 1. I am indebted to W.D. Farr of Greeley, Colorado, (contributor to this volume), who pointed out to me several years ago the fundamental significance of this proposal for change in state water rights law. 2. See "Let's Dismantle (Largely but Not Fully) the Federal Water Development Establishment, or the Apostasy of a Longstanding Water Development Federalist," in the Proceedings of the National Conference on Water, Washington, D.C., April 1975, sponsored by the U.S. Water Resources Council (U.S. Government Printing Office, Washington, 1976,
Stock Number 024-011-02798-4), pp. 180-194. Reprinted in Denver Journal of International Law of Policy, University of Denver, College of Law, Volume 6, Special Issue 1976, pp. 395-402. 3. This discussion of block grants only relates to intrastate water projects. The interstate responsibilities of the federal government for the nation's 25,000 mile inland navigation system, flood control relative to the Lower Mississippi River, and other major potential interstate developments, need to be separately addressed.
CONTRIBUTORS Darrell K. Adams , Senior Social Scientist, Bureau of Reclamation, Department of the Interior, Denver, CO Raymond L. Anderson , Resource Economist, Economic Research Service, U.S. Department of Agriculture, Economics Department, Colorado State University, Fort Collins, CO Thomas G. Bahr , Director, Office of Water Policy, U.S. Department of the Interior, Washington, D.C. Harvey O. Banks , Senior Consultant, Camp Dresser & McKee Inc., Belmont, CA Russell Bean , Texas Farmer, Lubbock, TX A.L. Black , Poarch Brothers, Hereford, TX John Bredehoeft , Regional Hydrologist, U.S. Geological Survey, Menlo Park, CA Herman Bouwer , Director, U.S. Water Conservation Laboratory, Agricultural Research Service, U.S. Department of Agriculture, Phoenix, AZ Donald J. Brosz , Extension Specialist and Irrigation Engineer, University of Wyoming, Laramie, WY F. Lee Brown , Professor of Economics, The University of New Mexico, Albuquerque, NM Bartley P. Cardon , Dean, College of Agriculture, University of Arizona, Tucson, AZ
Garrey E. Carruthers , Assistant Secretary, Land and Water Resources, U.S. Department of the Interior Henry P. Caulfield, Jr. , Professor, Department of Political Science, Colorado State University, Fort Collins, CO Raymond H. Coppock , Communications Specialist, Cooperative Extension, University of California, Davis, CA
― 486 ― Carole R. Cristiano , Professional Staff Member, U.S. Senate Committee on Environment and Public Works, Washington, D.C. Glenn S. Collins , Assistant Professor, Department of Agricultural Economics, Texas A&M University, College Station, TX Vernon M. Crowder , Vice President, Research Department, Security Pacific National Bank, Los Angeles, CA Robert R. Curry , Professor of Environmental Geology, University of California, Santa Cruz, CA Charles T. DuMars , Professor of Law, The University of New Mexico, Albuquerque, NM Marvin Duncan , Assistant Vice President and Economist, Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City, Kansas City, MO Ernest A. Engelbert , Professor of Public Administration, Department of Political Science, University of California, Los Angeles, CA Marshall J. English , Associate Professor, Department of Agricultural Engineering, Oregon State University, Corvallis, OR W.D. Farr , Chairman of the Board, Farr Farms Company, Greeley, CO Kenneth R. Farrell , Director, Food and Agricultural Policy Program, Resources For the Future, Washington, D.C. Marc Faye , Deputy Director, Department of Food and Agriculture, State of
California, Sacramento, CA J. Ernest Flack , Professor of Civil Engineering, University of Colorado, Boulder, CO Estevan T. Flores , Director, Mexican American Studies and Assistant Professor of Sociology, Southern Methodist University, Dallas, TX Kenneth D. Frederick , Senior Fellow, Resources For the Future, Washington, D.C. William H. Friedland , Professor and Chair, Community Studies, Merrill College, University of California, Santa Cruz, CA.
― 487 ― Harold C. Fritts , Professor of Dendrochronology, Laboratory of Tree-Ring Research, University of Arizona, Tucson, AZ Herbert H. Fullerton , Staff Assistant, Land and Water Resources, U.S. Department of the Interior Wilford R. Gardner , Head, Soils, Water and Engineering Department, University of Arizona, Tucson, AZ Lay James Gibson , Professor and Head, Department of Geography and Regional Development, University of Arizona, Tucson, AZ Robert M. Hagan , Professor, Department of Land, Air and Water Resources, University of California, Davis, CA A.N. Halter , Technical Staff, Electric Power Research Institute, Palo Alto, CA Wyatte L. Harman , Associate Professor of Agricultural Economics, Texas A&M University Agricultural Research and Extension Center, Amarillo, TX Joe B. Harris , Resource Economist, Camp Dresser & McKee Inc., Austin, TX Parry D. Harrison , Chief, Water Resource Branch, U.S. Bureau of Reclamation, Boise, ID
Earl O. Heady , Director and Distinguished Professor, Center for Agricultural and Rural Development, Iowa State University, Ames, IA Helen M. Ingram , Professor, Department of Political Science, University of Arizona, Tucson, AZ Dallin W. Jensen , Assistant Attorney General, State of Utah, Salt Lake City, UT Marvin E. Jensen , National Research Program Leader, Water Management, Agricultural Research Service, U.S. Department of Agriculture, Fort Collins, CO Thomas L. Kimball , Valley Center, CA; formerly Executive Vice President, National Wildlife Federation, Washington, D.C. Allen V. Kneese , Senior Fellow, Resources For the Future, Washington, D.C. Marcia Kreith , Conference Coordinator, Public Service Research and Dissemination Program, University of California, Davis, CA
― 488 ― Jon L. Kyl , Attorney, Jennings, Strouss and Salmon, Phoenix, AZ Ronald D. Lacewell , Professor, Department of Agricultural Economics, Texas A&M University, College Station, TX Marion E. Marts , Professor, Department of Geography, University of Washington, Seattle, WA W. Don Maughan , Deputy Director, Water Management, Department of Water Resources, State of Arizona, Phoenix, AZ Dorsey R. Meyer, Sr. , President and General Manager, Meyer West, Stockton, CA Cecil H. Miller, Jr. , President, Arizona Farm Bureau Federation, Phoenix, AZ
Charles V. Moore , Agricultural Economist, Economic Research Service, U.S. Department of Agriculture, Department of Agricultural Economics, University of California, Davis, CA James W. O'Leary , Associate Director (Science), Environmental Research Laboratory, University of Arizona, Tucson J.D. Rhoades , Research Leader, U.S. Salinity Laboratory, ARS, U.S. Department of Agriculture, Riverside, CA Ronald B. Robie , Director, Department of Water Resources, State of California, Sacramento, CA Norman J. Rosenberg , George Holmes Professor of Agricultural Meteorology, Center for Agricultural Meteorology and Climatology, University of Nebraska-Lincoln, Lincoln, NE J. Eleonora Sabadell , Program Associate, Program of Policy Studies in Science and Technology, The George Washington University, Washington, D.C. Albert Schaffer , Professor of Sociology, Texas A&M University, College Station, TX Ruth C. Schaffer , Professor of Sociology, Texas A&M University, College Station, TX Ann Foley Scheuring , Consulting Editor, University of California, Davis, CA Ted Schwinden , Governor, State of Montana, Helena, MT
― 489 ― Norman H. Starler , Economic Advisor, Bureau of Reclamation, U.S. Department of the Interior, Washington, D.C. B.A. Stewart , Soil Scientist and Laboratory Director, USDA Conservation and Production Research Laboratory, Bushland, TX Frank J. Trelease , Professor of Law, McGeorge School of Law, University of the Pacific, Sacramento, CA
Richard C. Tucker , Partner, Dames & Moore, Bethesda, MD Jan van Schilfgaarde , Director, U.S. Salinity Laboratory, ARS, U.S. Department of Agriculture, Riverside, CA Evan Vlachos , Professor of Sociology and Civil Engineering and Director, Environmental Resources Center, Colorado State University, Fort Collins, CO George H. Wallen , Ecologist, Chief, Environmental and Social Branch, Division of Planning Technical Services, Bureau of Reclamation, Department of the Interior, Denver, CO David L. Watt , Assistant Professor, Department of Agricultural Economics, North Dakota State University Gary D. Weatherford , Co-Director of Water Program, Center for Natural Resource Studies, John Muir Institute, Berkeley, CA, and Visiting Professor, School of Law, University of Santa Clara, Santa Clara, CA Gilbert F. White , Gustavson Professor Emeritus of Geography, Institute of Behavioral Science, University of Colorado, Boulder, CO Norman K. Whittlesey , Professor, Department of Agricultural Economics, Washington State University, Pullman, WA Zach Willey , Senior Economist, Environmental Defense Fund, Berkeley, CA Dennis C. Williams , Senior Planning Engineer, Los Angeles Department of Water and Power, Los Angeles, CA Jean O. Williams , Vice President, Camp Dresser & McKee Inc., Austin, TX Robert A. Young , Professor, Department of Economics, Colorado State University, Fort Collins, CO
― 491 ―
INDEX Titles of figures and tables are printed in italics.
A Acreage shifts under increased water costs, 183 -185 Action recommendations for water planning 14 -15 Aerospace Corporation water study, 91 -92 Agricultural Stabilization and Conservation Service, 389 Agriculture and labor force, 1947-80 (Table 14.7), 347 Agriculture changes in, in California, 302 exports, 296 , 355 -357 financing, changes in, 403 growth in productivity, 296 labor force, decline in, 346 management to increase water use efficiency, 204 -215 prices, effects of reduced irrigation, 273 -298 research, 394 , 397 , 402 -403 subsidies, 467 technology for limited water supplies, 194 -195 transformation of, in last century, 328 -329 use of water, 82 -90 water conservation, 396 -407
world and U.S. production, 355 -356 Alternative crops, 190 -191, 209 Amaranth, 387 American Farm Bureau Federation, 384 , 389 Appropriation doctrine, 52 Aquifers of the U.S. (Fig. 1.5), 23 Arid lands, 311 Arizona Groundwater Management Act, 69 , 72 , 76 , 381 , 386 , 470 Arizona, crop water use by acre-inch (Table 16.3), 388 Arizona, irrigated crop acreage (Table 16.2), 387 Arizona action on water issues, 65 depletion of groundwater in, 25 farm water conservation measures in, 380 -389 Supreme Court actions, 75 urban population, 68 water consumption in, 82 water costs for farm production, 380 -381 Arkansas River, 38 -39 Arkansas and Texas basins, potential for water export, 116
Assumptions on water use, discussion of, 472 -478
B "Beneficial use," 75 , 243 , 301 , 405 "Black water," 137 -138 Block grants, 464 Buffalo gourd, 191 , 387 -388 Bureau of Reclamation, 52 , 62 , 63 , 178 , 434 , 441 , 449 -456, passim,464 Business decline in farm-related, 312 -314 effects of limited water on, 299 -308 support for water conservation, 396 -407
C California State Water Project, 5 , 107 , 114 , 151 , 303 , 434 California drought of mid-70s, 43 farm water conservation measures, 392 -395 farm workers, 342 -343 impact of rural displacement, 345 importance of agriculture, 302
population, 301 projections for agribusiness, 299 -304 rank in irrigated acreage, 337 -341 state development of resources, 463 territoriality, 482 water transfers, 433 -435, 455 -456 Canada, proposals for water transfers from, 111 -113 Capital costs of developing water supplies, 300 Carter Administration, water policy, 63 , 67 , 463 Central Arizona Project, 54 , 67 , 74 , 77 , 126 , 301 Central Utah Project, 373 Central Valley Project, 4 , 114 , 121 ,
― 492 ― 304 , 434 , 455 Clean Water Act, 140 Climate changes possibility of, 14 , 478 , 482 projections of, 48 , 108 tree ring data on, 44 -47
Climate differences between centuries in North America (Fig. 1.1), 47 Colorado River Compact, 32 , 54 Colorado River basin depletion of water in, 22 -25 interbasin transfers to, 41 utilization of water supplies, 49 water use in, 32 -34 Colorado River system, consumptive uses and losses (Fig. 1.14), 34 Colorado River, 4 ; San Juan portion, 98 Colorado River, annual flow 1910-1980 (Fig. 1.13), 33 Colorado River, salt load in, 1941-78 (Fig. 1.15), 35 Colorado decrease in irrigation, 363 farm workers in, 342 -343 federal water transfer to, 455 flow right sale in, 462 rank in irrigated acreage, 340 -341 sale of water rights, 452 state development of water resources, 463
territoriality, 482 water policy, 69 water transfers in, 428 -430 Columbia Basin Project, 379 Columbia River studies, 129 -131 Columbia River, 4 , 49 , 114 Commodity price impacts of limited irrigation water, 273 -298 Communities and larger society, 310 . See Rural communities, Urban Communities Competition for water in West, 6 , 50 , 81 -108, 368 -370 economic impacts of, 244 -272 Competition in water markets, imperfect, 416 , 424 Congress and water policy, 68 , 466 , 470 Conjunctive water use, 40 , 118 -119 Consequences of reduced agricultural water supplies, 474 Conservation districts, Montana, 443 management, 358 management in High Plains, 297 -298 possibilities for agriculture, 300
tillage, 358 -359 See also Cultural practices; Efficiency of water use; Farm management. Corps of Engineers, 464 Cost sharing in water development, 457 -458 Court actions on water in Arizona, 75 Courts, role of, in institutional change, 418 -423 Crambe, 191 Crop producing regions of U.S. (Fig. 7.1), 182 Crop water use by acre-inch, Arizona (Table 16.3), 388 Crop yield and water use (Fig. 9.2), 238 Cropland nonirrigated, 358 potential in U.S. and abroad, 276 , 370 projections of need for, 356 -357 Crops high value, 187 -190, 288 -289 management strategies for water use efficiency, 180 -203 new, 190 -191 potential for yields, 276 -277 price elasticity of, 188 -190
price shifts under higher water costs, 186 rotation and residue management, 191 -193 selection, 386 -388, 395 Cultural heritage, of irrigated agriculture in West, 353 Cultural practices to improve water use efficiency, 208 -209. See also Conservation; Efficiency of water use; Farm management.
D Deficit irrigation, 239 Department of Labor programs, 326 Desalinization of water, 40 , 119 , 469 Desalting and diversion, 161 -162 Development of new water supplies, 109 -132 better allocation of resources, 122 -123
― 493 ― conjunctive use, 118 -119 desalting of brackish water, 119 groundwater recharge, 123 -124 imports from outside U.S., 110 -114 improving project operations, 120 -121
interstate diversions, 114 -116 wastewater reuse, 120 water harvesting/banking, 117 -118 weather modification, 116 -117 Displaced farmers and families, 315 -319 Displaced workers, 332 -353 Drainage problems, San Joaquin Valley, 170 -171 Drought-tolerant crops, 169 -170, 175 -176, 179 , 193 Drought California in mid-1970s, 43 management strategies, Great Plains, 205 -214 possibility of, 14 , 478 , 482 Dryland farming, 358 -366 passim practices to increase water use efficiency, 204 -215 Dryland, reversion of farms to, 360 -367, 378 -379
E Econometric models critique of, 200 -203 farm commodity prices, 279 -290 growth of western states, 257 -258, 266
TECHSIM, 181 -187 Economic impacts of competition for water, 244 -272 Effects of limited water on irrigated agriculture (Fig. 21.1), 476 Efficiency of water use in dryland farming, 204 -217 in irrigated farming, 218 -243 nonagricultural, 133 -156 Elasticity of prices, 289 Electricity, influences on prices of, 104 -105 Employment in irrigated agriculture, 341 -343 reduction of farm, 332 -353 Energy costs, 107 -108 development and water use, 91 -92, 442 prices, 14 , 103 , 300 use of water, 152 , 423 -424 Environmental impacts of agriculture, 355 , 373 of limited irrigation water, 354 -379
Environmental laws, 462 Equity issues in water rights, 70 , 72 (n.6), 290 Erosion control, 240 losses, 358 wind, 375 , 479 Evaporation losses, reducing, 242 Evapotranspiration with various irrigation methods (Table 9.5), 235 Evapotranspiration and reflectants, 212 -213 prediction of, 211 relation to irrigation efficiency, 129 relation between, and yield, 237 -239
F Fallowing, 208 Family farms, 310 Farm income, impacts of reduced, 350 Farm management for conservation of water, 194 -195, 380 -395 in Arizona, 380 -389 in Texas High Plains, 390 -392
in California, 392 -395 Farm population and employment in U.S., 1930-80 (Table 14.6), 347 Farm population declines, 1950-70 (Fig. 14.4), 348 Farm workers, in California, Colorado, Idaho, 342 -343 Farmers and families, displaced, 315 -319 Farming as a career, 315 -316 departure from, effects of, on families, 315 -319 practices to increase water use efficiency, 204 -215 Federal government budget deficit, 465 -466 Federal Reserve monetary system, 403 reclamation programs, 52 -53, 62 -64 role in water issues, 62 -69, 481
― 494 ― water policies, and irrigated agriculture, 445 -471 Financial incentives for water conservation, 398 -399 Financial institutions, changes in, 403 -404 Fish and wildlife, 370 -371, 377 -379, 464
Flaming Gorge Reservoir, 33 Food supply carryovers, 401
G Genetic engineering, 129 Great Plains, 2 drought management strategies, 205 -214 wind and water erosion, 358 -366 passim Great Western Desert, 2 Greenhouse vs. field water use in vegetable production (Table 16.1), 385 Greenhouses, 384 , 392 , 394 "Grey water," 137 -138 Groundwater and surface water price combinations (Table 11.2), 285 Groundwater legal systems (Fig. 2.3), 61 Groundwater overdraft, U.S . (Fig. 1.9), 28 Groundwater use, U.S., 1950-75 (Fig. 1.12), 30 Groundwater withdrawals, U.S., 1975 (Fig. 1.6), 26 Groundwater withdrawals, U.S., 1975 (Fig. 1.8), 27 Groundwater depletion in West, 25 -27, 49 -50, 180 , 479 legal systems, 60 -62
overdraft, 43 , 307 , 311 , 360 -361 potential for development, 38 , 50 problems, 105 -107 recharge, 123 -124 resources in West, 22 -24 rights, 60 -62, 421 -422 withdrawals, 82 -83 Guayule, 190 , 209 , 387 -388
H Halophytes, 169 , 176 -177, 179 , 388 Hatcheries, 373 High Plains depletion of water in, 25 econometric study of, 296 -298 return flow systems, 232 reversion to dry farming, 480 social change in, 310 -312 study of, 99 , 361 -367, 456 undeveloped resources, 122 -123 High value crops, 202 -203, 288 -289, 386 -387
Historical review of western water development, 445 -446 of western water law, 52 -69 Households, value of water in, 252 Hydroelectric power generation, value of water in, 253 Hydrologic cycle, 17 -18 Hydrologic records, 44 -48 Hydroponic water use, vegetable production (Table 16.1), 385 Hydroponics, 384 -385, 394
I Idaho, farm workers in, 342 -343 Impacts on agriculture of decreased water supplies, 474 Income effects of changes in irrigation, 255 , 258 Income, employment impacts from water reallocation (Table 10.1), 259 -260 Increasing water supplies alternatives for, 35 -41 by surface storage, 35 -37 Indian water rights, 424 , 430 , 454 , 478 , 481 Arizona case, 74 -75 declared reserved, 53 -54
dry paper, 78 legal position, 67 -68 Montana, 439 , 440 transferability, 421 Industrial water conservation, 138 -139, 155 -156 Industry, value of water in, 251 -252 Institutional and technical changes, response to limited water, 287 Instream flows, 479 to maintain fish and wildlife, 87 -90 rights, 419 Interbasin water transfers in western U.S. (Fig. 1.17), 42 Interbasin water transfers, 41
― 495 ― Interest rates, 403 International agricultural markets, 14 , 355 -357, 482 International water transfers, potential for, 110 -114 Interstate water markets, 70 -71 Interstate water transfers impracticality of, 131 -132
proposed, 114 -116, 423 Iowa, 455 Irrigated acreage in 17 western states, 1975 (Table 1.1), 31 Irrigated acreage environmental problems with, 357 -358 hay acres, 198 increase in, 296 , 332 , 354 -355 in U.S., 288 in West, 31 outlook for, 99 -100 projected changes in, 84 -90 Irrigated agriculture in metropolitan areas (Table 14.4), 339 Irrigated agriculture, effects of limited water (Fig. 21.1), 476 Irrigated crop acreage, Arizona (Table 16.2), 387 Irrigated cropland as percent of U.S. cropland (Fig. 14.1), 334 Irrigated cropland as percent of western cropland (Table 14.1), 335 Irrigated land as percent of U.S. land in farms (Table 14.2), 336 Irrigated land as percent of western land in farms (Table 14.2), 337 Irrigated land, locations as percent of U.S. total (Fig. 14.3), 338 Irrigated land, western states, and cumulative percent (Table 14.3), 339
Irrigation agriculture, locations, 333 -341 Irrigation and production costs in San Joaquin basin, 1975 (Table 7.2), 189 Irrigation costs as portion of production costs (Table 12.1), 303 Irrigation efficiency, 38 , 128 -129, 198 -200 and irrigation methods, 233 -235 costs and benefits, 223 improvements in, 218 -243 terminology, 220 -221 Irrigation efficiency, level basin (Table 9.4), 234 Irrigation system changes in downstream project (Table 9.2), 229 -230 Irrigation system changes in upstream project (Table 9.1), 225 -226 Irrigation water budget (Fig. 9.1), 222 Irrigation case examples, system changes, 223 -235 components of, in West, 473 -475 consumptive use of water in, 29 costs, San Joaquin Valley, 303 growth since World War II, 66 -67 importance of, 5 , 246 -247, 263 , 396 -397 methods, 242 , 381 -384, 393
water use in, 49
J Jojoba, 190 , 387 -388
K Kansas, 363 Kern County, California, 301 , 303 -304 Kochia, 209 , 392
L Labor force and agriculture, 1947-80 (Table 14.7), 347 Lake Mead, 32 , 33 Land use controls, 443 Land values, crop returns and water prices, 302 -304 Large-scale farms, competitive with small farms, 107 -108 Legal systems and groundwater overdraft, 60 -62 Los Angeles Metropolitan Water District, 154 , 301 , 434 Los Angeles, 268
M Marginal willingness to pay for water (Fig. 10.1), 256 Market prices for water, shadow pricing, 248 -249 Market transfers of water, 284 , 408 -436, 483
Metering water use, 140 , 143 Metropolitan areas with large irrigated acreage (Table 14.5), 340 Mexico, proposals for water transfers from, 113 -114
― 496 ― Microclimate modification, 209 -214 Migrant farm workers in declining communities, 326 -328 Minimum tillage, 207 -208, 358 -359 Mining, needs for water, 368 Mississippi River, 116 Missouri River Basin Project, 5 Missouri River basin study, 115 -116, 121 Missouri River, 4 Missouri, 455 Monetary policy of Federal Reserve system, 403 Montana, 462 , 463 , 467 , 482 action in water issues, 65 water reservations, 79 water resource management in, 437 -444 Water Use Act, 439 , 440
Mulches, 242 , 393 -394 Multiple use objectives, 374 , 376 Multiplier effects, 350 Municipal sector, value of water in, 252 Municipal-industrial water conservation 133 -156
N National Agricultural Lands Study, 356 National Environmental Protection Act, 37 National Water Assessment, 102 -104, 151 , 283 , 368 review of, 83 -93 National Water Commission, 140 , 295 National economy, impacts of reduced irrigation, 480 Nebraska, 363 , 455 , 482 center pivot irrigation, 205 groundwater potential in, 38 Sandhills, 99 New Mexico, 363 , 482 depletion of water in, 25 saline groundwater, 119 New crops, 190 -191, 209 , 387 -388, 392
Nonagricultural use of water, projections of, 82 -83, 86 -93 North American Water and Power Alliance (NAWAPA), 112 -113 Northern plains, water consumption in, 82
O Ogallala Aquifer area, 122 -123, 360 -361, 456 groundwater in, 38 , 43 overdraft, 78 population characteristics of, 312 productivity of, 322 programming model for, 288 , 297 -298 study, 293 -294 Ogallala Aquifer, principal soils overlying (Fig. 15.3), 367 Ogallala Aquifer, projected irrigation to 2020 (Fig. 15.1), 362 Ogallala Aquifer, projected irrigated and dry cropland (Fig. 15.2), 364 Ogallala Aquifer, water supplies and depletion (Table 1.3), 39 Overview of volume, 9 -12 Owens Valley, 261 , 268 , 301
P Pacific Coast states, 3 Palouse, 240
Percolation, reducing, 237 , 242 Permit procedure: prior appropriation states (Fig. 2.2), 58 Phreatophytes, 127 -128, 198 , 219 , 481 Planning difficulties of, for water, 13 -14 for community decline, 319 -321 policy, 482 -484 Plant architecture and reflectance, 213 -214 Plant transpiration, 237 -238, 241 Policy planning, 482 -484 Political division over water, in California, 301 -302, 305 Political power of agriculture, 480 Population trends, 14 projections, in West, 84 -85 Precipitation for 18 California stations, average (Fig. 1.18), 46 Precipitation, average annual U.S. (Fig. 1.1), 19 Price elasticities (Table 5.4), 146 Prices for commodities, effects of limited water on, 273 -298 Projected changes in water use, 1975-2000 (Table 3.1), 85
Public attitudes toward irrigated agriculture, 68
R Rate structures, water pricing,
― 497 ― 141 , 144 -147 Reagan Administration, 63 , 67 , 463 , 464 Reallocation of water, economic impacts of, 247 -272 Reclamation Act of 1902, 52 , 67 , 329 -330, 420 , 449 , 451 Recreation irrigation project areas, 378 value of water in, 253 -254, 464 Recycling water, 135 -139 Reflectants and evapotranspiration, 212 -213 Regional shifts in planted acres and net returns (Table 7.1), 184 -185 Research agricultural, 394 , 397 , 402 -403 need for interdisciplinary, 294 Reservoir capacity in major river basins of the U.S. (Table 1.2), 36 Reservoir capacity, major usable in U.S. since 1920 (Fig. 1.16), 37
Reservoir development, historic trends, 35 -37 Residential water demand (Table 5.2), 143 Residential water demand with change in price (Table 5.5), 146 Residential water demand, metered with devices (Table 5.3), 145 Residential water reuse, potential (Table 5.1), 137 Return flows on Texas High Plains farms (Table 9.3), 233 Return flows, 139 , 237 High Plains systems, 232 Riparian doctrine, 55 Rocky Mountain Plan, 111 -112 Runoff, average annual U.S. (Fig. 1.2), 20 Runoff, average monthly, Yellowstone River (Fig. 1.4), 22 Runoff difficulties of prediction, 49 farming, 128 Rural communities planning for adjustment, 319 -321 process of decline in, 312 -315 social impacts of reduced water, 309 -330
S Saline soils, 305 Salinity, 38 , 106 , 223 , 479 across world and in U.S., 158 causes of, 159 -160, 177 Colorado River basin, 33 definitions of, 158 -159 and diversion, 161 -162 economic impacts of, 178 effect on crops, 160 management strategies for, 157 -179 and reduced leaching, 162 -164 and salt-tolerant crops, 160 , 169 , 176 -177 use of saline water for irrigation, 164 -168 Salt River Project, 68 Salt load in the Colorado River, 1941-78 (Fig. 1.15), 35 Salt water intrusion, 375 Salt-tolerant crops, 160 , 169 , 176 -177 San Joaquin Valley, California, 107 drainage problems, 170 -171
irrigation costs, 303 Sectoral water consumptions estimates and projections (Table 3.3), 89 Sewage effluent, 385 , 392 -394 Shadow prices for five scenarios, 2030 (Table 11.1), 282 Small farms, decline of, 325 -328 Snow management, 207 Social goals of water allocation, 411 -413, 414 -415, 424 Social impacts analysis, 349 , 351 on rural communities, of reduced irrigation, 309 -330 on urban communities, of reduced irrigation, 331 -353 Soil Conservation Service, 62 -63, 231 -232, 239 , 366 Soil and water resources, environmental impacts of irrigation, 357 -370 Soil evaporation reduction, 208 -209 Soil modification, 395 South Dakota, 65 , 455 , 482 Southern California, depletion of water in, 25 Soybean pubescence and reflectance, 213 -214 Sporhase vs. Nebraska, 64 , 79 , 127 , 178 , 423 , 456 State role in water issues, 64 -69, 457 , 481
― 498 ― State statutory authority for water resources (Fig. 2.4), 66 State water laws, 54 -62 appropriative rights, 55 -59 "beneficial use," 55 -57 groundwater rights, 60 -62 riparian doctrine, 55 surface water rights, 55 -60 State's right, control of water resources, 458 Streamflow, average U.S., 1941-70 (Fig. 1.3), 21 Summary and conclusions, of volume, 472 -484 Supply and demand, affecting agricultural prices, 274 -275 Supreme Court decisions on water rights, 64 Surface water rights systems (Fig. 2.1), 56
T Tax incentives, 443 Technology, potential water savings of, 294 Territoriality, 481 -482 Texas, 362 -363, 463
High Plains, 371 , 402 High Plains water conservation, 390 -392 rank in irrigated acreage, 337 -341 Third party interests, 455 , 461 Tillage practices, 191 -193, 207 -208, 358 -359 Tillage practices, evolution of (Table 7.3), 192 Time horizons in discussion of water, 477 -478 Tree ring data, climate change in West, 44 -47
U U.S. Salinity Laboratory, 119 U.S. Water Resources Council, 151 , 219 U.S. agricultural exports, 275 U.S. farm population, decline in, 345 -346 U.S.-Mexican water agreements, 54 Uncertainty of future, re water issues, 14 , 69 -71 in policy planning, 482 -483 Unemployment, psychological effects of, 317 -318 Urban communities, social impacts on, of reduced irrigation, 331 -353 Urban population, Arizona, 68
Urban water use, 301 runoff control, 134 conservation, 140 -149 Utah, 431 , 442 , 461
V Value of production on irrigated lands, 396 -397 Value of water for average crop rotation (Table 10.2), 270 Value of water related to average annual supply (Fig. 10.1), 256 Vegetable production water use, greenhouse vs. field (Table 16.1), 385
W Washington (state), 271 Waste dilution, value of water in, 253 Wastewater, reuse to increase water supplies, 40 , 120 , 128 , 135 -139, 154 Water banking, 455 -456 Water conservation agricultural, 204 -215, 300 municipal-industrial, 133 -156 techniques, 127 -129, 155 See also Efficiency of water use; Farm Management.
Water consumption by use, U.S., 1950-75 (Fig. 1.11), 30 Water consumption for irrigation and other uses by state (Table 3.2), 86 Water consumption in West estimates, 219 projected changes in, 84 -90 Water costs farmers' response to, 448 impact of increased, 182 -187 Water depletion in U.S. (Fig. 1.6), 24 Water depletion critical areas of, in West, 22 -25 definition of, 22 Water development historical review, in West, 445 -446 joint ventures, 457
― 499 ― Montana, 441 -442 project costs and feasibility, 450 -451 Water harvesting, 117 -118, 206 , 240
Water institutions evolution in, 430 social goals of, 411 -413, 414 -415, 424 Water issues in West, summary of, 7 -8 Water law, 443 changes in, 418 -423 review of, 52 -69 Water leasing, 425 Water markets, 70 , 71 , 74 , 446 -449 passim arrangements needed, 453 distortions in, 451 -452, 458 imperfect competition in, 416 , 424 Water policy assumptions in, 460 Carter Administration, 63 , 67 and Congressional structure, 68 federal, 445 -471 Reagan Administration, 63 , 67 and state legislatures, 68 Water pollution
in irrigation, 357 nonpoint sources, 374 -375 Water pricing and changes in demand, 284 -287 as conservation tool, difficulties in, 155 factors in, 248 -251 price elasticities and urban demand rates, 141 , 144 -147 value of water, 269 -271 in water market, 267 Water problems in West, overview of, 6 -9 Water quality and agriculture, 223 , 355 salinity management, 157 -179 Water resource management, Montana, 437 -444 Water resources in West, 18 -43 groundwater, 22 -24 precipitation and streamflow, 18 -21 reallocation of, 401 -402, 480 sharing responsibility for, 321 Water rights, 262 , 266 , 301 , 443
Arizona interpretation of, 76 equity aspects, 290 federal reserved/nonreserved, 454 , 480 "flow right," 462 -463 groundwater, 60 -62 markets for, 98 , 103 market transfers, 408 -436 Montana adjudication of, 439 , 440 need for refining, 481 surface, 55 -60 transfers of, 479 See also Indian water rights. Water subregions with serious problems (Fig. 3.1), 88 Water supplies, variability of, 473 , 475 -477 Water supply, types of (Table 21.1), 474 Water transfers, regional benefits from, 247 -272 Water use and crop yield (Fig. 9.2), 238 Water use and prices of crops under four combinations (Table 11.3) , 285 Water use increasing efficiency, 241 -243
in U.S., 25 -29 dicussion of assumptions on, 472 -478 efficiencies in, 38 -39 Water value, in various uses, 251 -254 Water withdrawals by use, U.S., 1950-75 (Fig. 1.10), 29 Water withdrawals for irrigation and fuels, by region (Table 15.1), 369 Weather modification, 39 , 116 -117, 469 West ambiance of, 467 definition of, 2 -3 general description of, 475 historical development of, 3 -5 Western States Water Augmentation Concept, 113 Western agriculture, potential of, 307 Westlands Water District, California, 330 Wilderness areas, 371
― 500 ― Wildlife habitat, 199 -200 Willamette River, 49
Wind and water erosion, 240 , 375 , 479 Great Plains, 358 -366 passim Windbreaks, 207 -208, 209 -212 World demand for food, 299 World food production, 355 , 374 Wyoming, 79 , 84 , 442 , 463
Y Yampa River basin streamflows and water use for energy (Table 3.5), 96 Yampa River basin use of water (Table 3.4), 95 Yampa River case study, 93 -97 Yield of cotton under irrigation in Uzbekistan (Table 6.1), 165 Yuba County, California, 301
Preferred Citation: Engelbert, Ernest A., and Ann Foley Scheuring, editors Water Scarcity: Impacts on Western Agriculture. Berkeley: University of California Press, c1984 1984. http://ark.cdlib.org/ark:/13030/ft0f59n72f/